Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-sh8wx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-22T11:32:11.368Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 July 2009

Oliver Black
Affiliation:
King's College London
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Achinstein, P. 1983. The Concept of Evidence. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Acton, H. 1993. ‘The Morals of Markets: An Ethical Exploration’. In , H. Acton, The Morals of Markets and Related Essays. Indianapolis: Liberty PressGoogle Scholar
Alexander, L. 1985. ‘Pursuing the Good – Indirectly’. Ethics 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allingham, M. 2002. Choice Theory: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, W. 1989. ‘Varieties of Privileged Access’. In , W. Alston, Epistemic Justification: Essays in the Theory of Knowledge. Ithaca: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Altham, J. 1985. ‘Wicked Promises’. In , I. Hacking (ed.), Exercises in Analysis: Essays by Students of Casimir Lewy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Anonymous. 1983. ‘Fixing the Price Fixing Confusion: A Rule of Reason Approach’. Yale Law Journal 92
Archard, D. 1993. ‘Self-Justifying Paternalism’. Journal of Value Inquiry 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ardal, P. 1976. ‘Promises and Reliance’. Dialogue 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Areeda, P. 1985. ‘The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule’. Antitrust Law Journal 54Google Scholar
Areeda, P. 1989. Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Arneson, R. 1998. ‘Paternalism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 7
Arneson, R. 2002. ‘The End of Welfare As We Know It? Scanlon Versus Welfarist Consequentialism’. Social Theory and Practice 28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1951. ‘An Extension of the Basic Theorems of Classical Welfare Economics’. Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Symposium. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values (2nd edition). New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1979. The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1981. Promises, Morals, and Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1986. Essays on Contract. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Audi, R. 1989. Practical Reasoning. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. 1976. ‘Agreeing to Disagree’. Annals of Statistics 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, J. 1962. Sense and Sensibilia. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Bach, K. 1995. ‘Terms of Agreement’. Ethics 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baier, A. 1985. Postures of the Mind. Minneapolis: Minnesota University PressGoogle Scholar
Baird, D., , H. Gertner and , R. Picker. 1994. Game Theory and the Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. 1973. Political Argument. London: Routledge and Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. 1986. ‘Lady Chatterley's Lover and Doctor Fischer's Bomb Party: Liberalism, Pareto Optimality, and the Problem of Objectionable Preferences’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Beale, H., et al. (eds.). 1999. Chitty on Contracts (28th edition). vol. 1. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Beals, A., and , B. Siegel. 1966. Divisiveness and Social Conflict. Palo Alto: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Beard, D. 2003. ‘The Cartel Criminal Offence’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Beatson, J. 1987. ‘Benefit, Reliance and the Structure of Unjust Enrichment’. Current Legal Problems 40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benn, S. 1971. ‘Freedom, Autonomy, and the Concept of a Person’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 12Google Scholar
Bennett, J. 1976. Linguistic Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Benson, P. (ed.). 2001a. The Theory of Contract Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, P. 2001b. ‘The Unity of Contract Law’. In Benson (2001a)
Bentham, J. 1948. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, L. 1962. Aggression: A Social Psychological Analysis. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, M. 1998. ‘Well-Being’. American Philosophical Quarterly 35Google Scholar
Beschle, R. 1987. ‘“What Never? Well, Hardly Ever”: Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Antitrust Illegality’. Hastings Law Journal 38Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1994. Playing Fair. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 1998. Just Playing. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., and A. Brandenburger. 1990. ‘Common Knowledge and Game Theory’. In , K. Binmore (ed.), Essays on Foundations of Game Theory. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Bishop, S., and , M. Walker. 2002. The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1987a. ‘Induction and Experience: An Alleged Infinite Regress’. Fundamenta Scientiae 7Google Scholar
Black, O. 1987b. The Infinite Regress of Justification. PhD thesis, University of London
Black, O. 1988. ‘Infinite Regresses of Justification’. International Philosophical Quarterly 28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1992. ‘Communication and Obligation in Arrangements and Concerted Practices’. European Competition Law Review 13Google Scholar
Black, O. 1993. ‘Competition and Negative Obligation’. European Competition Law Review 14Google Scholar
Black, O. 1994a. ‘Ends, Desires and Rationality’. International Philosophical Quarterly 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1994b. ‘“Most Favoured Customer” Clauses: Application of the Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1976’. European Competition Law Review 15Google Scholar
Black, O. 1995a. ‘Accepting a Relevant Restriction by Accepting Something Else’. European Competition Law Review 16Google Scholar
Black, O. 1995b. ‘What Is the Difference Between a Term and a Restriction? – Associated Dairies and the Scope of Section 9(3) RTPA’. European Competition Law Review 16Google Scholar
Black, O. 1996a. ‘Concertation and Coordination: A Distinction without a Difference?European Competition Law Review 17Google Scholar
Black, O. 1996b. ‘Legal Validity and the Infinite Regress’. Law and Philosophy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1997. ‘Per Se Rules and Rules of Reason: What Are They?European Competition Law Review 18Google Scholar
Black, O. 1998. ‘The Relation Between Reliance and Obligation’. In , P. Kampits (eds.), Applied Ethics. Kirchberg am Wechsel: Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein SocietyGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2002. ‘What Makes Me the Person I Am’. Dialegesthai, November 2002Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003a. ‘Collusion and Coordination in EC Merger Control’. European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003b. ‘Concerted Practices, Joint Action and Reliance’. European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003c. ‘Grades of Correlation: The Spectrum from Independent Action to Collusion, and Its Implications for Antitrust’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003d. ‘Independent Promises and the Rescission of Contracts’. Legal Studies 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2003e. ‘Infinite Regresses, Infinite Beliefs’. In , W. Löffler and , P. Weingartner (eds.), Knowledge and Belief. Kirchberg am Wechsel: Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein SocietyGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2003f. ‘Joint Action, Reliance and the Law’. King's College Law Journal 14Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003g. ‘What Is an Agreement?European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2004a. ‘Agreements, Undertakings and Practical Reason’. Legal Theory 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2004b. ‘Reliance and Obligation’. Ratio Juris 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, R., and , N. Bruce. 1984. Welfare Economics. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Boardman, W. 1987. ‘Coordination and the Moral Obligation to Obey the Law’. Ethics 97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bock, B. 1990. ‘An Economist Considers Some Basic Issues of Antitrust Law in the United States’. European Competition Law Review 11Google Scholar
Bork, R. 1965. ‘The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division’ (Part 1). Yale Law Journal 74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bork, R. 1966. ‘The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division’ (Part 2). Yale Law Journal 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bork, R. 1978. The Antitrust Paradox. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Boulding, K. 1962. Conflict and Defense. New York: HarperGoogle Scholar
Brandt, R. 1979. A Theory of the Good and the Right. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Brandt, R. 1982. ‘Two Concepts of Utility’. In Miller and Williams (1982)
Bratman, M. 1999a. Faces of Intention. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratman, M. 1999b. ‘I Intend That We J’. In Bratman (1999a)
Bratman, M. 1999c. Intentions, Plans, and Practical Reason. Stanford: CSLI PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Bratman, M. 1999d. ‘Shared Cooperative Activity’. In Bratman (1999a)
Bratman, M. 1999e. ‘Shared Intention’. In Bratman (1999a)
Brickman, P., and D. Campbell. 1971. ‘Hedonic Relativism and Planning the Good Society’. In , M. Appley (ed.), Adaptation-Level Theory: A Symposium. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brickman, P., et al. 1978. ‘Lottery Winners and Accident Victims: Is Happiness Relative?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 36CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bright, C. 1995. ‘Deregulation of EC Competition Policy: Rethinking Article 85(1)’. New York: Fordham Corporate Law Institute
Brock, D. 1993. ‘Quality of Life Measures in Health Care and Medical Ethics’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Broome, J. 1979. ‘Choice and Value in Economics’. Oxford Economic Papers 30Google Scholar
Broome, J. 1991a. ‘Utility’. Economics and Philosophy 7Google Scholar
Broome, J. 1991b. Weighing Goods: Equality, Uncertainty and Time. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2000. ‘Normative Requirements’. In , J. Dancy (ed.), Normativity. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2001a. ‘Are Intentions Reasons? And How Should We Cope With Incommensurable Values?’ In , C. Morris and , A. Ripstein (eds.), Practical Rationality and Preference: Essays for David Gauthier. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2001b. ‘Normative Practical Reasoning’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 75Google Scholar
Broome, J. 2002. ‘Practical Reasoning’. In , J. Bermùdez and , A. Millar (eds.), Reason and Nature: Essays in the Theory of Rationality. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2004. ‘Reasons’. In , R. Wallaceet al. (eds.), Reason and Value: Essays on the Moral Philosophy of Joseph Raz. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Brownson, W. 1974. ‘The Structure of Competition in the School and Its Consequences’. Philosophy of Education 30Google Scholar
Brunet, E. 1984. ‘Streamlining Antitrust Litigation by “Facial Examination” of Restraints: The Burger Court and the Per Se Rule of Reason Distinction’. Washington Law Review 60Google Scholar
Buchanan, A. 1985. Ethics, Efficiency, and the Market. Totowa: Rowman & AllanheldGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, A., and , D. Brock. 1990. Deciding for Others: The Ethics of Surrogate Decision Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrows, P. 1993. ‘Patronising Paternalism’. Oxford Economic Papers 45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrows, P. 1995. ‘Analyzing Legal Paternalism’. International Review of Law and Economics 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caillois, R. 2001. Man, Play and Games. Urbana: University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
Campbell, A. 1981. The Sense of Well-Being in America: Recent Patterns and Trends. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Cane, P. 1992. An Introduction to Administrative Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Cartwright, J. 1984. ‘An Evidentiary Theory of Promises’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Castañeda, H. 1999. The Phenomeno-Logic of the I. Bloomington: Indiana University PressGoogle Scholar
Chang, R. (ed.). 1997. Incommensurability, Incomparability, and Practical Reason. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Chisholm, R. 1976. Person and Object. Chicago: Open CourtGoogle Scholar
Christman, J. (ed.). 1989. The Inner Citadel: Essays on Individual Autonomy. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Cohen, G. 1977. ‘Labor, Leisure, and a Distinctive Contradiction of Advanced Capitalism’. In , G. Dworkinet al. (eds.), Markets and Morals. Washington, DC: Hemisphere Publishing CoGoogle Scholar
Cohen, G. 1993. ‘Equality of What? On Welfare, Goods, and Capabilities’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Cohen, M. (ed.). 1984. Ronald Dworkin and Contemporary Jurisprudence. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. 1987. ‘Competition and Cooperation’. Ethics 98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Combs, A. 1979. Myths in Education. Boston: Allyn and BaconGoogle Scholar
Competition Commission. 1998. Ladbroke Group Plc and the Coral Betting Business: A Report on the Merger Situation. London: Competition Commission
Competition Commission 2003a. Merger References: Competition Commission Guidelines. London: Competition Commission
Competition Commission 2003b. Market Investigation References: Competition Commission Guidelines. London: Competition Commission
Confederation of British Industry. 1995. Loosening the Strait-Jacket: CBI Proposals for Reform of the Scope and Administration of Article 85. London: Confederation of British Industry
Cooke, E. 1995. ‘Reliance and Estoppel’. Law Quarterly Review 111Google Scholar
Cooke, P., and , D. Oughton. 1993. The Common Law of Obligations. London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Cooley, C. 1899. ‘Personal Competition’. American Economic Association Studies 4Google Scholar
Cooper, G. 1993. ‘The Competition Controversy in Community Ecology’. Biology and Philosophy 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craig, E. 1990. Knowledge and the State of Nature. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Craig, E. (ed.). 1998. Routledge Encyclopedia of Philosophy. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Craig, P. 1992. ‘Legitimate Expectations: A Conceptual Analysis’. Law Quarterly Review 108Google Scholar
Crampton, P. 1994. ‘Alternative Approaches to Competition Law: Consumers’ Surplus, Total Surplus, Total Welfare and Non-Efficiency Goals’. World Competition 17Google Scholar
Criminal Law Revision Committee. 1966. Eighth Report: Theft and Related Offences (1966 Cmnd 2977). London: HMSO
Crisp, R. 1998. ‘Virtue Ethics’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 9
Crisp, R. 2000. ‘Utilitarianism and Accomplishment’. Analysis 60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R. 2001. ‘Utilitarianism and Accomplishment Revisited’. Analysis 61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R., and , B. Hooker (eds.). 2000. Well-Being and Morality: Essays in Honour of James Griffin. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R., and , M. Slote (eds.). 1997. Virtue Ethics. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Dahlke, H. 1964. ‘Cooperation’. In , J. Gould and , W. Kolb (eds.), Dictionary of the Social Sciences. London: TavistockGoogle Scholar
