Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-09T12:14:15.228Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2017

Mark A. Zupan
Affiliation:
Alfred University, New York
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Inside Job
How Government Insiders Subvert the Public Interest
, pp. 208 - 223
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abram, Michael and Cooper, Joseph (1968). “The Rise of Seniority in the House of Representatives.” Polity 1 (1): 5285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramowitz, Moses (1986). “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” Journal of Economic History 46 (2): 389406.Google Scholar
Abrams, Burton A. and Settle, Russell F. (1978). “The Economic Theory of Regulation and Public Financing of Presidential Elections.” Journal of Political Economy 86 (2): 245257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron (2003). “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (4): 620652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. (2006). Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. (2006). “Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective.” American Political Science Review 100 (1): 115131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. New York: Crown Publishers.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. (2013). “Economics versus Politics: Pitfalls of Policy Advice.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (2): 173192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. (2015). “The Rise and Decline of General Laws of Capitalism.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 (1): 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James A., and Verdier, Thierry (2004). “Kleptocracy and Divide-and-Rule: A Model of Personal Rule.” Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (2–3): 162192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Jackson, Matthew (2015). “History, Expectations, and Leadership in the Evolution of Social Norms.” Review of Economic Studies 82 (1): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Naidu, Suresh, Restrepo, Pascual, and Robinson, James A. (2014). “Democracy Does Cause Growth.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, MIT.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Reed, Tristan, and Robinson, James A. (2014). “Chiefs: Economic Development and Elite Control of Civil Society in Sierra Leone.” Journal of Political Economy 122 (2): 319368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, Kenneth D. (2011). Boss Tweed: The Corrupt Pol Who Conceived the Soul of Modern New York. Falls Church, VA: Viral History Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Alesina, Alberto, and Trebbi, Francesco (2008). “Democracy, Technology, and Growth.” In Institutions and Economic Performance, 511543. Edited by Helpman, Elhanan. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Algan, Yann, Cahuc, Pierre, and Shleifer, Andrei (2010). “Regulation and Distrust.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (3): 10151049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahman, Ehtisham, Keping, Li, and Richardson, Thomas J. (2002). “Recentralization in China,” IMF Working Paper, Number 2/168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold (1972). “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization.” American Economic Review 62 (5): 777795.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Giuliano, Paola (2015). “Culture and Institutions.” Journal of Economic Literature 53 (4): 898944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anzia, Sarah F. and Moe, Terry M. (2015). “Public Sector Unions and the Costs of Government.” Journal of Politics 77 (1): 114127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aranson, Peter H. and Ordeshook, Peter C. (1977). “A Prolegomenon to a Theory of the Failure of Representative Democracy.” In American Re-evolution Papers and Proceedings, 2346. Edited by Auster, Richard D. and Sears, Barbara. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press.Google Scholar
Atsmon, Yuval and Magni, Max (2012). “Meet the Chinese Consumer of 2020.” The McKinsey Quarterly 50 (1): 110.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. (1996). “Democracy and Growth.” Journal of Economic Growth 1 (1): 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1983). “Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (3): 371398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, Daniel A. (2015). The China Model: Political Meritocracy and the Limits of Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bensel, Richard F. (1990). Yankee Leviathan: The Origins of Central State Authority in America, 1859–1877. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Peter L. (2005). Wedding of the Waters: The Erie Canal and the Making of a Great Nation. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Berry, Christopher R. (2009). Imperfect Union: Representation and Taxation in Multi-level Governments. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, David E., Canning, David, and Fink, Gunther (2008). “Urbanization and the Wealth of Nations.” Science 319: 772775.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Borcherding, Thomas E. (1977). Editor. Budgets and Bureaucrats: The Sources of Government Growth. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Borcherding, Thomas E., Pommerehne, Werner W., and Schneider, Friedrich (1982). “Comparing the Efficiency of Private and Public Production: The Evidence from Five Countries.” Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie 42 (2): 127156.Google Scholar
Brill, Steven (August 31, 2009). “The Rubber Room: The Battle over New York’s Worst Teachers.” The New Yorker: 3036.Google Scholar
Browder, Bill (2015). Red Notice: A True Story of High Finance, Murder, and One Man’s Fight for Justice. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Browning, Edgar K. (1975). “Why the Social Insurance Budget Is Too Large in a Democracy.” Economic Inquiry 13 (3): 373388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, Edgar K. (2008). Stealing From Each Other: How the Welfare State Robs Americans of Money and Spirit. Westport, CN: Praeger.Google Scholar
