Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-06T06:19:50.269Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Strategizing With Institutional Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 May 2024

Harry Sminia
Affiliation:
Strathclyde Business School

Summary

This text consults seven variants of institutional theory to explore how these can be applied to strategic management. These variants are New Institutional Economics, Old Institutionalism, New Institutionalism, institutional entrepreneurship and change, intra organizational institutionalization, institutional logics, and institutional work. In doing so, three strategic management styles are distinguished: competitiveness based strategic management, legitimacy based strategic management, and performativity based strategic management. While the competitive based style sees institutional theory submitting to mainstream strategy research, offering additional variables and considerations to explain competitive advantage, the legitimacy based style makes institutional theory a strategy theory in its own right by providing an explanation for an organization's viability that emphasizes legitimacy over competitive advantage. The performativity based style is an even more radical departure from mainstream strategizing by purporting that a future is actively created with organizations making contributions as emerging issues are being dealt with.
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781009357654
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 13 June 2024

1 Introduction: Applying Institutional Theory to Strategy

For many reasons it is difficult to write about how institutional theory is relevant for strategic management. These include it not being clear what exactly an institution is, what it explains, and how it is to be explained. Some argue that institutional theory is not a theory at all and more a brand with which researchers identify (Reference Alvesson, Hallett and SpicerAlvesson et al., 2019). Rather than taking these reasons as an excuse to declare institutional theory as useless and as having to get its act together, we can take this criticism as indicative of the complex world that organizations must deal with. When we do that, we open up a rich and nuanced understanding of what can be deemed as of ‘strategic’ importance, or indeed to understand what strategic management is about. Institutional theory not only adds to what we must consider when thinking about the content of our strategies. It also has things to say about the process or management part; about how strategy might be realized or implemented.

Despite the proliferation of definitions of ‘institution’, there are some common threads. Firstly, institution is an expression of social order; of a regularity in human activity, which tends to occur time and time again. Social order is the bedrock of society. Without social order, society would not exist. Moreover, institution refers to something that is experienced as real yet is largely virtual and intangible; associated with norms, values, understandings, meanings, ideas, and cognitions. For strategic management, institutional theory potentially provides a range of different understandings of how firms and any other types of organization can and must function in society at large. Reference Maurice, Lammers and HicksonMaurice (1979) described institutions as ‘the societal effect’. Moreover, by recognizing that organizations are little societies by themselves, institutional theory has something to say about how these can and must be managed as well.

The proliferation of the many variants of institutional theory that we have is a consequence of the many ways in which ideas have been developed about how to understand society and about how it could and should be governed. The concept of institution is a prominent feature in sociology, economics, and political science. Increasingly, the words ‘institution’, ‘institutional’, and ‘institutionalization’ appear in management and organization theory (Reference Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyGreenwood et al., 2008), often as derivatives or ‘borrowings’ of theorizing in sociology, economics, and, to a lesser extent, political science.

Secondly, legitimacy is a key term in theorizing about institutions. Again, there are many definitions in existence (Reference SuchmanSuchman, 1995; Reference Suddaby, Bitektine and HaackSuddaby et al., 2017). As a common thread, legitimacy tries to capture that for an organization to be able to exist and function in society, its activities in some way must be acceptable, suitable, tolerable, effectual, or something of that nature. For business firms, legitimacy compares with the requirement of being competitive or having competitive advantage. Some institutional theorists in management and organization see legitimacy as a contributor to competitive advantage – legitimacy helps a firm to be more competitive. Others see it as an additional requirement – firms must be both competitive and legitimate. And there are those who see competitive advantage as being defined by legitimacy – legitimacy tells what the competition is supposed to be about.

There is also a resemblance with the concept of value in that there are many declarations that organizations must produce value to be economically viable or justified. Value tends to be closely associated with money. What an organization delivers is compared with the costs or the price that has to be paid. Legitimacy tends to rely on a broader justification, albeit money considerations often are part of it. The difference is reminiscent of the Oscar Wilde quote about knowing the costs (money) of everything but the value (understood as legitimacy) of nothing, although this comparison might do an injustice to the multi-facedness of the notion of value (cf. Reference Lepak, Smith and TaylorLepak et al., 2007). Nevertheless, organizations – and even business firms – can be considered legitimate without ever making a profit or despite forever exceeding their allocated budgets (Reference Meyer and ZuckerMeyer & Zucker, 1989).

There are branches of institutional theory that concentrate more on institutionalization than on institutions. Their concern is about how legitimacy is gained and lost, or more fundamentally about how what is legitimate changes, rather than about how to fulfil the requirements of legitimacy as these might exist. These theories offer explanations about how organizations contribute to maintaining societal demands and expectations, how they help changing these to their advantage, or sometimes more altruistically, how people and organizations can make society a better place to live in.