Daniels, N. 1979. ‘Wide Reflective Equilibrium and Theory Acceptance in Ethics’. Journal of Philosophy 76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darwall, S. 2002. Welfare and Rational Care. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, D. 1980a. ‘Causal Relations’. In Davidson (1980b)
Davidson, D. 1980b. Essays on Actions and EventsOxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Davidson, D. 1980c. ‘How Is Weakness of the Will Possible?’ In Davidson (1980b)
Davies, S. 1997. ‘Two Conceptions of Welfare: Voluntarism and Incorporationism’. Social Philosophy and Policy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, C. 1995. ‘Estoppel – Reliance and Remedy’. Conveyancer and Property Lawyer 59Google Scholar
Dean, N. 2003. ‘Creating a Stir’. New Law Journal, 13 June 2003Google Scholar
Dearden, R. 1972. ‘Competition in Education’. Proceedings of the Philosophy of Education Society of Great Britain 6Google Scholar
Demarco, J., and , R. Fox. 1992. ‘Putting Pressure on Promises’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moor, A. 1986. ‘Contract and Agreement in English and French Law’. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 6Google Scholar
De Moor, A. 1987. ‘Are Contracts Promises?’ In , J. Eekelaar and , J. Bell (eds.), Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Department of Trade and Industry. 2001. Productivity and Enterprise: A World Class Competition Regime. London: Department of Trade and Industry
Deutsch, M. 1973. The Resolution of Conflict: Constructive and Destructive Processes. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Deutscher, I. 1952. ‘Socialist Competition’. Foreign Affairs 30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diener, E. 1984. ‘Subjective Well-Being’. Psychological Bulletin 95CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Diogenes Laertius. 1980. Lives of Eminent Philosophers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Dixit, A., and , S. Skeath. 1999. Games of Strategy. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Downie, R. 1985. ‘Three Accounts of Promising’. Philosophical Quarterly 35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downie, R., and , E. Telfer. 1971. ‘Autonomy’. Philosophy 15Google Scholar
Dummett, M. 1978. ‘Truth’. In , M. Dummett, Truth and Other Enigmas. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Duncan, O. 1975. ‘Does Money Buy Satisfaction?Social Indicators Research 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, G. 1972. ‘Paternalism’. Monist 56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, G. 1988. The Theory and Practice of Autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1978. Taking Rights Seriously. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1986a. Law's Empire. London: FontanaGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1986b. A Matter of Principle. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Easterbrook, F. 1984a. ‘The Limits of Antitrust’. Texas Law Review 63Google Scholar
Easterbrook, F. 1984b. ‘Vertical Arrangements and the Rule of Reason’. Antitrust Law Journal 53Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. 1974. ‘Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence’. In , P. David and , M. Reder (eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, I., and , R. Posner. 1974. ‘An Economic Analysis of Legal Rulemaking’. Journal of Legal Studies 3Google Scholar
Elliott, D. 1982. ‘Dishonesty in Theft: A Dispensable Concept’. Criminal Law Review
Elster, J. 1985. Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. 1989. ‘The Market and the Forum: Three Varieties of Political Theory’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Elster, J., and , A. Hylland (eds.). 1989a. Foundations of Social Choice Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., and A. Hylland 1989b. ‘Introduction’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Elster, J., and , J. Roemer (eds.). 1993a. Interpersonal Comparisons of Well-Being. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., and J. Roemer 1993b. ‘Introduction’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Faull, J., and , A. Nikpay. 1999. The EC Law of Competition. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1973. Social Philosophy. Upper Saddle River: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1984. Harm to Others. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1986. Harm to Self. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinman, J. 1984a. ‘The Meaning of Reliance: A Historical Perspective’. Wisconsin Law Review
Feinman, J. 1984b. ‘Promissory Estoppel and Judicial Method’. Harvard Law Review 97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feltkamp, R. 2003. ‘Some Reflections on the Structure of the State Aid Rules in the Treaty of Rome’. EC Competition Policy Newsletter 1Google Scholar
Fielding, M. 1976. ‘Against Competition: In Praise of Malleable Analysis and the Subversiveness of Philosophy’. Proceedings of the Philosophy of Education Society of Great Britain 10Google Scholar
Finnis, J. 1980. Natural Law and Natural Rights. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Flew, A. 1983. ‘Competition and Cooperation, Equality and Elites’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, J. 1982. ‘Rethinking Sherman Act Section 1 Analysis: Three Proposals for Reducing the Chaos’. Antitrust Law Journal 49Google Scholar
Fogelin, R. 1983. ‘Richard Price on Promising: A Limited Defence’. Journal of the History of Philosophy 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foot, P. (ed.). 1967. Theories of Ethics. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Foster, E., and , H. Sonnenschein. 1970. ‘Price Distortion and Economic Welfare’. Econometrica 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, E. 1990. ‘The Future of the Per Se Rule: Two Visions at War With One Another’. Washburn Law Journal 29Google Scholar
Fox, E., and , L. Sullivan. 1989. Cases and Materials on Antitrust. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Fox, R., and , J. Demarco. 1993. ‘The Immorality of Promising’. Journal of Value Inquiry 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. 2003. Microeconomics and Behavior (5th edition). New York: McGraw-Hill IrwinGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, H. 1999a. ‘Autonomy, Necessity, and Love’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Frankfurt, H. 1999b. Necessity, Volition, and Love. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, H. 1999c. ‘On the Necessity of Ideals’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Frankfurt, H. 1999d. ‘On the Usefulness of Final Ends’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Franklin, D. Unpublished. ‘Valuing Health, Healthcare and Health Equality’
Freeman, P., and , R. Whish (eds.). 2002. Butterworths Competition Law. London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Freeman, S. 1998. ‘Contractarianism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 2
Frege, G. 1952. ‘On Sense and Reference’. In , P. Geach and , M. Black (eds.), Translations from the Philosophical Writings of Gottlob Frege. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Fried, C. 1981. Contract as Promise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Fuller, L. 1969. The Morality of Law. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Fuller, L., and , W. Perdue. 1936. ‘The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages’. Yale Law Journal 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganz, G. 1986. ‘Legitimate Expectation’. In , C. Harlow (ed.), Public Law and Politics. London, Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Gaus, G. 1998. ‘Why All Welfare States (Including Laissez-Faire Ones) Are Unreasonable’. Social Philosophy and Policy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, D. 1978. ‘The Social Contract as Ideology’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 6Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. 1986. Morals By Agreement. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Geach, P. 1972. Logic Matters. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, J. 1992. ‘Common Knowledge’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gellhorn, E. 1986. Antitrust Law and Economics. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Gellhorn, E., and , T. Tatham. 1985. ‘Making Sense Out of the Rule of Reason’. Case Western Reserve Law Review 35Google Scholar
Gert, B., and , C. Culver. 1976. ‘Paternalistic Behavior’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 6Google ScholarPubMed
Gibbard, A. 1986. ‘Interpersonal Comparisons: Preference, Good, and the Intrinsic Reward of a Life’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. Cambridge: Polity PressGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1989. On Social Facts. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1996a. ‘Agreements, Coercion, and Obligation’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996b. ‘Is an Agreement an Exchange of Promises?’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996c. Living Together. Lanham: Rowman & LittlefieldGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1996d. ‘Notes on the Concept of a Social Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996e. ‘On Language and Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996f. ‘Rationality, Coordination, and Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996g. ‘Walking Together: A Paradigmatic Social Phenomenon’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilmore, G. 1995. The Death of Contract. Columbus: Ohio State University PressGoogle Scholar
Glover, J. 1990. Causing Death and Saving Lives. Harmondsworth: PenguinGoogle Scholar
Goldman, A. 1995. ‘Simulation and Interpersonal Utility’. Ethics 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, R. 1989. ‘Laundering Preferences’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Goodin, R. 1993. ‘Democracy, Preferences and Paternalism’. Policy Sciences 26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, N. 1973. Fact, Fiction, and Forecast (3rd edition). Indianapolis: Bobbs-MerrillGoogle Scholar
Gordley, G. 1991. The Philosophical Origins of Modern Contract Doctrine. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Goyder, D. 1998. ECCompetition Law (3rd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Greenawalt, K. 1992. Law and Objectivity. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Grice, H. 1957. ‘Meaning’. Philosophical Review 67Google Scholar
Griew, E. 1985. ‘Dishonesty: The Objections to Feely and Ghosh’. Criminal Law Review
Griffin, J. 1986. Well-Being: Its Meaning, Measurement and Moral Importance. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Griffin, J. 1993. ‘Against the Taste Model’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Griffin, J. 2000. ‘Welfare Rights’. Journal of Ethics 4Google Scholar
Hahn, F., and M. Hollis. 1979. ‘Introduction’. In , F. Hahn and , M. Hollis (eds.), Philosophy and Economic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hammond, A., and R. Penrose. 2001. Proposed Criminalisation of Cartels in the UK. London: Office of Fair Trading
Hammond, P. 1995. ‘The Moral Status of Profits and Other Rewards: A Perspective from Modern Welfare Economics’. In , R. Cowan and , M. Rizzo (eds.), Profits and Morality. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hampton, J. 1998. ‘Rationality, Practical’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 8
Handler, M. 1941. A Study of the Construction and Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws. Washington, DC: US GPO, Temporary National Economic CommitteeGoogle Scholar
Hare, R. 1973. ‘Principles’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hargreaves Heap, S., et al. 1992. The Theory of Choice. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Harman, G. 1974. Review of Schiffer (1972). Journal of Philosophy 71Google Scholar
Harman, G. 1986. Change in View. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. 1982. ‘Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour’. In Sen and Williams (1982)
Hart, H. 1961. The Concept of Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, H. 1963. Law, Liberty, and Morality. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hartley, T. 1994. The Foundations of European Community Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Harvey, J., et al. 1917. Competition: A Study in Human Motive. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Harvey, P. 1990. An Introduction to Buddhism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Harvey, P. 2000. An Introduction to Buddhist Ethics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. 1995. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons’. Mind 104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. 1997. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons – A Reply’. Mind 106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D., and , M. McPherson. 1993. ‘Taking Ethics Seriously: Economics and Contemporary Moral Philosophy’. Journal of Economic Literature 31Google Scholar
Hausman, D., and M. McPherson. 1998. ‘Economics and Ethics’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 3
Hawk, B. 1994. United States, Common Market and International Antitrust: A Comparative Guide. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. 1982. Law, Legislation and Liberty. London: Routledge & Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Head, J. 1974a. ‘Merit Goods Revisited’. In Head (1974c)
Head, J. 1974b. ‘On Merit Goods’. In Head (1974c)
Head, J. 1974c. Public Goods and Public Welfare. Durham, NC: Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Head, J. 1978. ‘Common Knowledge’. Philosophical Quarterly 28Google Scholar
Hegel, G. 1952. The Philosophy of Right. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heiner, R. 1986. ‘Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules’. Journal of Legal Studies 15Google Scholar
Hempel, C. 1983. ‘Studies in the Logic of Confirmation’. In Achinstein (1983)
Hertzberg, L. 1988. ‘On the Attitude of Trust’. Inquiry 31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. 1981. ‘A Manifesto’. In , J. Hicks, Wealth and Welfare. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 1991. Autonomy and Self-Respect. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 2002a. ‘Happiness and Human Flourishing’. In Hill (2002b)
Hill, T. 2002b. Human Welfare and Moral Worth: Kantian Perspectives. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 2002c. ‘Kantian Analysis: From Duty to Autonomy’. In Hill (2000b)
Hobbes, T. 1968. Leviathan. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Holton, R. 1994. ‘Deciding to Trust, Coming to Believe’. Australasian Journal of Philosophy 72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooker, B. 1995. ‘Rule-Consequentialism, Incoherence, Fairness’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, B. 1991. ‘Showoffs, Achievers, and Rivals’. Philosophy of Education 47Google Scholar
Howerth, I. 1912. ‘Competition, Natural and Industrial’. International Journal of Ethics 22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huizinga, J. 1949. Homo Ludens. London: Routledge & Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Hume, D. 1963. ‘Of the Original Contract’. In , D. Hume, Essays, Moral, Political and Literary. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hurka, T. 1993. Perfectionism. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hurley, S. 1989. Natural Reasons. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hylland, A. 1989. ‘The Purpose and Significance of Social Choice Theory: Some General Remarks and an Application to the “Lady Chatterley” Problem’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Inglehart, R. 1996. ‘The Diminishing Utility of Economic Growth: From Maximizing Security Toward Maximizing Subjective Well-Being’. Critical Review 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johansson, P. 1991. An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joliet, R. 1967. The Rule of Reason in Antitrust Law: American, German and Common Market Laws in Comparative Perspective. The Hague: NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joshua, J. 2003. ‘The UK's New Cartel Offence and Its Implications for EC Competition Law: A Tangled Web’. European Law Review 28Google Scholar