Brunner, Karl (1978). “Reflections on the Political Economy of Government: The Persistent Growth of Government.” Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 114 (3): 649680.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1972). “Before Public Choice.” In Explorations in the Theory of Anarchy, 2737. Edited by Tullock, Gordon. Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice, Virginia Polytechnic Institute.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1977). “The Expanding Public Sector: Wagner Squared.” Public Choice 31 (1): 147150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Wagner, Richard E. (1977). Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. Indianapolis, IN: The Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Musgrave, Richard A. (1999). Public Finance and Public Choice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno, de Mesquita, and Smith, Alastair (2011). The Dictator’s Handbook. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Buck, Pearl S. (1931). The Good Earth. New York: P. F. Collier & Son.Google Scholar
Burgess, Robin, Jedwab, Remi, Miguel, Edward, Morjaria, Ameet, and Miquel, Gerard Padro (2015). “The Value of Democracy: Evidence from Road Building in Kenya.” American Economic Review 105 (6): 18171851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, John P. (2007). “Civil Service Reform in China.” OECD Journal on Budgeting 7 (1): 5781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cain, Bruce E. and Kousser, Thad (2004). Adapting to Term Limits: Recent Experiences and New Directions. San Francisco, CA: Public Policy Institute of California.Google Scholar
Cain, Bruce, Ferejohn, John, and Fiorina, Morris (1987). The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin (1983). Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interactions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, Averil (1993). The Later Roman Empire. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Caplan, Bryan (2006). The Myth of the Rational Voter. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Card, David, and Krueger, Alan (1992a). “Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (1): 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David, and Krueger, Alan (1992b). “School Quality and Black-White Relative Earnings: A Direct Assessment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (1): 151200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlin, John (2009). Invictus. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Carlyle, Thomas (1841). On Heroes, Hero-Worship, and the Heroic in History. London: James Fraser.Google Scholar
Caro, Robert A. (1974). The Power Broker: Robert Moses and the Fall of New York. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, Inc.Google Scholar
Caro, Robert A. (2012). The Passage of Power. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, Inc.Google Scholar
Carson, Jamie L., Engstrom, Erik J., and Roberts, Jason M. (2006). “Redistricting, Candidate Entry, and the Politics of Nineteenth-Century U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 50 (2): 283293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chayes, Sarah (2015). Thieves of State: Why Corruption Threatens Global Security. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Chen, Jowei, and Johnson, Tim (2015). “Federal Employee Unionization and Presidential Control of the Bureaucracy: Estimating and Explaining Ideological Change in Executive Agencies.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 27 (1): 151171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chetty, Raj, Friedman, John N., and Rockoff, Jonah E. (2014). “Measuring the Impacts of Teachers II: Teacher Value-Added and Student Outcomes in Adulthood.” American Economic Review 104 (9): 26332679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chua, Amy (2011). Battle Hymn of the Tiger Mother. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Chubb, John E., and Moe, Terry M. (1990). Politics, Markets, and American Schools. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4 (16): 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1960). “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1964). “The Regulated Industries: Discussion.” American Economic Review 54 (2): 194197.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., and Wang, Ning (2012). How China Became Capitalist. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornell, Stephen, and Kalt, Joseph P. (2000). “Where’s the Glue? Institutional and Cultural Foundations of American Indian Economic Development.” Journal of Socio-Economics 29 (3): 443470.Google Scholar
Corruption Perceptions Index (Annual). Berlin, Germany: Transparency International.Google Scholar
Cost, Jay (2015). A Republic No More: Big Government and the Rise of American Corruption. New York: Encounter Books.Google Scholar
Cowen, Tyler, and Sutter, Daniel (1997). “Politics and the Pursuit of Fame.” Public Choice 93 (1–2): 1935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowen, Tyler, Glazer, Amihai, and McMillan, Henry (1994). “Rent Seeking Can Promote the Provision of Public Goods.” Economics and Politics 6 (2): 131145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crew, Michael A., and Kleindorfer, Paul R. (1993). Editors. Regulation and the Nature of Postal and Delivery Services. Boston, MA: Kluwer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crow, Carl (1938). The Chinese Are Like That. New York: Harper and Brothers.Google Scholar
Dalberg-Acton, John E. E. (1907). “Letter to Bishop Mandell Creighton, April 5, 1887.” In Historical Essays and Studies, 504. Edited by Figgis, John N. and Laurence, Reginald V.. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Deaton, Angus (2013). The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
DeCelles, Katherine, DeRue, D. Scott, Margolis, Joshua D., and Ceranic, Tara L. (2012). “Does Power Corrupt or Enable?: When and Why Power Facilitates Self-Interested Behavior.” Journal of Applied Psychology 97 (3): 681689.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
DeLong, Bradford J., and Shleifer, Andrei (1993). “Princes and Merchants: European City Growth Before the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of Law and Economics 36 (2): 671702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold E. (1968). “Why Regulate Public Utilities?Journal of Law and Economics 11 (1): 5565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Jared (1997). Guns, Germs and Steel. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, Keane, Michael P., and Merlo, Antonio M. (2005). “A Political Economy Model of Congressional Careers.” American Economic Review 95 (1): 347373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Lodovico, Amadeo M., Lewis, William W., Palmade, Vincent, and Sankhe, Shirish (2001). “India: From Emerging to Surging.” The McKinsey Quarterly 4 (Special Edition): 2850.Google Scholar
