Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-x5cpj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-02T08:19:46.753Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Costs, scale and size

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Martin Upton
Affiliation:
University of Reading
Get access

Summary

Two variable inputs

Generally speaking, labour is not the only input which can be varied. Where there are two or more variable inputs then substitution of one for the other may be possible, and decisions must be taken on the appropriate combination of inputs, and method of production. This may be illustrated using the example from the previous chapter, of maize yield response to variations in weeding labour. It is now assumed that the amount of seed sown, per one hectare plot, is a second variable input. An increase in seed use which raises maize yield, thereby raises the average product per day of weeding labour but may reduce the amount of weeding necessary. More specifically there may be scope for substituting seed for weeding labour in producing a particular yield of maize. A possible response surface for these two variable inputs is represented by the data given in Table 5.1 and plotted in Figure 5.1.

The original response curve for weeding labour is now seen to relate to a fixed seed rate of 10 000 plants per hectare, as shown in the first row of Table 5.1 and by the line AB in Figure 5.1. Although some yield is obtained, even when no weeding labour is used (at least for seed rates above 15 000), the situation is different for seed. There can be no yield when no seed is used, so the response curves for seed pass through the origin.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Costs, scale and size
  • Martin Upton, University of Reading
  • Book: The Economics of Tropical Farming Systems
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139172868.006
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Costs, scale and size
  • Martin Upton, University of Reading
  • Book: The Economics of Tropical Farming Systems
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139172868.006
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Costs, scale and size
  • Martin Upton, University of Reading
  • Book: The Economics of Tropical Farming Systems
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139172868.006
Available formats
×