Kagan, S. 1998. Normative Ethics. Boulder: Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and J. Snell. 1990. ‘Predicting Utility’. In , R. Hogarth (ed.), Insights in Decision Making. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1990. ‘Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk’. In , P. Moser (ed.), Rationality in Action: Contemporary Approaches. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and C. Varey. 1993. ‘Notes on the Psychology of Utility’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Kane, R. 1974. Through the Moral Maze: Searching for Absolute Values in a Pluralistic World. New York: Paragon HouseGoogle Scholar
Katz, A., and , L. Teitelbaum. 1978. ‘PINS Jurisdiction, the Vagueness Doctrine, and the Rule of Law’. Indiana Law Journal 53Google Scholar
Kavka, G. 1986. Hobbesian Moral and Political Theory. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Kawall, J. 1999. ‘The Experience Machine and Mental-State Theories of Well-Being’. Journal of Value Inquiry 33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kay, J. 2003. The Truth About Markets. London: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Keating, J. 1964. ‘Sportsmanship as a Moral Category’. Ethics 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keita, L. 1999. ‘Welfare Economics and Positive Neoclassical Economics’. Journal of Value Inquiry 33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, M. 1992. ‘The Phantom Reliance Interest in Contract Damages’. Wisconsin Law Review
Kelman, M. 1987. A Guide to Critical Legal Studies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Kelman, S. 1981. ‘Regulation and Paternalism’. Public Policy 29Google ScholarPubMed
Kemmerling, A. 1986. ‘Utterer's Meaning Revisited’. In , R. Grandy and , R. Warner (eds.), Philosophical Grounds of Rationality: Intentions, Categories, Ends. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, D. 1973. ‘Legal Formality’. Journal of Legal Studies 2Google Scholar
Kennedy, D. 1976. ‘Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication’. Harvard Law Review 89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kew, F. 1978. ‘Values in Competitive Games’. Quest 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, J. 1971. ‘Causes and Events: Mackie on Causation’. Journal of Philosophy 68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, K. 1991. ‘Does Competition Lead to Improved Quality in Education?Philosophy of Education 47Google Scholar
Klein, P. 1976. ‘Knowledge, Causality, and Defeasibility’. Journal of Philosophy 73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinig, J. 1982. Philosophical Issues in Education. London: Croom HelmGoogle Scholar
Kluge, E. 1991. ‘Competition and Function: The Canada–US Free Trade Agreement and the Philosophy of Health Care’. Business and Professional Ethics Journal 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knapp, C. 1984. ‘The Promise of the Future – and Vice Versa: Some Reflections on the Metamorphosis of Contract Law’. Michigan Law Review 82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. 1956. On the History and Method of Economics. Chicago: Chicago University PressGoogle Scholar
Kohn, A. 1992. No Contest (revised edition). Boston, MA: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Kolnai, A. 1965. ‘Games and Aims’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 66Google Scholar
Korah, V. 1986. ‘EEC Competition Policy – Legal Form or Economic Efficiency’. Current Legal Problems 39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korsgaard, C. 1996. Creating the Kingdom of Ends. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kymlicka, W. 2002. Contemporary Political Philosophy: An Introduction (2nd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lagenspetz, O. 1992. ‘Legitimacy and Trust’. Philosophical Investigations 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, R. 1994. ‘Quality of Life and Quality of Persons: A New Role for Government?Political Theory 22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larmore, C. 1987. Patterns of Moral Complexity. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, H. 1980. Beyond Economic Man: A New Foundation for Microeconomics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Leibniz, G. 1875–90. Philosophische Schriften. Leipzig: GerhardtGoogle Scholar
Lentz, T., and R. Cornelius. 1950. ‘All Together: A Manual of Cooperative Games’. Photocopy. Attitude Research Laboratory, St Louis, MO
Lever, J. 1969. ‘Bipartite Arrangements and the Restrictive Trades Practices Acts 1956 and 1968’. Law Quarterly Review 85Google Scholar
Levmore, S. (ed.). 1994. Foundations of Tort Law. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, C., and , C. Langford. 1959. Symbolic Logic (2nd edition). New York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1973. Counterfactuals. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1989. ‘Dispositional Theories of Value’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 63Google Scholar
Lieberman, M. 1998. Commitment, Value, and Moral Realism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, R. 1989. An Introduction to Positive Economics (7th edition). London: Weidenfeld and NicolsonGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, R., and , K. Lancaster. 1956. ‘The General Theory of Second Best’. Review of Economic Studies 24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, D. 1957. A Critique of Welfare Economics (2nd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Loar, B. 1981. Mind and Meaning. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lomasky, L. 1987. Persons, Rights, and the Moral Community. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lomasky, L. 2000. ‘Liberty and Welfare Goods: Reflections on Clashing Liberalisms’. Journal of Ethics 4Google Scholar
Luce, R., and , H. Raiffa. 1985. Games and Decisions. New York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Luschen, G. 1970. ‘Cooperation, Association and Contest’. Journal of Conflict Resolution 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyon, L., et al. 1939. Government and Economic Life. Washington, DC: Brookings InstitutionGoogle Scholar
Lyons, D. 1965. Forms and Limits of Utilitarianism. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyons, D. 1994. ‘Benevolence and Justice in Mill’. In , D. Lyons, Rights, Welfare, and Mill's Moral Theory. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
MacCallum, G. 1993. ‘Competition and Moral Philosophy’. In , G. MacCallum, Legislative Intent and Other Essays on Law, Politics, and Morality. Madison: University of Wisconsin PressGoogle Scholar
MacCormick, N. 1972. ‘Voluntary Obligations and Normative Powers (I)’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 46Google Scholar
MacCormick, N. 1982. Legal Right and Social Democracy. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
MacCulloch, A. 2003. ‘The Cartel Offence and the Criminalisation of United Kingdom Competition Law’. Journal of Business Law, November 2003
MacDonald, K., and , R. Thompson. 2003. ‘Dishonest Agreements’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Mack, R. 1965. ‘The Components of Social Conflict’. Social Problems 22Google Scholar
Mackie, J. 1974. The Cement of the Universe. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
McMahon, C. 1989. ‘Promising and Coordination’. American Philosophical Quarterly 26Google Scholar
McMurtry, J. 1984. ‘Free Enterprise, Rationality and Competition’. Journal of Business Ethics 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMurtry, J. 1991. ‘How Competition Goes Wrong’. Journal of Applied Philosophy 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNaughton, D. 1998. ‘Consequentialism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 2
McNaughton, D., and , P. Rawling. 2001. ‘Achievement, Welfare and Consequentialism’. Analysis 61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malina, M., and , R. Steuer. 1991. ‘Trial Lawyers and ARCO: Jurisprudentially Inconsistent Approaches to Per Se Illegality’. Fordham Law Review 59Google Scholar
Martin, J. 1985. Hanbury and Maudsley: Modern Equity (12th edition). London: Stevens & SonsGoogle Scholar
Mason, E. 1939. ‘Price and Production Policies of Large-Scale Enterprise’. American Economic Review 29Google Scholar
May, M., and , L. Doob. 1937. Cooperation and Competition. New York: Social Science Research CouncilGoogle Scholar
Mead, M. 2003. Cooperation and Competition Among Primitive Peoples. New Brunswick: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Meakin, D. 1986. ‘The Moral Status of Competition: An Issue of Concern for Physical Educators’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelman, J. 1983. ‘Some Ethical Consequences of Economic Competition’. Journal of Business Ethics 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P. 1981. ‘An Axiomatic Characterization of Common Knowledge’. Econometrica 49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, J. 1972a. Utilitarianism. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Mill, J. 1972b. On Liberty. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Miller, D. 1976. Social Justice. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Miller, H., and , W. Williams (eds.). 1982. The Limits of Utilitarianism. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota PressGoogle Scholar
Miller, S. 1992. ‘Joint Action’. Philosophical Papers 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millgram, E. 2000. ‘What's the Use of Utility?Philosophy and Public Affairs 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, A. 2000. ‘Objective Human Goods’. In Crisp and Hooker (2000)
Moore, A., and , R. Crisp. 1996. ‘Welfarism in Moral Theory’. Australasian Journal of Philosophy 74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, G. 1959. Principia Ethica. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Morris, C. 1991. ‘Some Notes on “Reliance”’. Minnesota Law Review 75Google Scholar
Morris, C. 1996. ‘Well-Being, Reasons, and the Politics of Law’. Ethics 106Google Scholar
Munzer, S. 1998. ‘Property’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 7
Musgrave, R. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. 1950. ‘The Bargaining Problem’. Econometrica 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naylor, F. 1975. ‘Comprehensive Mythology’. In , D. Cox and , R. Boyson (eds.), Black Paper 1975. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Neale, A., and , D. Goyder. 1980. The Antitrust Laws of the USA: A Study of Competition Enforced by Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
New, B. 1999. ‘Paternalism and Public Policy’. Economics and Philosophy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nielsen, L. 1984. ‘Common Knowledge, Communication, and Convergence of Beliefs’. Mathematical Social Sciences 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nove, A. 1983. The Economics of Feasible Socialism. London: George Allen & UnwinCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, R. 1974. Anarchy, State, and Utopia. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Nussbaum, M., and , A. Sen (eds.). 1993. The Quality of Life. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odudu, O. 2001a. ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention’. European Law Review 26Google Scholar
Odudu, O. 2001b. ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): The Object Requirement Revisited’. European Law Review 26Google Scholar
Office of Fair Trading. 2003a. Market Investigation References (Guidance About the Making of References Under Part 4 of the Enterprise Act). London: Office of Fair Trading
Office of Fair Trading 2003b. Mergers: Substantive Assessment Guidance. London: Office of Fair Trading
Ong, W. 1981. Fighting for Life. Ithaca: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Oppenheim, C., , G. Weston and , T. McCarthy (eds.). 1981. Federal Antitrust Laws: Cases, Text, and Commentary. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Overvold, M. 1980. ‘Self-Interest and the Concept of Self-Sacrifice’. Canadian Journal of Philosophy 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Overvold, M. 1982. ‘Self-Interest and Getting What You Want’. In Miller and Williams (1982)
Parfit, D. 1984. Reasons and Persons. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Parfit, D. 1997. ‘Reasons and Motivation’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 71Google Scholar
Parikh, R., and , P. Krasucki. 1990. ‘Communication, Consensus and Knowledge’. Journal of Economic Theory 52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, D. 1992. ‘The Value of a Promise’. Law and Philosophy 11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peacocke, C. 1979. Holistic Explanation. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Peretz, G., and , J. Lewis. 2003. ‘Go Directly to Jail: Losing Badly in “Monopoly”’. New Law Journal, 24 January 2003Google Scholar
Perry, L. 1975. ‘Competition and Cooperation’. British Journal of Educational Studies 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, P. 1998. ‘Desire’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 3
Phlips, L. 1995. Competition Policy: A Game-Theoretic Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pietroski, P. 1993. ‘Prima Facie Obligations, Ceteris Paribus Laws in Moral Theory’. Ethics 103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. 2002. The Economics of Welfare. New Brunswick: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Piraino, T. 1991. ‘Reconciling the Per Se Rule and Rule of Reason Approaches to Antitrust Analysis’. Southern California Law Review 64Google Scholar
Piraino, T. 1994. ‘Making Sense of the Rule of Reason: A New Standard for Section 1 of the Sherman Act’. Vanderbilt Law Review 47Google Scholar
Plant, R. 1991. Modern Political Thought. Malden, MA: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. 1979. ‘Utilitarianism, Economics, and Legal Theory’. Journal of Legal Studies 8Google Scholar
Posner, R. 1986. Economic Analysis of Law. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. 1994. ‘The Concept of Corrective Justice in Recent Theories of Tort Law’. In Levmore (1994)
Posner, R. 2001. Antitrust Law (2nd edition). Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Postow, B. 1980. ‘A Possible Ground of Political Obligation’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prichard, H. 1949a. ‘Exchanging’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prichard, H. 1949b. Moral Obligation. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Prichard, H. 1949c. ‘The Obligation to Keep a Promise’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prichard, H. 1949d. ‘The Time of an Obligation’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prvulovich, Z. 1982. ‘In Defence of Competition’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, H. 1994. Words and Life. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Qizilbash, M. 1997. ‘Well-Being and Despair: Dante's Ugolino’. Utilitas 9Google Scholar
Qizilbash, M. 1998. ‘The Concept of Well-Being’. Economics and Philosophy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radford, C. 1966. ‘Knowledge – By Examples’. Analysis 27Google Scholar