DiIulio, John J. Jr. (2014). Bring Back the Bureaucrats. West Coshohocken, PA: Templeton Press.Google Scholar
DiSalvo, Daniel (2010). “The Trouble with Public Sector Unions.” National Affairs 5: 319.Google Scholar
DiSalvo, Daniel (2015). Government Against Itself: Public Union Power and Its Consequences. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dobbie, Will, and Fryer, Roland G. Jr. (2015). “The Medium-Term Impacts of High-Achieving Charter Schools.” Journal of Political Economy 123 (5): 9851037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Doyle, Michael W. (1983). “Kant, Liberal Legacies, and Foreign Affairs.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 12 (4): 205235.Google Scholar
Duhigg, Charles (2012). The Power of Habit: Why We Do What We Do in Life and Business. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Duhigg, Charles (2016). Smarter Faster Better. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Edwards, Chris, and Gokhale, Jagadeesh (2006). “Unfunded State and Local Health Costs: $1.4 Trillion.” Tax and Budget Bulletin 40. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.Google Scholar
Eliot, T. S. (1943). “Little Gidding.” Four Quartets. New York: Harcourt, Inc.Google Scholar
Ellison, Sarah (January 2015). “Which Blair Project.” Vanity Fair, 5468.Google Scholar
Farr, W. Ken, Lord, Richard A., and Wolfenbarger, J. Larry (1998). “Economic Freedom, Political Freedom, and Economic Well-Being: A Causality Analysis.” Cato Journal 18 (2): 247262.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard (1978). Homestyle: House Members and Their Districts. Boston, MA: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Niall (2006). The War of the World: Twentieth Century Conflict and the Descent of the West. New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P., and Noll, Roger G. (1978). “Voters, Bureaucrats and Legislators: A Rational Choice Perspective on the Growth of Bureaucracy.” Journal of Public Economics 9 (2): 239254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, Raymond, Schulz, Florian, and Vig, Vikrant (2014). “The Private Returns to Public Office.” Journal of Political Economy 122 (4): 806862.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, J. Ronald (1988). The Defense Management Challenge. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Freedom House (Annual). Freedom in the World: Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. Boston: Freedom House.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. (1986). “Unionism Comes to the Public Sector.” In When Public Sector Workers Unionize, 365398. Edited by Freeman, Richard B. and Ichniovski, Casey. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1962). Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Friedman, Rose D. (1984). Tyranny of the Status Quo. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (1992). The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (2011). The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (2014). Political Order and Political Decay: From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth (1958). The Affluent Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galloway, George B. (1959). “Development of the Committee System in the House.” The American Historical Review 65 (1): 1730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Przeworski, Adam (2007). “Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats.” Comparative Political Studies 40 (11): 12791301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garen, John, and Clark, Jeff R. (2015). “Trust and the Growth of Government.” Unpublished manuscript, Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky.Google Scholar
Geddes, Barbara, Wright, Joseph, and Frantz, Erica (2014). “Autocratic Breakdown and Regime Transitions: A New Data Set.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (2): 313331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbon, Edward ([1776–1789] 1974). The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire. Edited by Bury, John Bagnell. New York: AMS Press.Google Scholar
Gladwell, Malcolm (October 2010). “Small Change.” The New Yorker, 4249.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., and Shleifer, Andrei (2005). “The Economics of Shaping the Electorate.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 21 (1):119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Gyourko, Joseph, and Saks, Raven E. (2005). “Why Have Housing Prices Gone Up?American Economic Review 95 (2): 329333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glassman, Matthew E., and Wilhelm, Amber H. (2015). Congressional Career: Service Tenure and Patterns of Member Service, 1789–2015. CRS Report for Congress 7–5700. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.Google Scholar
Goff, Brian L., and Tollison, Robert D. (1990). “Is National Defense A Pure Public Good?Defence Economics 1: 141147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, Claudia, and Katz, Lawrence F. (2008). The Race Between Education and Technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, A.J.H. (1957). “The Medieval Empire of Ghana.” South African Archaeological Bulletin (12): 108112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenstein, Shane (2015). How the Internet Became Commercial: Innovation, Privatization, and the Birth of a New Network. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grief, Avner (1994). “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (5): 912950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gropper, Daniel M., Jahera, John, and Park, Jung-Chul (2015). “Political Power, Economic Freedom, and Congress: Effects on Bank Performance.” Journal of Banking and Finance 60:7692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola, and Zingales, Luigi (2015). “Corporate Culture, Societal Culture, and Institutions.” American Economic Review 105 (5): 336339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Holcombe, Randall G., and Lawson, Robert A. (1998). “The Scope of Government and the Wealth of Nations.” Cato Journal 18: 163190.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Lawson, Robert A., and Hall, Joshua (Annual). Economic Freedom of the World. Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander, Jay, John, and Madison, James ([1788] 1982). The Federalist Papers. Toronto: Bantam Books.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry B. (1986). “The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise.” In The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy, 161184. Edited by Rose-Ackerman, Susan. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hanushek, Eric A. (2009). “Teacher Deselection.” In Creating a New Teaching Profession, 165180. Edited by Goldhaber, Dan and Hannaway, Jane. Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press.Google Scholar
