Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-5lx2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-01T07:24:20.373Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conclusion: downstream from industrialisation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 September 2009

Get access

Summary

In a much-quoted statement, J. L. Hammond described the industrial revolution as ‘a storm that passed over London and broke elsewhere’. The storm broke at the top of the river, upstream in the production process, where raw materials were changed into semifinished goods – bales of cloth, bars of iron – or finished capital goods such as steam engines. It all took place a long way from London, the goods came down to London, and London adapted itself to them. It did so, not by building factories and competing directly – the cost of factory production in London would have rendered this prohibitive. With its higher costs – its more expensive land and labour, its more expensive coal and the alternative outlets for local finance – manufacturing in London could not compete if its production processes were identical to those of the provinces and the material that it processed cost as much as in the provinces. Where London could compete was by taking advantage of its proximity to the market, its low transport costs and its ample supply of labour. It specialised at the ‘downstream’ end of production, but it could only do so by continually adapting, both to constantly fluctuating markets within the capital and also to falling costs outside the capital. The tendency was to move up-market – fustian manufacture left London during the course of the seventeenth century, framework knitting during the early eighteenth century, the mass production of silk and handkerchiefs increasingly by the late eighteenth century, shoes likewise.

Type
Chapter
Information
London in the Age of Industrialisation
Entrepreneurs, Labour Force and Living Conditions, 1700–1850
, pp. 231 - 240
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×