Radford, C. 1984. ‘I Will, If You Will’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Rappoport, A., and C. Orwant. 1964. ‘Experimental Games: A Review’. In , M. Shubik (ed.), Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior. New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. 1967. ‘Two Concepts of Rules’. In Foot (1967)
Rawls, J. 1972. A Theory of Justice. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. 1982. ‘Social Unity and Primary Goods’. In Sen and Williams (1982)
Rawls, J. 1993. Political Liberalism. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1972. ‘Voluntary Obligations and Normative Powers (II)’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 46Google Scholar
Raz, J. 1977. ‘Promises and Obligations’. In , P. Hacker and , J. Raz (eds.), Law Morality, and Society. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1979. The Authority of Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1984. ‘On the Nature of Rights’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Raz, J. 1986. The Morality of Freedom. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1994a. ‘Duties of Well-Being’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994b. Ethics in the Public Domain: Essays in the Morality of Law and Politics. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1994c. ‘Liberalism, Scepticism, and Democracy’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994d. ‘Liberating Duties’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994e. ‘Rights and Individual Well-Being’. In Raz (1994b)
Reath, A. 1998. ‘Autonomy, Ethical’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 1
Rees, R. 1993. ‘Tacit Collusion’. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reeve, S. 1906. The Cost of Competition. New York: McClure, PhillipsGoogle Scholar
Regan, D. 1985. ‘On Preferences and Promises: A Response to Harsanyi’. Ethics 96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rich, J. 1988. ‘Competition in Education’. Educational Theory 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robins, M. 1984. Promising, Intending, and Moral Autonomy. New York: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Roemer, J. 1996. Theories of Distributive Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Rogers, W. 1994. Winfield & Jolowicz on Tort (14th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Rotenstreich, N. 1972. ‘On Confidence’. Philosophy 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, P. (ed.). 2001. Bellamy and Child: European Community Law of Competition (5th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Russell, B. 1951. New Hopes for a Changing World. London: George Allen & UnwinGoogle Scholar
Sainsbury, M. 1990. Concepts Without Boundaries. London: King's College LondonGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. 1970. Foundations of Economic Analysis. New York: AtheneumGoogle Scholar
Sartorius, R. (ed.). 1983. Paternalism. St Paul: University of Minnesota PressGoogle Scholar
Scanlan, G. 2002. ‘Dishonesty in Corporate Offences: A Need for Reform’. Company Lawyer 23Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1972. ‘A Theory of Freedom of Expression’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1975. ‘Preference and Urgency’. Journal of Philosophy 72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1990. ‘Promises and Practices’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 19Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1993a. ‘The Moral Basis of Interpersonal Comparisons’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Scanlon, T. 1993b. ‘Value, Desire, and Quality of Life’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Scanlon, T. 1998. What We Owe to Each Other. Cambridge, MA: Belknap PressGoogle Scholar
Scanlon, T. 2001. ‘Promises and Contracts’. In Benson (2001a)
Schauer, F. 1991a. ‘Exceptions’. University of Chicago Law Review 58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schauer, F. 1991b. Playing by the Rules. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Schechter, M. 1982. ‘The Rule of Reason in European Competition Law’. Legal Issues in European Integration 1982
Schelling, T. 1980. The Strategy of Conflict (2nd edition). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F., and , D. Ross. 1990. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (3rd edition). Boston: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Scherer, M. 1987. ‘Making the Rule of Reason Analysis More Manageable’. Antitrust Law Journal 56Google Scholar
Schiffer, S. 1972. Meaning. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schiffer, S. 1987. Remnants of Meaning. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Schneewind, J. 1986. ‘The Use of Autonomy in Ethical Theory’. In , T. Helleret al. (eds.), Reconstructing Individualism: Autonomy, Individuality, and the Self in Western Thought. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, C. 1995. ‘From Consumer Choice to Consumer Welfare’. Hastings Center Report, Special Supplement 25Google ScholarPubMed
Schopenhauer, A. 1951. ‘The Vanity of Existence’. In , A. Schopenhauer, Essays from the Parerga and Paralipomena. London: George Allen & UnwinGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, E. 1973. Small Is Beautiful: A Study of Economics as if People Mattered. London: Blond & BriggsGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1975. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: HarperPerennialGoogle Scholar
Schwarze, J. 1992. European Administrative Law. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1981. ‘The Desire for Excitement in Modern Society’. Kyklos 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1992. The Joyless Economy: The Psychology of Human Satisfaction (revised edition). New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Scoccia, D. 1987. ‘Autonomy, Want Satisfaction, and the Justification of Liberal Freedoms’. Canadian Journal of Philosophy 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, J. 1967. ‘How to Derive “Ought” from “Is”’. In Foot (1967)
Searle, J. 1968. ‘Prima Facie Obligations’. In , J. Raz (ed.), Practical Reasoning. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Seel, M. 1997. ‘Well-Being: On a Fundamental Concept of Practical Philosophy’. European Journal of Philosophy 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1981. ‘Plural Utility’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1982a. ‘Behaviour and the Concept of Preference’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982b. ‘Choice, Orderings and Morality’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982c. Choice, Welfare and Measurement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1982d. ‘Equality of What?’ In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982e. ‘The Impossibility of a Paretian Liberal’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982f. ‘Interpersonal Aggregation and Partial Comparability’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982g. ‘Interpersonal Comparisons of Welfare’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982h. ‘Introduction’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982i. ‘Liberty, Unanimity and Rights’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982j. ‘Personal Utilities and Public Judgments: Or What's Wrong with Welfare Economics?’ In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982k. ‘Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioural Foundations of Economic Theory’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1985. ‘Well-Being, Agency and Freedom: The Dewey Lectures 1984’. Journal of Philosophy 82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1993. ‘Capability and Well-Being’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Sen, A. 2002a. ‘Freedom and Social Choice: The Arrow Lectures’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002b. ‘Individual Preference as the Basis of Social Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002c. ‘Internal Consistency of Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002d. ‘Introduction: Rationality and Freedom’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002e. ‘Markets and Freedoms’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002f. ‘Maximisation and the Act of Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002g. ‘Non-Binary Choice and Preference’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002h. ‘The Possibility of Social Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002i. Rationality and Freedom. Cambridge, MA: Belknap PressGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 2002j. ‘Rationality and Uncertainty’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A., and , B. Williams (eds.). 1982. Utilitarianism and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafer-Landau, R. 1995. ‘Vagueness, Borderline Cases and Moral Realism’. American Philosophical Quarterly 32Google Scholar
Shah, R. 1995. ‘Estoppel and Legitimate Expectation’. New Law Journal, 3 November 1995Google Scholar
Sidgwick, H. 1907. The Methods of Ethics (7th edition). London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simmel, G. 1955. Conflict and the Web of Group-Affiliations. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Simmons, A. 1981. ‘Reasonable Expectations and Obligations: A Reply to Postow’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. 1982. Models of Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Singer, P. 1972. ‘Altruism and Commerce: A Defence of Titmuss Against Arrow’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 2Google Scholar
Singh, R. 1994. ‘Making Legitimate Use of Legitimate Expectation’. New Law Journal, 9 September 1994Google Scholar
Skorupski, J. 2000. ‘Quality of Well-Being: Quality of Being’. In Crisp and Hooker (2000)
Smart, J. 1973. ‘An Outline of a System of Utilitarian Ethics’. In , J. Smart and , B. Williams, Utilitarianism: For and Against. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Smith, J. 2002. Smith & Hogan: Criminal Law (10th edition). London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Smith, M. 1994. The Moral Problem. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Smith, N. (ed.). 1982. Mutual Knowledge. London: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Soames, T. 1996. ‘An Analysis of the Principles of Concerted Practice and Collective Dominance: A Distinction without a Difference?European Competition Law Review 17Google Scholar
Sobel, D. 1994. ‘Full Information Accounts of Well-Being’. Ethics 104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobel, D. 1998. ‘Well-Being as the Object of Moral Consideration’. Economics and Philosophy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stalnaker, R. 1991. ‘A Theory of Conditionals’. In , F. Jackson (ed.), Conditionals. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Stocker, M. 1992. Plural and Conflicting Values. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoljar, S. 1988. ‘Promise, Expectation and Agreement’. Cambridge Law Journal 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strasser, M. 1985. ‘Dependence, Reliance and Abortion’. Philosophical Quarterly 35CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Strawson, P. 1971. ‘Intention and Convention in Speech Acts’. In , J. Searle (ed.), The Philosophy of Language. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, L. 1977. Handbook of the Law of Antitrust. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, L. 1987. ‘The Viability of the Current Law on Horizontal Restraints’. California Law Review 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sumner, L. 1996. Welfare, Happiness, and Ethics. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Taggart, M. 1996. ‘Legitimate Expectation and Treaties in the High Court of Australia’. Law Quarterly Review 112Google Scholar
Tännsjö, T. 1996. ‘Classical Hedonistic Utilitarianism’. Philosophical Studies 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, S., and , J. Mansell. 2003. ‘White-Collar Crime – Caught in the Act’. Legal Week 5Google Scholar
Thompson, G. 1972. ‘Effects of Cooperation and Competition on Public Learning’. Educational Research (British) 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, M. 1983. ‘From Representation to Expectation: Estoppel as a Cause of Action’. Cambridge Law Journal 42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, J. 1994. ‘Remarks on Causation and Liability’. In Levmore (1994)
Titmuss, R. 1971. The Gift Relationship: From Human Blood to Social Policy. London: PantheonGoogle Scholar
Treitel, G. 1995. The Law of Contract (9th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Tuomela, R. 1995. The Importance of Us. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. 1981. ‘Choice, Preference and Welfare: Some Psychological Observations’. Paper presented at a colloquium on ‘Foundations of Social Choice Theory’, Ustaoset (Norway)
Ullmann-Margalit, E. 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Unger, P. 1996. Living High and Letting Die: Our Illusion of Innocence. New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanDeVeer, D. 1986. Paternalistic Intervention: The Moral Bounds of Benevolence. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Praag, B. 1993. ‘The Relativity of the Welfare Concept’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Varian, H. 1978. Microeconomic Analysis. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Velleman, D. 2000a. ‘Deciding How to Decide’. In Velleman (2000c)
Velleman, D. 2000b. ‘How to Share an Intention’. In Velleman (2000c)
Velleman, D. 2000c. The Possibility of Practical Reason. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Vickers, J. 1995. ‘Concepts of Competition’. Oxford Economic Papers 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warnock, G. 1971. The Object of Morality. London: MethuenGoogle Scholar
Weale, A. 1978. ‘Paternalism and Social Policy’. Journal of Social Policy 7CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Weale, A. 1998. ‘Welfare’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 9
Weinstein, N. 1982. ‘Community Noise Problems: Evidence Against Adaptation’. Journal of Environmental Psychology 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, R. 1996. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons: A Critical Note’. Mind 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, R. 1998. ‘Do Utility Comparisons Pose a Problem?Philosophical Studies 92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wertheimer, B. 1984. ‘Rethinking the Rule of Reason: From Professional Engineers to NCAA’. Duke Law Journal
Whish, R. 1993. Competition Law (3rd edition). London, ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Whish, R. 2003. Competition Law (5th edition). London: LexisNexis UKGoogle Scholar
Whish, R., and B. Sufrin. 1987. ‘Article 85 and the Rule of Reason’. Oxford Yearbook of European Law 1987
Williams, B. 1978. Descartes: The Project of Pure Enquiry. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Williams, B. 1985. Ethics and the Limits of Philosophy. London: FontanaGoogle Scholar
Williams, B. 2002. Truth and Truthfulness. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Williams, G. 1983. Textbook of Criminal Law (2nd edition). London: Stevens & SonsGoogle Scholar
Williamson, T. 1994. Vagueness. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Wilson, J. 1989. ‘Competition’. Journal of Moral Education 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolff, J. Unpublished. ‘Libertarianism, Utility and Economic Competition’
Wood Hutchinson, D. 1984. ‘Antitrust 1984: Five Decisions in Search of a Theory’. The Supreme Court Review 1984
Woozley, A. 1981. ‘Promises, Promises’. Mind 90Google Scholar
Young, R. 1980. ‘Autonomy and the Inner Self’. American Philosophical Quarterly 17Google Scholar
Achinstein, P. 1983. The Concept of Evidence. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Acton, H. 1993. ‘The Morals of Markets: An Ethical Exploration’. In , H. Acton, The Morals of Markets and Related Essays. Indianapolis: Liberty PressGoogle Scholar