Harrell, Stevan (1985). “Why Do the Chinese Work So Hard?Modern China 11 (2): 203226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1944). The Road to Serfdom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayes, Kathy, and Chang, Semoon (1990). “The Relative Efficiency of City Manager and Mayor-Council Forms of Government.” Southern Economic Journal 51 (1): 167177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heitger, Bernhard (2004). “Property Rights and the Wealth of Nations: A Cross-Country Study.” Cato Journal 23 (3): 381402.Google Scholar
Hibbert, Christopher (1980). The French Revolution. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Hibbing, John R. (1991). “The Modern Congressional Career.” The American Political Science Review 85: 404425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Higgs, Robert (1990). Editor. Arms, Politics, and the Economy. New York: Holmes and Meier.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. (1970). Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hodler, Roland, and Raschky, Paul A. (2014). “Regional Favoritism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2): 9951033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. (2012). “Make Economics Policy Relevant: Depose the Omniscient Benevolent Dictator.” The Independent Review 17 (2): 165176.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. (2015). “Political Capitalism.” Cato Journal 35 (1): 4166.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., and Boudreaux, Christopher J. (2013). “Institutional Quality and the Tenure of Autocrats.” Public Choice 156 (3): 409421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holderlin, Friedrich (2008). Hyperion. Translated by Benjamin, Ross. Brooklyn, NY: Archipelago Books.Google Scholar
Hollyer, James R., and Wantchekon, Leonard (2015). “Corruption and Ideology in Autocracies.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 31 (3): 499533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, Frank L. (2016). The Treasures of Alexander the Great: How One Man’s Wealth Shaped the World. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxby, Caroline M. (1996). “How Teachers Unions Affect Education Production.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 111 (3): 671718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxby, Caroline M. (2000). “Does Competition Among Public Schools Benefit Students and Taxpayers?American Economic Review 90 (5): 12091238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoxby, Caroline M. (2011). Editor. The Economics of School Choice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hoxby, Caroline M., and Leigh, Andrew (2004). “Pulled Away or Pushed Out: Explaining the Decline of Teacher Aptitude in the U.S.” American Economic Review 94 (2): 236240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubbard, Glenn, and Kane, Tim (2013). Balance: The Economics of Great Powers From Ancient Rome to Modern America. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hummler, Konrad. (2004). “Globalization: Phase 2,” Wegelin Investment Commentary No. 232.Google Scholar
Hummler, Konrad. (2009). “States Under Stress.” Wegelin Commentary No. 264. Wegelin & Company.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. (1996). The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. New York: Touchstone.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid (2008). “But Who Will Guard the Guardians?American Economic Review 98 (3): 577585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaacson, Walter, and Thomas, Evan (1986). The Wise Men: Six Friends and the World They Made. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Ito, Takatoshi (1996). “Japan and the Asian Economies: A Miracle in Transition.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 27 (2): 205272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Meckling, William H. (1976). “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (4): 305360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Murphy, Kevin J. (1990). “Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (2): 225264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, George E., and Stafford, Frank P. (1973). “Social Returns to Quantity and Quality of Schooling.” Journal of Human Resources 8 (2): 139155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Paul E. (1978). A Shopkeeper’s Millennium. New York: Hill & Wang.Google Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N., and Libecap, Gary D. (1994). The Federal Civil Service and the Problem of Bureaucracy: The Economics and Politics of Institutional Change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux.Google Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P., and Zupan, Mark A. (1984). “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.” American Economic Review 74 (3): 279300.Google Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P., and Zupan, Mark A. (1990). “The Apparent Ideological Behavior of Legislators: Testing for Principal-Agent Slack in Political Institutions.” Journal of Law and Economics 33 (1): 103131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Robert S., and Walker, David M. (2013). “Government Debt and Competitiveness.” Harvard Business School U.S. Competitiveness Project. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School.Google Scholar
