Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-txr5j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-07T13:23:42.437Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Measuring absolute poverty: shame is all you need

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 April 2022

Helmut P. Gaisbauer
Affiliation:
Universität Salzburg
Gottfried Schweiger
Affiliation:
Universität Salzburg
Clemens Sedmak
Affiliation:
King's College London
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Each generation asks the same questions. Often, they yield the same answers. But sometimes they do not.

‘What is poverty?’ and ‘Is it absolute or relative?’ are a couple of the questions that people keep asking. By the 1960s, it was generally agreed in Europe that poverty is inherently relative. But Americans kept insisting on using a measure that was fairly absolute. (Microsoft's grammar checker points out that ‘fairly absolute’ is a nonsense [since absolute is non-gradable] but the Orshanski measure used in the US is just that [US Census, 2017].) Maybe Americans clung to an absolute measure because in many US policy circles socialism is largely a term of abuse while a simplistic understanding of relative poverty might point to policy responses requiring substantial income redistribution and big government; ergo, socialism.

Looking to the Global South, where poverty in the 1960s manifested as a truly life or death matter, there was much less confidence that poverty had to be relative and little agreement about what to do about it however it was measured. However, with the role of government denigrated during the era of the Washington Consensus (circa 1980–2008), measuring poverty seemed superfluous since market-driven growth would eradicate poverty, making measurement redundant (Surender, 2014). When that didn't happen and the Consensus cracked, the World Bank promoted a measure, less absolute than arbitrary, to be used in the developing world. Initially fixed at $1/day, the measure was in 1990 sufficiently low to avoid accusations that doing something about it smacked of socialism, while simultaneously implying that people blessed with an additional cent were, if not rich, not poor (World Bank, 1990).

Later people began to listen to Amartya Sen, economist and Nobel laureate, perhaps because he was an economist and Nobel laureate; certainly, it could not have been because he expressed his ideas clearly. What he seemed to say was that poverty was both relative and absolute, that it was possible to have a poverty cake and eat it. Moreover, he willingly offered the policy world several metrics including the Human Development Index (HDI) and Human Poverty Index (HPI); these were simple, cheap, functional and policy-focused indicators that enthusiasts willingly called measures of poverty (although they were better as indicators of wellbeing).

Type
Chapter
Information
Absolute Poverty in Europe
Interdisciplinary Perspectives on a Hidden Phenomenon
, pp. 97 - 118
Publisher: Bristol University Press
Print publication year: 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×