Alexander, L. 1985. ‘Pursuing the Good – Indirectly’. Ethics 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allingham, M. 2002. Choice Theory: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, W. 1989. ‘Varieties of Privileged Access’. In , W. Alston, Epistemic Justification: Essays in the Theory of Knowledge. Ithaca: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Altham, J. 1985. ‘Wicked Promises’. In , I. Hacking (ed.), Exercises in Analysis: Essays by Students of Casimir Lewy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Anonymous. 1983. ‘Fixing the Price Fixing Confusion: A Rule of Reason Approach’. Yale Law Journal 92
Archard, D. 1993. ‘Self-Justifying Paternalism’. Journal of Value Inquiry 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ardal, P. 1976. ‘Promises and Reliance’. Dialogue 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Areeda, P. 1985. ‘The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule’. Antitrust Law Journal 54Google Scholar
Areeda, P. 1989. Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Arneson, R. 1998. ‘Paternalism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 7
Arneson, R. 2002. ‘The End of Welfare As We Know It? Scanlon Versus Welfarist Consequentialism’. Social Theory and Practice 28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1951. ‘An Extension of the Basic Theorems of Classical Welfare Economics’. Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Symposium. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values (2nd edition). New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1979. The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1981. Promises, Morals, and Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. 1986. Essays on Contract. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Audi, R. 1989. Practical Reasoning. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. 1976. ‘Agreeing to Disagree’. Annals of Statistics 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austin, J. 1962. Sense and Sensibilia. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Bach, K. 1995. ‘Terms of Agreement’. Ethics 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baier, A. 1985. Postures of the Mind. Minneapolis: Minnesota University PressGoogle Scholar
Baird, D., , H. Gertner and , R. Picker. 1994. Game Theory and the Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. 1973. Political Argument. London: Routledge and Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. 1986. ‘Lady Chatterley's Lover and Doctor Fischer's Bomb Party: Liberalism, Pareto Optimality, and the Problem of Objectionable Preferences’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Beale, H., et al. (eds.). 1999. Chitty on Contracts (28th edition). vol. 1. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Beals, A., and , B. Siegel. 1966. Divisiveness and Social Conflict. Palo Alto: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Beard, D. 2003. ‘The Cartel Criminal Offence’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Beatson, J. 1987. ‘Benefit, Reliance and the Structure of Unjust Enrichment’. Current Legal Problems 40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benn, S. 1971. ‘Freedom, Autonomy, and the Concept of a Person’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 12Google Scholar
Bennett, J. 1976. Linguistic Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Benson, P. (ed.). 2001a. The Theory of Contract Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, P. 2001b. ‘The Unity of Contract Law’. In Benson (2001a)
Bentham, J. 1948. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, L. 1962. Aggression: A Social Psychological Analysis. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, M. 1998. ‘Well-Being’. American Philosophical Quarterly 35Google Scholar
Beschle, R. 1987. ‘“What Never? Well, Hardly Ever”: Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Antitrust Illegality’. Hastings Law Journal 38Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1994. Playing Fair. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 1998. Just Playing. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., and A. Brandenburger. 1990. ‘Common Knowledge and Game Theory’. In , K. Binmore (ed.), Essays on Foundations of Game Theory. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Bishop, S., and , M. Walker. 2002. The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1987a. ‘Induction and Experience: An Alleged Infinite Regress’. Fundamenta Scientiae 7Google Scholar
Black, O. 1987b. The Infinite Regress of Justification. PhD thesis, University of London
Black, O. 1988. ‘Infinite Regresses of Justification’. International Philosophical Quarterly 28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1992. ‘Communication and Obligation in Arrangements and Concerted Practices’. European Competition Law Review 13Google Scholar
Black, O. 1993. ‘Competition and Negative Obligation’. European Competition Law Review 14Google Scholar
Black, O. 1994a. ‘Ends, Desires and Rationality’. International Philosophical Quarterly 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1994b. ‘“Most Favoured Customer” Clauses: Application of the Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1976’. European Competition Law Review 15Google Scholar
Black, O. 1995a. ‘Accepting a Relevant Restriction by Accepting Something Else’. European Competition Law Review 16Google Scholar
Black, O. 1995b. ‘What Is the Difference Between a Term and a Restriction? – Associated Dairies and the Scope of Section 9(3) RTPA’. European Competition Law Review 16Google Scholar
Black, O. 1996a. ‘Concertation and Coordination: A Distinction without a Difference?European Competition Law Review 17Google Scholar
Black, O. 1996b. ‘Legal Validity and the Infinite Regress’. Law and Philosophy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 1997. ‘Per Se Rules and Rules of Reason: What Are They?European Competition Law Review 18Google Scholar
Black, O. 1998. ‘The Relation Between Reliance and Obligation’. In , P. Kampits (eds.), Applied Ethics. Kirchberg am Wechsel: Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein SocietyGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2002. ‘What Makes Me the Person I Am’. Dialegesthai, November 2002Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003a. ‘Collusion and Coordination in EC Merger Control’. European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003b. ‘Concerted Practices, Joint Action and Reliance’. European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003c. ‘Grades of Correlation: The Spectrum from Independent Action to Collusion, and Its Implications for Antitrust’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003d. ‘Independent Promises and the Rescission of Contracts’. Legal Studies 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2003e. ‘Infinite Regresses, Infinite Beliefs’. In , W. Löffler and , P. Weingartner (eds.), Knowledge and Belief. Kirchberg am Wechsel: Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein SocietyGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2003f. ‘Joint Action, Reliance and the Law’. King's College Law Journal 14Google Scholar
Black, O. 2003g. ‘What Is an Agreement?European Competition Law Review 24Google Scholar
Black, O. 2004a. ‘Agreements, Undertakings and Practical Reason’. Legal Theory 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, O. 2004b. ‘Reliance and Obligation’. Ratio Juris 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, R., and , N. Bruce. 1984. Welfare Economics. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Boardman, W. 1987. ‘Coordination and the Moral Obligation to Obey the Law’. Ethics 97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bock, B. 1990. ‘An Economist Considers Some Basic Issues of Antitrust Law in the United States’. European Competition Law Review 11Google Scholar
Bork, R. 1965. ‘The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division’ (Part 1). Yale Law Journal 74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bork, R. 1966. ‘The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Division’ (Part 2). Yale Law Journal 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bork, R. 1978. The Antitrust Paradox. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Boulding, K. 1962. Conflict and Defense. New York: HarperGoogle Scholar
Brandt, R. 1979. A Theory of the Good and the Right. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Brandt, R. 1982. ‘Two Concepts of Utility’. In Miller and Williams (1982)
Bratman, M. 1999a. Faces of Intention. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratman, M. 1999b. ‘I Intend That We J’. In Bratman (1999a)
Bratman, M. 1999c. Intentions, Plans, and Practical Reason. Stanford: CSLI PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Bratman, M. 1999d. ‘Shared Cooperative Activity’. In Bratman (1999a)
Bratman, M. 1999e. ‘Shared Intention’. In Bratman (1999a)
Brickman, P., and D. Campbell. 1971. ‘Hedonic Relativism and Planning the Good Society’. In , M. Appley (ed.), Adaptation-Level Theory: A Symposium. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brickman, P., et al. 1978. ‘Lottery Winners and Accident Victims: Is Happiness Relative?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 36CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bright, C. 1995. ‘Deregulation of EC Competition Policy: Rethinking Article 85(1)’. New York: Fordham Corporate Law Institute
Brock, D. 1993. ‘Quality of Life Measures in Health Care and Medical Ethics’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Broome, J. 1979. ‘Choice and Value in Economics’. Oxford Economic Papers 30Google Scholar
Broome, J. 1991a. ‘Utility’. Economics and Philosophy 7Google Scholar
Broome, J. 1991b. Weighing Goods: Equality, Uncertainty and Time. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2000. ‘Normative Requirements’. In , J. Dancy (ed.), Normativity. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2001a. ‘Are Intentions Reasons? And How Should We Cope With Incommensurable Values?’ In , C. Morris and , A. Ripstein (eds.), Practical Rationality and Preference: Essays for David Gauthier. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2001b. ‘Normative Practical Reasoning’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 75Google Scholar
Broome, J. 2002. ‘Practical Reasoning’. In , J. Bermùdez and , A. Millar (eds.), Reason and Nature: Essays in the Theory of Rationality. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Broome, J. 2004. ‘Reasons’. In , R. Wallaceet al. (eds.), Reason and Value: Essays on the Moral Philosophy of Joseph Raz. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Brownson, W. 1974. ‘The Structure of Competition in the School and Its Consequences’. Philosophy of Education 30Google Scholar
Brunet, E. 1984. ‘Streamlining Antitrust Litigation by “Facial Examination” of Restraints: The Burger Court and the Per Se Rule of Reason Distinction’. Washington Law Review 60Google Scholar
Buchanan, A. 1985. Ethics, Efficiency, and the Market. Totowa: Rowman & AllanheldGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, A., and , D. Brock. 1990. Deciding for Others: The Ethics of Surrogate Decision Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrows, P. 1993. ‘Patronising Paternalism’. Oxford Economic Papers 45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrows, P. 1995. ‘Analyzing Legal Paternalism’. International Review of Law and Economics 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caillois, R. 2001. Man, Play and Games. Urbana: University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
Campbell, A. 1981. The Sense of Well-Being in America: Recent Patterns and Trends. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Cane, P. 1992. An Introduction to Administrative Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Cartwright, J. 1984. ‘An Evidentiary Theory of Promises’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Castañeda, H. 1999. The Phenomeno-Logic of the I. Bloomington: Indiana University PressGoogle Scholar
Chang, R. (ed.). 1997. Incommensurability, Incomparability, and Practical Reason. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Chisholm, R. 1976. Person and Object. Chicago: Open CourtGoogle Scholar
Christman, J. (ed.). 1989. The Inner Citadel: Essays on Individual Autonomy. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Cohen, G. 1977. ‘Labor, Leisure, and a Distinctive Contradiction of Advanced Capitalism’. In , G. Dworkinet al. (eds.), Markets and Morals. Washington, DC: Hemisphere Publishing CoGoogle Scholar
Cohen, G. 1993. ‘Equality of What? On Welfare, Goods, and Capabilities’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Cohen, M. (ed.). 1984. Ronald Dworkin and Contemporary Jurisprudence. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. 1987. ‘Competition and Cooperation’. Ethics 98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Combs, A. 1979. Myths in Education. Boston: Allyn and BaconGoogle Scholar
Competition Commission. 1998. Ladbroke Group Plc and the Coral Betting Business: A Report on the Merger Situation. London: Competition Commission
Competition Commission 2003a. Merger References: Competition Commission Guidelines. London: Competition Commission
Competition Commission 2003b. Market Investigation References: Competition Commission Guidelines. London: Competition Commission
Confederation of British Industry. 1995. Loosening the Strait-Jacket: CBI Proposals for Reform of the Scope and Administration of Article 85. London: Confederation of British Industry
Cooke, E. 1995. ‘Reliance and Estoppel’. Law Quarterly Review 111Google Scholar
Cooke, P., and , D. Oughton. 1993. The Common Law of Obligations. London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Cooley, C. 1899. ‘Personal Competition’. American Economic Association Studies 4Google Scholar
Cooper, G. 1993. ‘The Competition Controversy in Community Ecology’. Biology and Philosophy 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craig, E. 1990. Knowledge and the State of Nature. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Craig, E. (ed.). 1998. Routledge Encyclopedia of Philosophy. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Craig, P. 1992. ‘Legitimate Expectations: A Conceptual Analysis’. Law Quarterly Review 108Google Scholar
Crampton, P. 1994. ‘Alternative Approaches to Competition Law: Consumers’ Surplus, Total Surplus, Total Welfare and Non-Efficiency Goals’. World Competition 17Google Scholar
Criminal Law Revision Committee. 1966. Eighth Report: Theft and Related Offences (1966 Cmnd 2977). London: HMSO
Crisp, R. 1998. ‘Virtue Ethics’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 9
Crisp, R. 2000. ‘Utilitarianism and Accomplishment’. Analysis 60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R. 2001. ‘Utilitarianism and Accomplishment Revisited’. Analysis 61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R., and , B. Hooker (eds.). 2000. Well-Being and Morality: Essays in Honour of James Griffin. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Crisp, R., and , M. Slote (eds.). 1997. Virtue Ethics. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Dahlke, H. 1964. ‘Cooperation’. In , J. Gould and , W. Kolb (eds.), Dictionary of the Social Sciences. London: TavistockGoogle Scholar
Daniels, N. 1979. ‘Wide Reflective Equilibrium and Theory Acceptance in Ethics’. Journal of Philosophy 76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darwall, S. 2002. Welfare and Rational Care. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, D. 1980a. ‘Causal Relations’. In Davidson (1980b)
Davidson, D. 1980b. Essays on Actions and EventsOxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Davidson, D. 1980c. ‘How Is Weakness of the Will Possible?’ In Davidson (1980b)