Kau, James B., and Rubin, Paul H. (1979). “Self-Interest, Ideology, and Logrolling in Congressional Voting.” Journal of Law and Economics 22 (2): 365384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kauffmann, Daniel, Kray, Aart, and Mastruzzi, Massimo (2003). “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3106, Washington D.C.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kayser, Mark A., and Peress, Michael (2012). “Benchmarking Across Borders: Electoral Accountability and the Necessity of Comparison.” American Political Science Review 106 (3): 661682.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keech, William, and Munger, Michael (2015). “The Anatomy of Government Failure.” Public Choice 164: 142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kendall-Taylor, Andrea, and Frantz, Erica (2014). “How Autocracies Fall.” Washington Quarterly 37 (1): 3547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kendall-Taylor, Andrea, and Frantz, Erica (2015). “Mimicking Democracy to Prolong Autocracies.” Washington Quarterly 37 (4): 7184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, Paul (1987). The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Kenny, Lawrence W., and Schmidt, Amy B. (1994). “The Decline in the Number of School Districts in the U.S.: 1950–1980.” Public Choice 79 (1–2): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khaldun, Ibn (2005). The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History. Translated by Rosenthal, Franz. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kinross, Patrick (2001). Ataturk: The Rebirth of a Nation. London: Phoenix.Google Scholar
Kissinger, Henry (2011). On China. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Kissinger, Henry (2014). World Order. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G., and Alchian, Armen A. (1978). “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process.” Journal of Law and Economics 21 (2): 297326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, Stephen, and Keefer, Philip (1997). “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Analysis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 12511288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolko, Gabriel (1963). The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900–1916. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and Burns, Scott (2012). The Clash of Generations: Saving Ourselves, Our Kids, and Our Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kravitz, Walker (1974). “Evolution of the Senate’s Committee System.” Annals of the American Academy of Political Science 411: 2738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Anne (1974). “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society.” American Economic Review 64 (3): 291303.Google Scholar
Kuhrt, Amelie (1995). The Ancient Near-East c. 3000–330 BC. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kumar, Krishna B., and Matsusaka, John G. (2009). “From Families to Formal Contracts: An Approach to Development.” Journal of Development Economics 90 (1): 106119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuziemko, Illyana, Norton, Michael I., Saez, Emmanuel, and Stantcheva, Stefanie (2015). “How Elastic Are Preferences for Redistribution? Evidence from Randomized Survey Experiments.” American Economic Review 105 (4): 14781508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffer, Arthur B., Moore, Stephen, Sinquefield, Rex A., and Brown, Travis H. (2014). Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of States: How Taxes, Energy, and Worker Freedom Change Everything. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Landry, Pierre F. (2003). “The Political Management of Mayors in Post-Deng China.” The Copenhagen Journal of Asian Studies 17: 3158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landsberg, Henry A. (1958). Hawthorne Revisited. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.Google Scholar
Lardy, Nicholas (2014). Markets Over Mao: The Rise of Private Business in China. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Lasswell, Harold D. (1936). Politics: Who Gets What, When, and How. New York: Whittlesey House.Google Scholar
Lawson, Robert A., and Clark, J. R. (2010). “Examining the Hayek-Friedman Hypothesis on Economic and Political Freedom.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 74 (3): 230239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lemos, Margaret H., and Minzner, Max (2014). “For Profit Public Enforcement.” Harvard Law Review 127 (3): 853913.Google Scholar
Levitt, Steven D. (1996). “How Do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Preferences, Party Affiliation, and Senator Ideology.” American Economic Review 86 (3): 425441.Google Scholar
Levy, David M., and Peart, Sandra J. (2011). “Soviet Growth and American Textbooks: An Endogenous Past.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 78 (1–2): 110125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard (1995). The Middle East: A Brief History of the Last 2,000 Years. New York: Touchstone.Google Scholar
Lewis, Michael (2011). Boomerang. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Lewis, Michael (2014). Flash Boys: A Wall Street Revolt. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Lott, John R. Jr. (1987). “Why is Education Publicly Provided? A Critical Survey.” Cato Journal 7 (2): 475501.Google Scholar
MacMillan, Margaret (2014). The War That Ended the Peace: The Road to 1914. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Manne, Henry G. (1965). “Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control.” Journal of Political Economy 73 (2): 110120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Monty G. (2013). “Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2013.” North Vienna, VA: Center for Systematic Peace.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl ([1867] 2009). Das Capital: Critique of Political Economy. Washington, DC: Regnery Publishing.Google Scholar
Mayer, Jane (2016). Dark Money: The Hidden History of the Billionaires Behind the Rise of the Radical Right. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S. (1997). Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. (2010). Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. (2016). Bourgeois Equality: How Betterment Became Ethical, 1600 to 1848, and Then Suspect. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCormick, Robert E., and Tollison, Robert D. (1981). Politicians, Legislation, and the Economy: An Inquiry Into the Interest Group Theory of Government. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, Patrick J. (2009). The Invisible Hand of Peace: Capitalism, The War Machine, and International Relations. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKean, Roland N. (1965). “The Unseen Hand in Government.” American Economic Review 55 (3): 496506.Google Scholar
