Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-20T12:18:03.412Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - The optimal number of futures markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 October 2009

Get access

Summary

Considering the significant advantages of functioning loan markets in commodities and the dominance of futures markets as the institution for providing such loan markets, one might wonder why organized futures markets are so few in number. There are probably no more than forty or fifty worldwide with sufficient volume to be deemed active markets. The number of exchanges, like the Chicago Board of Trade, is even smaller. Further, the same commodity is rarely actively traded on more than one exchange. The London Metal Exchange and Comex in New York do survive side by side, but because the LME closes just as Comex opens they do not compete directly. Likewise, the cocoa and coffee markets in London and New York, even though they trade different varieties, are more naturally considered as part of one worldwide market chasing daylight hours. In any case, for metals, cocoa, and coffee, either New York or London dominates, attracting the large majority of volume and open interest. Similarly, the markets for wheat in Kansas City and Minneapolis, which offer contracts for different varieties, are also small in comparison to the primary market on the Chicago Board of Trade. Otherwise, futures trading is overwhelmingly concentrated in one location for a particular commodity. In that one market trading is rarely in more than five or six delivery months, spanning a year or two.

The small number of active futures markets is perfectly reasonable. Few commodities have a pronounced term structure. That is to say, few have spreads sufficiently volatile to justify delivery months stretching far into the future. The same is true for one commodity in several locations and for the full multitude of delivery months within a calendar year.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×