Davies, S. 1997. ‘Two Conceptions of Welfare: Voluntarism and Incorporationism’. Social Philosophy and Policy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, C. 1995. ‘Estoppel – Reliance and Remedy’. Conveyancer and Property Lawyer 59Google Scholar
Dean, N. 2003. ‘Creating a Stir’. New Law Journal, 13 June 2003Google Scholar
Dearden, R. 1972. ‘Competition in Education’. Proceedings of the Philosophy of Education Society of Great Britain 6Google Scholar
Demarco, J., and , R. Fox. 1992. ‘Putting Pressure on Promises’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moor, A. 1986. ‘Contract and Agreement in English and French Law’. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 6Google Scholar
De Moor, A. 1987. ‘Are Contracts Promises?’ In , J. Eekelaar and , J. Bell (eds.), Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Department of Trade and Industry. 2001. Productivity and Enterprise: A World Class Competition Regime. London: Department of Trade and Industry
Deutsch, M. 1973. The Resolution of Conflict: Constructive and Destructive Processes. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Deutscher, I. 1952. ‘Socialist Competition’. Foreign Affairs 30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diener, E. 1984. ‘Subjective Well-Being’. Psychological Bulletin 95CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Diogenes Laertius. 1980. Lives of Eminent Philosophers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Dixit, A., and , S. Skeath. 1999. Games of Strategy. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Downie, R. 1985. ‘Three Accounts of Promising’. Philosophical Quarterly 35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downie, R., and , E. Telfer. 1971. ‘Autonomy’. Philosophy 15Google Scholar
Dummett, M. 1978. ‘Truth’. In , M. Dummett, Truth and Other Enigmas. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Duncan, O. 1975. ‘Does Money Buy Satisfaction?Social Indicators Research 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, G. 1972. ‘Paternalism’. Monist 56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, G. 1988. The Theory and Practice of Autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1978. Taking Rights Seriously. London: DuckworthGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1986a. Law's Empire. London: FontanaGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. 1986b. A Matter of Principle. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Easterbrook, F. 1984a. ‘The Limits of Antitrust’. Texas Law Review 63Google Scholar
Easterbrook, F. 1984b. ‘Vertical Arrangements and the Rule of Reason’. Antitrust Law Journal 53Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. 1974. ‘Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence’. In , P. David and , M. Reder (eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, I., and , R. Posner. 1974. ‘An Economic Analysis of Legal Rulemaking’. Journal of Legal Studies 3Google Scholar
Elliott, D. 1982. ‘Dishonesty in Theft: A Dispensable Concept’. Criminal Law Review
Elster, J. 1985. Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. 1989. ‘The Market and the Forum: Three Varieties of Political Theory’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Elster, J., and , A. Hylland (eds.). 1989a. Foundations of Social Choice Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., and A. Hylland 1989b. ‘Introduction’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Elster, J., and , J. Roemer (eds.). 1993a. Interpersonal Comparisons of Well-Being. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., and J. Roemer 1993b. ‘Introduction’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Faull, J., and , A. Nikpay. 1999. The EC Law of Competition. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1973. Social Philosophy. Upper Saddle River: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1984. Harm to Others. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinberg, J. 1986. Harm to Self. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Feinman, J. 1984a. ‘The Meaning of Reliance: A Historical Perspective’. Wisconsin Law Review
Feinman, J. 1984b. ‘Promissory Estoppel and Judicial Method’. Harvard Law Review 97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feltkamp, R. 2003. ‘Some Reflections on the Structure of the State Aid Rules in the Treaty of Rome’. EC Competition Policy Newsletter 1Google Scholar
Fielding, M. 1976. ‘Against Competition: In Praise of Malleable Analysis and the Subversiveness of Philosophy’. Proceedings of the Philosophy of Education Society of Great Britain 10Google Scholar
Finnis, J. 1980. Natural Law and Natural Rights. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Flew, A. 1983. ‘Competition and Cooperation, Equality and Elites’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, J. 1982. ‘Rethinking Sherman Act Section 1 Analysis: Three Proposals for Reducing the Chaos’. Antitrust Law Journal 49Google Scholar
Fogelin, R. 1983. ‘Richard Price on Promising: A Limited Defence’. Journal of the History of Philosophy 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foot, P. (ed.). 1967. Theories of Ethics. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Foster, E., and , H. Sonnenschein. 1970. ‘Price Distortion and Economic Welfare’. Econometrica 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, E. 1990. ‘The Future of the Per Se Rule: Two Visions at War With One Another’. Washburn Law Journal 29Google Scholar
Fox, E., and , L. Sullivan. 1989. Cases and Materials on Antitrust. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Fox, R., and , J. Demarco. 1993. ‘The Immorality of Promising’. Journal of Value Inquiry 27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. 2003. Microeconomics and Behavior (5th edition). New York: McGraw-Hill IrwinGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, H. 1999a. ‘Autonomy, Necessity, and Love’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Frankfurt, H. 1999b. Necessity, Volition, and Love. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, H. 1999c. ‘On the Necessity of Ideals’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Frankfurt, H. 1999d. ‘On the Usefulness of Final Ends’. In Frankfurt (1999b)
Franklin, D. Unpublished. ‘Valuing Health, Healthcare and Health Equality’
Freeman, P., and , R. Whish (eds.). 2002. Butterworths Competition Law. London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Freeman, S. 1998. ‘Contractarianism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 2
Frege, G. 1952. ‘On Sense and Reference’. In , P. Geach and , M. Black (eds.), Translations from the Philosophical Writings of Gottlob Frege. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Fried, C. 1981. Contract as Promise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Fuller, L. 1969. The Morality of Law. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Fuller, L., and , W. Perdue. 1936. ‘The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages’. Yale Law Journal 46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganz, G. 1986. ‘Legitimate Expectation’. In , C. Harlow (ed.), Public Law and Politics. London, Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Gaus, G. 1998. ‘Why All Welfare States (Including Laissez-Faire Ones) Are Unreasonable’. Social Philosophy and Policy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, D. 1978. ‘The Social Contract as Ideology’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 6Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. 1986. Morals By Agreement. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Geach, P. 1972. Logic Matters. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, J. 1992. ‘Common Knowledge’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gellhorn, E. 1986. Antitrust Law and Economics. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Gellhorn, E., and , T. Tatham. 1985. ‘Making Sense Out of the Rule of Reason’. Case Western Reserve Law Review 35Google Scholar
Gert, B., and , C. Culver. 1976. ‘Paternalistic Behavior’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 6Google ScholarPubMed
Gibbard, A. 1986. ‘Interpersonal Comparisons: Preference, Good, and the Intrinsic Reward of a Life’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society. Cambridge: Polity PressGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1989. On Social Facts. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1996a. ‘Agreements, Coercion, and Obligation’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996b. ‘Is an Agreement an Exchange of Promises?’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996c. Living Together. Lanham: Rowman & LittlefieldGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. 1996d. ‘Notes on the Concept of a Social Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996e. ‘On Language and Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996f. ‘Rationality, Coordination, and Convention’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilbert, M. 1996g. ‘Walking Together: A Paradigmatic Social Phenomenon’. In Gilbert (1996c)
Gilmore, G. 1995. The Death of Contract. Columbus: Ohio State University PressGoogle Scholar
Glover, J. 1990. Causing Death and Saving Lives. Harmondsworth: PenguinGoogle Scholar
Goldman, A. 1995. ‘Simulation and Interpersonal Utility’. Ethics 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, R. 1989. ‘Laundering Preferences’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Goodin, R. 1993. ‘Democracy, Preferences and Paternalism’. Policy Sciences 26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, N. 1973. Fact, Fiction, and Forecast (3rd edition). Indianapolis: Bobbs-MerrillGoogle Scholar
Gordley, G. 1991. The Philosophical Origins of Modern Contract Doctrine. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Goyder, D. 1998. ECCompetition Law (3rd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Greenawalt, K. 1992. Law and Objectivity. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Grice, H. 1957. ‘Meaning’. Philosophical Review 67Google Scholar
Griew, E. 1985. ‘Dishonesty: The Objections to Feely and Ghosh’. Criminal Law Review
Griffin, J. 1986. Well-Being: Its Meaning, Measurement and Moral Importance. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Griffin, J. 1993. ‘Against the Taste Model’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Griffin, J. 2000. ‘Welfare Rights’. Journal of Ethics 4Google Scholar
Hahn, F., and M. Hollis. 1979. ‘Introduction’. In , F. Hahn and , M. Hollis (eds.), Philosophy and Economic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hammond, A., and R. Penrose. 2001. Proposed Criminalisation of Cartels in the UK. London: Office of Fair Trading
Hammond, P. 1995. ‘The Moral Status of Profits and Other Rewards: A Perspective from Modern Welfare Economics’. In , R. Cowan and , M. Rizzo (eds.), Profits and Morality. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hampton, J. 1998. ‘Rationality, Practical’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 8
Handler, M. 1941. A Study of the Construction and Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws. Washington, DC: US GPO, Temporary National Economic CommitteeGoogle Scholar
Hare, R. 1973. ‘Principles’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hargreaves Heap, S., et al. 1992. The Theory of Choice. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Harman, G. 1974. Review of Schiffer (1972). Journal of Philosophy 71Google Scholar
Harman, G. 1986. Change in View. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. 1982. ‘Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour’. In Sen and Williams (1982)
Hart, H. 1961. The Concept of Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, H. 1963. Law, Liberty, and Morality. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hartley, T. 1994. The Foundations of European Community Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Harvey, J., et al. 1917. Competition: A Study in Human Motive. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Harvey, P. 1990. An Introduction to Buddhism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Harvey, P. 2000. An Introduction to Buddhist Ethics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. 1995. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons’. Mind 104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. 1997. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons – A Reply’. Mind 106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D., and , M. McPherson. 1993. ‘Taking Ethics Seriously: Economics and Contemporary Moral Philosophy’. Journal of Economic Literature 31Google Scholar
Hausman, D., and M. McPherson. 1998. ‘Economics and Ethics’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 3
Hawk, B. 1994. United States, Common Market and International Antitrust: A Comparative Guide. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. 1982. Law, Legislation and Liberty. London: Routledge & Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Head, J. 1974a. ‘Merit Goods Revisited’. In Head (1974c)
Head, J. 1974b. ‘On Merit Goods’. In Head (1974c)
Head, J. 1974c. Public Goods and Public Welfare. Durham, NC: Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Head, J. 1978. ‘Common Knowledge’. Philosophical Quarterly 28Google Scholar
Hegel, G. 1952. The Philosophy of Right. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heiner, R. 1986. ‘Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules’. Journal of Legal Studies 15Google Scholar
Hempel, C. 1983. ‘Studies in the Logic of Confirmation’. In Achinstein (1983)
Hertzberg, L. 1988. ‘On the Attitude of Trust’. Inquiry 31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. 1981. ‘A Manifesto’. In , J. Hicks, Wealth and Welfare. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 1991. Autonomy and Self-Respect. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 2002a. ‘Happiness and Human Flourishing’. In Hill (2002b)
Hill, T. 2002b. Human Welfare and Moral Worth: Kantian Perspectives. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, T. 2002c. ‘Kantian Analysis: From Duty to Autonomy’. In Hill (2000b)
Hobbes, T. 1968. Leviathan. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Holton, R. 1994. ‘Deciding to Trust, Coming to Believe’. Australasian Journal of Philosophy 72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooker, B. 1995. ‘Rule-Consequentialism, Incoherence, Fairness’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, B. 1991. ‘Showoffs, Achievers, and Rivals’. Philosophy of Education 47Google Scholar
Howerth, I. 1912. ‘Competition, Natural and Industrial’. International Journal of Ethics 22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huizinga, J. 1949. Homo Ludens. London: Routledge & Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Hume, D. 1963. ‘Of the Original Contract’. In , D. Hume, Essays, Moral, Political and Literary. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hurka, T. 1993. Perfectionism. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hurley, S. 1989. Natural Reasons. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hylland, A. 1989. ‘The Purpose and Significance of Social Choice Theory: Some General Remarks and an Application to the “Lady Chatterley” Problem’. In Elster and Hylland (1989a)
Inglehart, R. 1996. ‘The Diminishing Utility of Economic Growth: From Maximizing Security Toward Maximizing Subjective Well-Being’. Critical Review 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johansson, P. 1991. An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joliet, R. 1967. The Rule of Reason in Antitrust Law: American, German and Common Market Laws in Comparative Perspective. The Hague: NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joshua, J. 2003. ‘The UK's New Cartel Offence and Its Implications for EC Competition Law: A Tangled Web’. European Law Review 28Google Scholar