McKelvey, (1984). Rochester: A Brief History. New York: Edwin Mellen Press.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H., and Richard, Scott F. (1981). “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (5): 914927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H., and Richard, Scott F. (2014). “A Rational Theory of the Growth of Government and the Distribution of Income.” The Wharton School Research Paper No. 67.Google Scholar
Merewitz, Leonard, and Zupan, Mark (1993). “Franchise Bidding, Contracting Out, and Worksharing in the Production of Postal Services: Can They Collect, Sort, and Deliver?” In Regulation and the Nature of Postal and Delivery Services, 6989. Edited by Crew, Michael A. and Kleindorfer, Paul R.. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Micklethwait, John, and Wooldridge, Adrian (2014). The Fourth Revolution: The Global Race to Reinvent the State. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Milgram, Stanley (1974). Obedience to Authority: An Experimental View. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Miller, Terry, Kim, Anthony B., and Holmes, Kim R. (Annual). Index of Economic Freedom. Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation and Dow Jones & Company, Inc.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. (2006). “Political Control and the Power of the Agent.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 22 (1): 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. (2009). “Collective Bargaining and the Performance of Public Schools.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (1): 156174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. (2011). Special Interest: Teachers Unions and America’s Public Schools. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. (2015). “Vested Interests and Political Institutions.” Political Science Quarterly 30 (2): 277318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M., and Chubb, John E. (2009). Liberating Learning: Technology, Politics, and the Future of American Education. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morck, Randall, and Yeung, Bernard (2014). “Corporate Governance in China.” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 26 (3): 2041.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, Dennis C. (1979). Public Choice. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nietzsche, Friedrich (1909). Thoughts Out of Season. Edinburgh, UK: Edinburgh Press.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A. Jr. (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A. (2008). Reflections of a Political Economist: Selected Articles on Government Policies and Political Processes. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1968). “Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600–1850.” Journal of Political Economy 76 (5): 953970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1991). “Institutions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert P. (1973). The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R. (1989). “Constitutions and Commitment: Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Novy-Marx, Robert, and Rauh, Joshua D. (2014a). “Revenue Demands of Public Employee Pension Promises.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6 (1): 193229.Google Scholar
Novy-Marx, Robert, and Rauh, Joshua D. (2014b). “Linking Benefits to Investment Performance in U.S. Public Pension Systems.” Journal of Public Economics 116: 4761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. Jr., Zelikow, Philip D., and King, David C. (1997). Why People Don’t Trust Government. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2012). PISA 2012 Results. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
OECD (2015). “Urban Policy Review: China 2015.” Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Ogilvie, Sheilagh (2014). “The Economics of Guilds.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (4): 169192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okun, Arthur M. (1975). Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1971). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. New York: Shocken.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1993). “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur (2000). Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ornstein, Norman (1955). Editor. Congress in Change. New York: Praeger Publishers.Google Scholar
Paulson, Henry M. Jr. (2015). Dealing With China: An Insider Unmasks the New Economic Superpower. New York: Hachette Book Group.Google Scholar
Peden, Edgar A. (1991). “Productivity in the United States and its Relationship to Government Activity: An Analysis of 57 Years, 1929–1986.” Public Choice 69 (2): 153173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam (1976). “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19 (2): 211240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido (2003). The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, Paul E. (2007). Saving Schools: From Horace Mann to Virtual Learning. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pfeffer, Jeffrey (2015). Leadership BS. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Pharr, Susan J., and Putnam, Robert D. (2000). Disaffected Democracies: What’s Troubling the Trilateral Countries? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, Arthur C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare, 4th ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pink, Daniel H. (2011). Drive: The Surprising Truth About What Motivates Us. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven Arthur (2011). The Better Angels of Our Nature: Why Violence has Declined. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Polsby, Nelson (1968). “The Institutionalization of the U.S. House of Representatives.” The American Political Science Review 41 (1): 144168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. (1974). “Theories of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5 (2): 335358.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. (1977). Economic Analysis of Law. Boston: Little-Brown.Google Scholar
Primo, David M. (2007). Rules and Restraints: Government Spending and the Design of Institutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Primo, David M. (2014). “Making Budget Rules Work: 2014 Edition.” Fairfax, VA: George Mason University, Mercatus Center.Google Scholar