Kagan, S. 1998. Normative Ethics. Boulder: Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and J. Snell. 1990. ‘Predicting Utility’. In , R. Hogarth (ed.), Insights in Decision Making. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1990. ‘Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk’. In , P. Moser (ed.), Rationality in Action: Contemporary Approaches. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and C. Varey. 1993. ‘Notes on the Psychology of Utility’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Kane, R. 1974. Through the Moral Maze: Searching for Absolute Values in a Pluralistic World. New York: Paragon HouseGoogle Scholar
Katz, A., and , L. Teitelbaum. 1978. ‘PINS Jurisdiction, the Vagueness Doctrine, and the Rule of Law’. Indiana Law Journal 53Google Scholar
Kavka, G. 1986. Hobbesian Moral and Political Theory. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Kawall, J. 1999. ‘The Experience Machine and Mental-State Theories of Well-Being’. Journal of Value Inquiry 33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kay, J. 2003. The Truth About Markets. London: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Keating, J. 1964. ‘Sportsmanship as a Moral Category’. Ethics 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keita, L. 1999. ‘Welfare Economics and Positive Neoclassical Economics’. Journal of Value Inquiry 33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, M. 1992. ‘The Phantom Reliance Interest in Contract Damages’. Wisconsin Law Review
Kelman, M. 1987. A Guide to Critical Legal Studies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Kelman, S. 1981. ‘Regulation and Paternalism’. Public Policy 29Google ScholarPubMed
Kemmerling, A. 1986. ‘Utterer's Meaning Revisited’. In , R. Grandy and , R. Warner (eds.), Philosophical Grounds of Rationality: Intentions, Categories, Ends. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, D. 1973. ‘Legal Formality’. Journal of Legal Studies 2Google Scholar
Kennedy, D. 1976. ‘Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication’. Harvard Law Review 89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kew, F. 1978. ‘Values in Competitive Games’. Quest 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, J. 1971. ‘Causes and Events: Mackie on Causation’. Journal of Philosophy 68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, K. 1991. ‘Does Competition Lead to Improved Quality in Education?Philosophy of Education 47Google Scholar
Klein, P. 1976. ‘Knowledge, Causality, and Defeasibility’. Journal of Philosophy 73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinig, J. 1982. Philosophical Issues in Education. London: Croom HelmGoogle Scholar
Kluge, E. 1991. ‘Competition and Function: The Canada–US Free Trade Agreement and the Philosophy of Health Care’. Business and Professional Ethics Journal 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knapp, C. 1984. ‘The Promise of the Future – and Vice Versa: Some Reflections on the Metamorphosis of Contract Law’. Michigan Law Review 82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. 1956. On the History and Method of Economics. Chicago: Chicago University PressGoogle Scholar
Kohn, A. 1992. No Contest (revised edition). Boston, MA: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Kolnai, A. 1965. ‘Games and Aims’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 66Google Scholar
Korah, V. 1986. ‘EEC Competition Policy – Legal Form or Economic Efficiency’. Current Legal Problems 39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korsgaard, C. 1996. Creating the Kingdom of Ends. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kymlicka, W. 2002. Contemporary Political Philosophy: An Introduction (2nd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lagenspetz, O. 1992. ‘Legitimacy and Trust’. Philosophical Investigations 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, R. 1994. ‘Quality of Life and Quality of Persons: A New Role for Government?Political Theory 22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larmore, C. 1987. Patterns of Moral Complexity. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, H. 1980. Beyond Economic Man: A New Foundation for Microeconomics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Leibniz, G. 1875–90. Philosophische Schriften. Leipzig: GerhardtGoogle Scholar
Lentz, T., and R. Cornelius. 1950. ‘All Together: A Manual of Cooperative Games’. Photocopy. Attitude Research Laboratory, St Louis, MO
Lever, J. 1969. ‘Bipartite Arrangements and the Restrictive Trades Practices Acts 1956 and 1968’. Law Quarterly Review 85Google Scholar
Levmore, S. (ed.). 1994. Foundations of Tort Law. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, C., and , C. Langford. 1959. Symbolic Logic (2nd edition). New York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1973. Counterfactuals. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1989. ‘Dispositional Theories of Value’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 63Google Scholar
Lieberman, M. 1998. Commitment, Value, and Moral Realism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, R. 1989. An Introduction to Positive Economics (7th edition). London: Weidenfeld and NicolsonGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, R., and , K. Lancaster. 1956. ‘The General Theory of Second Best’. Review of Economic Studies 24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, D. 1957. A Critique of Welfare Economics (2nd edition). Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Loar, B. 1981. Mind and Meaning. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lomasky, L. 1987. Persons, Rights, and the Moral Community. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lomasky, L. 2000. ‘Liberty and Welfare Goods: Reflections on Clashing Liberalisms’. Journal of Ethics 4Google Scholar
Luce, R., and , H. Raiffa. 1985. Games and Decisions. New York: Dover PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Luschen, G. 1970. ‘Cooperation, Association and Contest’. Journal of Conflict Resolution 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyon, L., et al. 1939. Government and Economic Life. Washington, DC: Brookings InstitutionGoogle Scholar
Lyons, D. 1965. Forms and Limits of Utilitarianism. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyons, D. 1994. ‘Benevolence and Justice in Mill’. In , D. Lyons, Rights, Welfare, and Mill's Moral Theory. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
MacCallum, G. 1993. ‘Competition and Moral Philosophy’. In , G. MacCallum, Legislative Intent and Other Essays on Law, Politics, and Morality. Madison: University of Wisconsin PressGoogle Scholar
MacCormick, N. 1972. ‘Voluntary Obligations and Normative Powers (I)’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 46Google Scholar
MacCormick, N. 1982. Legal Right and Social Democracy. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
MacCulloch, A. 2003. ‘The Cartel Offence and the Criminalisation of United Kingdom Competition Law’. Journal of Business Law, November 2003
MacDonald, K., and , R. Thompson. 2003. ‘Dishonest Agreements’. Competition Law Journal 2Google Scholar
Mack, R. 1965. ‘The Components of Social Conflict’. Social Problems 22Google Scholar
Mackie, J. 1974. The Cement of the Universe. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
McMahon, C. 1989. ‘Promising and Coordination’. American Philosophical Quarterly 26Google Scholar
McMurtry, J. 1984. ‘Free Enterprise, Rationality and Competition’. Journal of Business Ethics 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMurtry, J. 1991. ‘How Competition Goes Wrong’. Journal of Applied Philosophy 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNaughton, D. 1998. ‘Consequentialism’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 2
McNaughton, D., and , P. Rawling. 2001. ‘Achievement, Welfare and Consequentialism’. Analysis 61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malina, M., and , R. Steuer. 1991. ‘Trial Lawyers and ARCO: Jurisprudentially Inconsistent Approaches to Per Se Illegality’. Fordham Law Review 59Google Scholar
Martin, J. 1985. Hanbury and Maudsley: Modern Equity (12th edition). London: Stevens & SonsGoogle Scholar
Mason, E. 1939. ‘Price and Production Policies of Large-Scale Enterprise’. American Economic Review 29Google Scholar
May, M., and , L. Doob. 1937. Cooperation and Competition. New York: Social Science Research CouncilGoogle Scholar
Mead, M. 2003. Cooperation and Competition Among Primitive Peoples. New Brunswick: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Meakin, D. 1986. ‘The Moral Status of Competition: An Issue of Concern for Physical Educators’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelman, J. 1983. ‘Some Ethical Consequences of Economic Competition’. Journal of Business Ethics 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P. 1981. ‘An Axiomatic Characterization of Common Knowledge’. Econometrica 49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, J. 1972a. Utilitarianism. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Mill, J. 1972b. On Liberty. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Miller, D. 1976. Social Justice. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Miller, H., and , W. Williams (eds.). 1982. The Limits of Utilitarianism. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota PressGoogle Scholar
Miller, S. 1992. ‘Joint Action’. Philosophical Papers 21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millgram, E. 2000. ‘What's the Use of Utility?Philosophy and Public Affairs 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, A. 2000. ‘Objective Human Goods’. In Crisp and Hooker (2000)
Moore, A., and , R. Crisp. 1996. ‘Welfarism in Moral Theory’. Australasian Journal of Philosophy 74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, G. 1959. Principia Ethica. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Morris, C. 1991. ‘Some Notes on “Reliance”’. Minnesota Law Review 75Google Scholar
Morris, C. 1996. ‘Well-Being, Reasons, and the Politics of Law’. Ethics 106Google Scholar
Munzer, S. 1998. ‘Property’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 7
Musgrave, R. 1959. The Theory of Public Finance. New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. 1950. ‘The Bargaining Problem’. Econometrica 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naylor, F. 1975. ‘Comprehensive Mythology’. In , D. Cox and , R. Boyson (eds.), Black Paper 1975. London: DentGoogle Scholar
Neale, A., and , D. Goyder. 1980. The Antitrust Laws of the USA: A Study of Competition Enforced by Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
New, B. 1999. ‘Paternalism and Public Policy’. Economics and Philosophy 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nielsen, L. 1984. ‘Common Knowledge, Communication, and Convergence of Beliefs’. Mathematical Social Sciences 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nove, A. 1983. The Economics of Feasible Socialism. London: George Allen & UnwinCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, R. 1974. Anarchy, State, and Utopia. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Nussbaum, M., and , A. Sen (eds.). 1993. The Quality of Life. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odudu, O. 2001a. ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): Object as Subjective Intention’. European Law Review 26Google Scholar
Odudu, O. 2001b. ‘Interpreting Article 81(1): The Object Requirement Revisited’. European Law Review 26Google Scholar
Office of Fair Trading. 2003a. Market Investigation References (Guidance About the Making of References Under Part 4 of the Enterprise Act). London: Office of Fair Trading
Office of Fair Trading 2003b. Mergers: Substantive Assessment Guidance. London: Office of Fair Trading
Ong, W. 1981. Fighting for Life. Ithaca: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Oppenheim, C., , G. Weston and , T. McCarthy (eds.). 1981. Federal Antitrust Laws: Cases, Text, and Commentary. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Overvold, M. 1980. ‘Self-Interest and the Concept of Self-Sacrifice’. Canadian Journal of Philosophy 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Overvold, M. 1982. ‘Self-Interest and Getting What You Want’. In Miller and Williams (1982)
Parfit, D. 1984. Reasons and Persons. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Parfit, D. 1997. ‘Reasons and Motivation’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 71Google Scholar
Parikh, R., and , P. Krasucki. 1990. ‘Communication, Consensus and Knowledge’. Journal of Economic Theory 52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, D. 1992. ‘The Value of a Promise’. Law and Philosophy 11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peacocke, C. 1979. Holistic Explanation. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Peretz, G., and , J. Lewis. 2003. ‘Go Directly to Jail: Losing Badly in “Monopoly”’. New Law Journal, 24 January 2003Google Scholar
Perry, L. 1975. ‘Competition and Cooperation’. British Journal of Educational Studies 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, P. 1998. ‘Desire’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 3
Phlips, L. 1995. Competition Policy: A Game-Theoretic Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pietroski, P. 1993. ‘Prima Facie Obligations, Ceteris Paribus Laws in Moral Theory’. Ethics 103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. 2002. The Economics of Welfare. New Brunswick: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Piraino, T. 1991. ‘Reconciling the Per Se Rule and Rule of Reason Approaches to Antitrust Analysis’. Southern California Law Review 64Google Scholar
Piraino, T. 1994. ‘Making Sense of the Rule of Reason: A New Standard for Section 1 of the Sherman Act’. Vanderbilt Law Review 47Google Scholar
Plant, R. 1991. Modern Political Thought. Malden, MA: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. 1979. ‘Utilitarianism, Economics, and Legal Theory’. Journal of Legal Studies 8Google Scholar
Posner, R. 1986. Economic Analysis of Law. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. 1994. ‘The Concept of Corrective Justice in Recent Theories of Tort Law’. In Levmore (1994)
Posner, R. 2001. Antitrust Law (2nd edition). Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Postow, B. 1980. ‘A Possible Ground of Political Obligation’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prichard, H. 1949a. ‘Exchanging’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prichard, H. 1949b. Moral Obligation. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Prichard, H. 1949c. ‘The Obligation to Keep a Promise’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prichard, H. 1949d. ‘The Time of an Obligation’. In Prichard (1949b)
Prvulovich, Z. 1982. ‘In Defence of Competition’. Journal of Philosophy of Education 16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, H. 1994. Words and Life. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Qizilbash, M. 1997. ‘Well-Being and Despair: Dante's Ugolino’. Utilitas 9Google Scholar
Qizilbash, M. 1998. ‘The Concept of Well-Being’. Economics and Philosophy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radford, C. 1966. ‘Knowledge – By Examples’. Analysis 27Google Scholar
Radford, C. 1984. ‘I Will, If You Will’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Rappoport, A., and C. Orwant. 1964. ‘Experimental Games: A Review’. In , M. Shubik (ed.), Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior. New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. 1967. ‘Two Concepts of Rules’. In Foot (1967)
Rawls, J. 1972. A Theory of Justice. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. 1982. ‘Social Unity and Primary Goods’. In Sen and Williams (1982)