Pritchett, Lant, and Summers, Lawrence H. (2014). “Asiaphoria Meets Regression to the Mean.” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 20573.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritchett, Lant, and Woolcock, Michael (2002). Solutions When the Solution is the Problem: Arraying the Disarray in Development. Center for Global Development Working Paper No. 10.Google Scholar
Putti, Joseph M., Aryee, Samuel, and Liang, Tan Kim (1989). “Work Values and Organizational Commitment: A Study in the Asian Context.” Human Relations 42: 275288.Google Scholar
Querebin, Pablo (2016). Family and Politics: Dynastic Persistence in the Philippines. Quarterly Journal of Political Science 11 (2): 151181.Google Scholar
Reading, Brian (1992). Japan: The Coming Collapse. London: Orion Books.Google Scholar
Ridley, Matt W. (2010). The Rational Optimist: How Prosperity Evolves. New York: HarperCollins.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ridley, Matt W. (2015). The Evolution of Everything. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Rivkin, Steven, G., Hanushek, Eric A., and Kain, John F. (2005). “Teachers, Schools and Academic Achievement.” Econometrica 73 (2): 417458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani (2014). “When Ideas Trump Interests: Preferences, Worldviews, and Policy Innovations.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (1): 189208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1978). Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1986). Editor. The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Roser, Max (2015). “Democratization.” www.OurWorldInData.org.Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E. (2015). Who Gets What – and Why: The New Economics of Matchmaking and Market Design. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Russakoff, Dale (2015). The Prize. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey D. (2006). The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Warner, Andrew M. (2001). “The Curse of Natural Resources.” European Economic Review 45: 827838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandel, Michael J. (2009). Justice: What’s the Right Thing to Do? New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Sandel, Michael J. (2012). What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limit of Markets. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Schama, Simon (1989). Citizens: A Chronicle of the French Revolution. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Schuck, Peter H. (2014). Why Government Fails So Often: And How it can do Better. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter F. (2011). Throw Them All Out: How Politicians and Their Friends Get Rich Off Insider Stock Tips, Land Deals, and Cronyism That Would Send the Rest of Us to Prison. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter F. (2013). Extortion: How Politicians Extract Your Money, Buy Votes, and Line Their Own Pockets. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter F. (2015). Clinton Cash: The Untold Story of How and Why Foreign Governments and Businesses Helped Make Bill and Hillary Rich. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Scully, Gerald W. (1988). “The Institutional Framework and Economic Development.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (3): 652662.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scully, Gerald W. (1994). What Is the Optimal Size of Government in the United States? Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis.Google Scholar
Shambaugh, David (2016). China’s Future. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Shaw, Ian (2003). The Oxford History of Ancient Egypt. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shelley, Mary (2013). The Complete Poems of Percy Bysshe Shelley. New York: Modern Library/Random House.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. (1980). “The Private Use of Public Interest.” Society 17 (4): 3541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W. (1993). “Corruption.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3): 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W. (1998). The Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and Their Cures. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Silverstein, Michael J., Singhi, Abheek, Liao, Carol, and Michael, David (2012). The $10 Trillion Prize: Captivating the Newly Affluent in China and India. Boston: Harvard Business Review Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. (1978). “Rationality as Process and as Product of Thought.” American Economic Review 68 (2): 116.Google Scholar
Sinn, Hans-Werner (2014). The Euro-Trap: On Bursting Bubbles, Budgets, and Beliefs. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam ([1776] 1937). An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Edited by Cannan, Edwin. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Smith, Noah (2015). “Japan’s Debt Dilemma.” The Milken Institute Review, 2nd Quarter: 4654.Google Scholar
Smith, Richard Norton (2014). On His Own Terms: A Life of Nelson Rockefeller. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1): 6594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sowell, Thomas (1975). Race and Economics. New York: David McKey Co.Google Scholar
Spencer, Herbert (1896). The Study of Sociology. New York: D. Appleton and Company.Google Scholar
Stansel, Dean (2005). “Local Decentralization and Local Economic Growth: A Cross-Sectional Examination of U.S. Metropolitan Areas.” Journal of Urban Economics 57 (1): 5572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stansel, Dean (2006). “Jurisdictional Competition and Local Government Spending in U.S. Metropolitan Areas.” Public Finance Review 34 (2): 173194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, Whitney (2001). Deng Xiaoping: Leader in a Changing China. Minneapolis, MN: Lerner Publications Company.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. (1971). “The Economic Theory of Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (1): 321.Google Scholar