Rawls, J. 1993. Political Liberalism. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1972. ‘Voluntary Obligations and Normative Powers (II)’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, Supplementary Volume 46Google Scholar
Raz, J. 1977. ‘Promises and Obligations’. In , P. Hacker and , J. Raz (eds.), Law Morality, and Society. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1979. The Authority of Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1984. ‘On the Nature of Rights’. Mind 93Google Scholar
Raz, J. 1986. The Morality of Freedom. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1994a. ‘Duties of Well-Being’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994b. Ethics in the Public Domain: Essays in the Morality of Law and Politics. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Raz, J. 1994c. ‘Liberalism, Scepticism, and Democracy’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994d. ‘Liberating Duties’. In Raz (1994b)
Raz, J. 1994e. ‘Rights and Individual Well-Being’. In Raz (1994b)
Reath, A. 1998. ‘Autonomy, Ethical’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 1
Rees, R. 1993. ‘Tacit Collusion’. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reeve, S. 1906. The Cost of Competition. New York: McClure, PhillipsGoogle Scholar
Regan, D. 1985. ‘On Preferences and Promises: A Response to Harsanyi’. Ethics 96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rich, J. 1988. ‘Competition in Education’. Educational Theory 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robins, M. 1984. Promising, Intending, and Moral Autonomy. New York: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Roemer, J. 1996. Theories of Distributive Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Rogers, W. 1994. Winfield & Jolowicz on Tort (14th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Rotenstreich, N. 1972. ‘On Confidence’. Philosophy 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, P. (ed.). 2001. Bellamy and Child: European Community Law of Competition (5th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Russell, B. 1951. New Hopes for a Changing World. London: George Allen & UnwinGoogle Scholar
Sainsbury, M. 1990. Concepts Without Boundaries. London: King's College LondonGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. 1970. Foundations of Economic Analysis. New York: AtheneumGoogle Scholar
Sartorius, R. (ed.). 1983. Paternalism. St Paul: University of Minnesota PressGoogle Scholar
Scanlan, G. 2002. ‘Dishonesty in Corporate Offences: A Need for Reform’. Company Lawyer 23Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1972. ‘A Theory of Freedom of Expression’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1975. ‘Preference and Urgency’. Journal of Philosophy 72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1990. ‘Promises and Practices’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 19Google Scholar
Scanlon, T. 1993a. ‘The Moral Basis of Interpersonal Comparisons’. In Elster and Roemer (1993a)
Scanlon, T. 1993b. ‘Value, Desire, and Quality of Life’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Scanlon, T. 1998. What We Owe to Each Other. Cambridge, MA: Belknap PressGoogle Scholar
Scanlon, T. 2001. ‘Promises and Contracts’. In Benson (2001a)
Schauer, F. 1991a. ‘Exceptions’. University of Chicago Law Review 58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schauer, F. 1991b. Playing by the Rules. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Schechter, M. 1982. ‘The Rule of Reason in European Competition Law’. Legal Issues in European Integration 1982
Schelling, T. 1980. The Strategy of Conflict (2nd edition). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F., and , D. Ross. 1990. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (3rd edition). Boston: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Scherer, M. 1987. ‘Making the Rule of Reason Analysis More Manageable’. Antitrust Law Journal 56Google Scholar
Schiffer, S. 1972. Meaning. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schiffer, S. 1987. Remnants of Meaning. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Schneewind, J. 1986. ‘The Use of Autonomy in Ethical Theory’. In , T. Helleret al. (eds.), Reconstructing Individualism: Autonomy, Individuality, and the Self in Western Thought. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, C. 1995. ‘From Consumer Choice to Consumer Welfare’. Hastings Center Report, Special Supplement 25Google ScholarPubMed
Schopenhauer, A. 1951. ‘The Vanity of Existence’. In , A. Schopenhauer, Essays from the Parerga and Paralipomena. London: George Allen & UnwinGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, E. 1973. Small Is Beautiful: A Study of Economics as if People Mattered. London: Blond & BriggsGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1975. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: HarperPerennialGoogle Scholar
Schwarze, J. 1992. European Administrative Law. London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1981. ‘The Desire for Excitement in Modern Society’. Kyklos 34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1992. The Joyless Economy: The Psychology of Human Satisfaction (revised edition). New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Scoccia, D. 1987. ‘Autonomy, Want Satisfaction, and the Justification of Liberal Freedoms’. Canadian Journal of Philosophy 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, J. 1967. ‘How to Derive “Ought” from “Is”’. In Foot (1967)
Searle, J. 1968. ‘Prima Facie Obligations’. In , J. Raz (ed.), Practical Reasoning. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Seel, M. 1997. ‘Well-Being: On a Fundamental Concept of Practical Philosophy’. European Journal of Philosophy 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1981. ‘Plural Utility’. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1982a. ‘Behaviour and the Concept of Preference’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982b. ‘Choice, Orderings and Morality’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982c. Choice, Welfare and Measurement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1982d. ‘Equality of What?’ In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982e. ‘The Impossibility of a Paretian Liberal’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982f. ‘Interpersonal Aggregation and Partial Comparability’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982g. ‘Interpersonal Comparisons of Welfare’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982h. ‘Introduction’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982i. ‘Liberty, Unanimity and Rights’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982j. ‘Personal Utilities and Public Judgments: Or What's Wrong with Welfare Economics?’ In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1982k. ‘Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioural Foundations of Economic Theory’. In Sen (1982c)
Sen, A. 1985. ‘Well-Being, Agency and Freedom: The Dewey Lectures 1984’. Journal of Philosophy 82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 1993. ‘Capability and Well-Being’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Sen, A. 2002a. ‘Freedom and Social Choice: The Arrow Lectures’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002b. ‘Individual Preference as the Basis of Social Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002c. ‘Internal Consistency of Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002d. ‘Introduction: Rationality and Freedom’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002e. ‘Markets and Freedoms’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002f. ‘Maximisation and the Act of Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002g. ‘Non-Binary Choice and Preference’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002h. ‘The Possibility of Social Choice’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A. 2002i. Rationality and Freedom. Cambridge, MA: Belknap PressGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. 2002j. ‘Rationality and Uncertainty’. In Sen (2002i)
Sen, A., and , B. Williams (eds.). 1982. Utilitarianism and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafer-Landau, R. 1995. ‘Vagueness, Borderline Cases and Moral Realism’. American Philosophical Quarterly 32Google Scholar
Shah, R. 1995. ‘Estoppel and Legitimate Expectation’. New Law Journal, 3 November 1995Google Scholar
Sidgwick, H. 1907. The Methods of Ethics (7th edition). London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simmel, G. 1955. Conflict and the Web of Group-Affiliations. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Simmons, A. 1981. ‘Reasonable Expectations and Obligations: A Reply to Postow’. Southern Journal of Philosophy 19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. 1982. Models of Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Singer, P. 1972. ‘Altruism and Commerce: A Defence of Titmuss Against Arrow’. Philosophy and Public Affairs 2Google Scholar
Singh, R. 1994. ‘Making Legitimate Use of Legitimate Expectation’. New Law Journal, 9 September 1994Google Scholar
Skorupski, J. 2000. ‘Quality of Well-Being: Quality of Being’. In Crisp and Hooker (2000)
Smart, J. 1973. ‘An Outline of a System of Utilitarian Ethics’. In , J. Smart and , B. Williams, Utilitarianism: For and Against. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Smith, J. 2002. Smith & Hogan: Criminal Law (10th edition). London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Smith, M. 1994. The Moral Problem. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Smith, N. (ed.). 1982. Mutual Knowledge. London: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Soames, T. 1996. ‘An Analysis of the Principles of Concerted Practice and Collective Dominance: A Distinction without a Difference?European Competition Law Review 17Google Scholar
Sobel, D. 1994. ‘Full Information Accounts of Well-Being’. Ethics 104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobel, D. 1998. ‘Well-Being as the Object of Moral Consideration’. Economics and Philosophy 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stalnaker, R. 1991. ‘A Theory of Conditionals’. In , F. Jackson (ed.), Conditionals. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Stocker, M. 1992. Plural and Conflicting Values. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoljar, S. 1988. ‘Promise, Expectation and Agreement’. Cambridge Law Journal 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strasser, M. 1985. ‘Dependence, Reliance and Abortion’. Philosophical Quarterly 35CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Strawson, P. 1971. ‘Intention and Convention in Speech Acts’. In , J. Searle (ed.), The Philosophy of Language. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, L. 1977. Handbook of the Law of Antitrust. St Paul: WestGoogle Scholar
Sullivan, L. 1987. ‘The Viability of the Current Law on Horizontal Restraints’. California Law Review 75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sumner, L. 1996. Welfare, Happiness, and Ethics. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Taggart, M. 1996. ‘Legitimate Expectation and Treaties in the High Court of Australia’. Law Quarterly Review 112Google Scholar
Tännsjö, T. 1996. ‘Classical Hedonistic Utilitarianism’. Philosophical Studies 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, S., and , J. Mansell. 2003. ‘White-Collar Crime – Caught in the Act’. Legal Week 5Google Scholar
Thompson, G. 1972. ‘Effects of Cooperation and Competition on Public Learning’. Educational Research (British) 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, M. 1983. ‘From Representation to Expectation: Estoppel as a Cause of Action’. Cambridge Law Journal 42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, J. 1994. ‘Remarks on Causation and Liability’. In Levmore (1994)
Titmuss, R. 1971. The Gift Relationship: From Human Blood to Social Policy. London: PantheonGoogle Scholar
Treitel, G. 1995. The Law of Contract (9th edition). London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Tuomela, R. 1995. The Importance of Us. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. 1981. ‘Choice, Preference and Welfare: Some Psychological Observations’. Paper presented at a colloquium on ‘Foundations of Social Choice Theory’, Ustaoset (Norway)
Ullmann-Margalit, E. 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Unger, P. 1996. Living High and Letting Die: Our Illusion of Innocence. New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanDeVeer, D. 1986. Paternalistic Intervention: The Moral Bounds of Benevolence. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Praag, B. 1993. ‘The Relativity of the Welfare Concept’. In Nussbaum and Sen (1993)
Varian, H. 1978. Microeconomic Analysis. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Velleman, D. 2000a. ‘Deciding How to Decide’. In Velleman (2000c)
Velleman, D. 2000b. ‘How to Share an Intention’. In Velleman (2000c)
Velleman, D. 2000c. The Possibility of Practical Reason. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Vickers, J. 1995. ‘Concepts of Competition’. Oxford Economic Papers 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warnock, G. 1971. The Object of Morality. London: MethuenGoogle Scholar
Weale, A. 1978. ‘Paternalism and Social Policy’. Journal of Social Policy 7CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Weale, A. 1998. ‘Welfare’. In E. Craig (1998), vol. 9
Weinstein, N. 1982. ‘Community Noise Problems: Evidence Against Adaptation’. Journal of Environmental Psychology 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, R. 1996. ‘The Impossibility of Interpersonal Utility Comparisons: A Critical Note’. Mind 105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weintraub, R. 1998. ‘Do Utility Comparisons Pose a Problem?Philosophical Studies 92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wertheimer, B. 1984. ‘Rethinking the Rule of Reason: From Professional Engineers to NCAA’. Duke Law Journal
Whish, R. 1993. Competition Law (3rd edition). London, ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Whish, R. 2003. Competition Law (5th edition). London: LexisNexis UKGoogle Scholar
Whish, R., and B. Sufrin. 1987. ‘Article 85 and the Rule of Reason’. Oxford Yearbook of European Law 1987
Williams, B. 1978. Descartes: The Project of Pure Enquiry. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Williams, B. 1985. Ethics and the Limits of Philosophy. London: FontanaGoogle Scholar
Williams, B. 2002. Truth and Truthfulness. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Williams, G. 1983. Textbook of Criminal Law (2nd edition). London: Stevens & SonsGoogle Scholar
Williamson, T. 1994. Vagueness. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Wilson, J. 1989. ‘Competition’. Journal of Moral Education 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolff, J. Unpublished. ‘Libertarianism, Utility and Economic Competition’
Wood Hutchinson, D. 1984. ‘Antitrust 1984: Five Decisions in Search of a Theory’. The Supreme Court Review 1984
Woozley, A. 1981. ‘Promises, Promises’. Mind 90Google Scholar
Young, R. 1980. ‘Autonomy and the Inner Self’. American Philosophical Quarterly 17Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Oliver Black, King's College London
  • Book: Conceptual Foundations of Antitrust
  • Online publication: 08 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511494666.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Oliver Black, King's College London
  • Book: Conceptual Foundations of Antitrust
  • Online publication: 08 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511494666.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Oliver Black, King's College London
  • Book: Conceptual Foundations of Antitrust
  • Online publication: 08 July 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511494666.009
Available formats
×