Strouse, Jean (1999). Morgan: American Financier. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Surowiecki, James (2004). The Wisdom of Crowds. New York: Doubleday/Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Svensson, Jakob (2005). “Eight Questions about Corruption.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (3): 1942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tax Foundation (Annual). Facts & Figures: How Does Your State Compare? Washington, DC: Tax Foundation.Google Scholar
Telser, Lester G. (1980). “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements.” Journal of Business 53 (1): 2744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, Melissa A. (2015). Govern Like Us: U.S. Expectations of Poor Countries. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Charles M. (1956). “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64 (5): 416424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis ([1835–1840] 2003). Democracy in America. Edited by Kramick, Isaac. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Tolstoy, Leo (2010). War and Peace. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toynbee, Albert Joseph ([1934–1961] 1989). A Study of History. Edited by Caplan, Jane. New York: Gramercy.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon (1967). “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft.” Western Economic Journal 5 (3): 224232.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, Seldon, Arthur, and Brady, Gordon L. (2002). Government Failure: A Primer in Public Choice. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.Google Scholar
UNESCO (2014). Higher Education in Asia. Montreal: UNESCO Institute for Statistics.Google Scholar
United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime. Global Study on Homicide 2013. Vienna, Austria: United Nations.Google Scholar
Wagner, Adolph (1958). “Three Extracts on Public Finance.” In Classics in the Theory of Public Finance 115. Edited by Musgrave, Richard A. and Peacock, Alan. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wallis, W. Allen (1976). An Overgoverned Society. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Walters, Stephen J. K. (2014). Boom Towns: Restoring the Urban American Dream. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Wang, Xuanhui (1998). Taxation in China, 1997/1998. Hong Kong: FT Law and Tax, Asia Pacific.Google Scholar
Weber, Max ([1905] 2002). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Weitzman, Martin L. (1974). “Prices vs. Quantities.” Review of Economic Studies 41 (4): 472491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Welch, Finis (1966). “Measurement of the Quality of Schooling.” American Economic Review 56 (2): 379392.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1976). “Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies-In General with Respect to CATV.” Bell Journal of Economics 1 (1): 73104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, James Q. (1989). Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Winter, Jay (2003). Editor. America and the Armenian Genocide of 1915. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald (1989). “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97 (6): 13951424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolf, Charles J. (2003). Markets or Governments: Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Woods, Frederick A. (1913). The Influence of Monarchs: Steps in a New Science of History. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Workman, Samuel (2015). The Dynamics of Bureaucracy in the U.S. Government: How Congress and Federal Agencies Process Information and Solve Problems. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Factbook (2015). Central Intelligence Agency. www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/index.html February 2, 2016.Google Scholar
Zhang, Weiying (2015). “The Power of Ideas and Leadership in China’s Transition to a Liberal Society.” Cato Journal 35 (1): 140.Google Scholar
Zimbardo, Philip G. (2007). The Lucifer Effect: Understanding How Good People Turn Evil. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Ziobrowski, Alan J., Boyd, James W., Cheng, Ping X., and Ziobrowski, Brigitte J. (2004). “Abnormal Returns from the Common Stock Investments of Members of the United States Senate.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39 (4): 661676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ziobrowski, Alan J., Boyd, James W., Cheng, Ping X., and Ziobrowski, Brigitte J. (2011). “Abnormal Returns from the Common Stock Investments of Members of the U.S. House of Representatives.” Business and Politics 13 (1): 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zingales, Luigi G. (2012). A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Zucman, Gabriel (2015). The Hidden Wealth of Nations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zupan, Mark A. (1989). “The Efficacy of Franchise Bidding Schemes in the Case of Cable Television: Some Systematic Evidence.” Journal of Law and Economics 32 (2): 401456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zupan, Mark A. (1991a). “Paradigms and Cultures: Some Economic Reasons for Their Stickiness.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 50 (1): 99103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zupan, Mark A.(1991b). “An Economic Explanation for the Existence and Nature of Political Ticket Splitting.” Journal of Law and Economics 34 (2): 343369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zupan, M.A. (2011). “The Virtues of Free Markets.” Cato Journal 31 (2): 36.Google Scholar
Zupan, Mark A. (2015a). “Government Self-Capture and the Decline of Nations.” Unpublished working paper, Simon Business School, University of RochesterGoogle Scholar
Zupan, Mark A.(2015b). “The Duration and Motivation of Autocracies.” Unpublished working paper, Simon Business School, University of Rochester.Google Scholar
Zupan, Mark A.(2015c). “The Road to Virtue.” Schweizer Monat, Issue 1030.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Mark A. Zupan, Alfred University, New York
  • Book: Inside Job
  • Online publication: 06 April 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316599983.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Mark A. Zupan, Alfred University, New York
  • Book: Inside Job
  • Online publication: 06 April 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316599983.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Mark A. Zupan, Alfred University, New York
  • Book: Inside Job
  • Online publication: 06 April 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316599983.012
Available formats
×