Organizations and especially business firms being actively involved in changing what is seen as legitimate to their advantage points towards a serious ethical concern. To what extent is it right or legitimate for commercial or other partial interests to tell society what is right and what is wrong? Institutional theorists who see competitive advantage as a requirement separate from legitimacy often argue that legitimacy is the responsibility of government whose task is to set out the playing field so that firms then can compete within this (often with an expectation that this government is democratically elected). Institutional theorists who see legitimacy and competitiveness as intertwined do not have it that easy, ending up with theories that not only explain but also take up moral positions.

Legitimacy considerations can be converted into strategic management applications, and indeed some of them already have. Besides, while discussing strategy, managers can find themselves using argumentations that resemble one of the many variants of institutional theory without them knowing it. In trying to implement strategy, they might be informed by their own – maybe intuitively derived – ‘theory-in-use’ (Reference Argyris and SchönArgyris & Schön, 1978), that is the way they understand how they can be effective as a manager. A strategist’s theory-in-use could well be a variant of institutional theory.

What this text has on offer is not the ultimate or best institutional theory for strategic management. Instead, it provides an opportunity for readers who are practicing strategists to compare their understanding of strategic management and how they do it, to the translations into the realm of strategy of several prominent but different variants of institutional theory. For researchers, the text delivers an overview of the state-of-affairs regarding institutional theory and its relevance and maybe irrelevance for the field of strategic management. It will also develop some ideas for further research and what interesting research questions would be, at some point even boldly suggesting to re-direct the strategy field towards becoming more sociologically informed.

To get to grips with institutional theory and its applicability in strategic management it is useful to understand that the theorizing is stratified. There is a foundation of basic theories derived from economics like methodological individualism (Reference Von MisesVon Mises, 1949), or derived from sociology like social construction (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966), structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984), or actor-network theory (Reference LatourLatour, 2005), which have worked their way into variants of institutional theory like Old Institutionalism (Reference SelznickSelznick, 1957), New Institutionalism (Reference DiMaggio, Powell, Powell and DiMaggioDiMaggio & Powell, 1991), institutional logics (Reference Thornton, Ocasio, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyThornton & Ocasio, 2008), or institutional work (Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence & Suddaby, 2006), and into more specific institutional theory applications like Non-Market Strategy (Reference Mellahi, Frynas, Sun and SiegelMellahi et al., 2016), or into International Business/Strategy (Reference Hotho, Pedersen, Wood and DemirbagHotho & Pedersen, 2012) and strategic change (Reference Hinings and GreenwoodHinings & Greenwood, 1988a).

The text will trace these lineages, starting with economics-derived New Institutional Economics and its applications in strategy. This will be followed by exploring the more sociological variants and their basic theoretical roots as well as their (potential) application into strategy. Often enough, there is a clearly recognizable ancestry from basic theory to strategy application, aided by academic texts referencing the associated literature. Nevertheless, in many cases, there is more reading between the lines required to make the connections, having to rely on recognizing similar argumentation that appears in basic theory, in management and organization theory and research, and in strategy applications. Referencing and mutual criticizing does provide many clues about where authors get their ideas from. Albeit some contributions are a bit promiscuous, combining ideas with different parentage.

A complication in making all these variants of institutional theory relevant for strategic management is the presumption of agency that is built into the notion of strategy. Strategic management assumes a strategist to have ‘strategic choice’ (Reference ChildChild, 1972); to have sufficient command over the process by which an organization performs to be able to direct this process towards a desired outcome. From an institutional theory point of view, this presumption of agency is problematic because the very notion of institution proclaims that something extra-individual imposes social order on to this process, determining how this process proceeds towards maybe different outcomes than the strategist had intended. Within institutional theory, this complication started being referred to as the ‘paradox of embedded agency’ (Reference HolmHolm, 1995; Reference Seo and CreedSeo & Creed, 2002). Alternative variants of institutional theory differ from each other regarding what is proposed as a solution to this paradox, or whether this is made a point of at all.

Each variant of institutional theory has different presumptions of how process proceeds, or as it will be referred to in this text: process principles. That is, among the many layers in every alternative version of institutional theory there is a specific presumed process philosophy of how process progresses, from which the extent of presumed agency or strategic choice can be derived. These process principles can be traced back to basic theories like methodological individualism, social construction, structuration theory, or actor-network theory, which underpin the many variants of institutional theory. Moreover, different process principles have different ideas about what animates the process, or what is the deus ex machina that make it ‘go’. The main objective of specifying the process principles is to recognize the distinctions and what each variant has to say about strategic management.

This is expected to help not only in understanding how and why different institutional theories are different, but also to recognize how a strategist’s theory-in-use compares and to add to a strategist’s repertoire of different ways by which strategic problems can be appreciated and dealt with. A similar usefulness is envisioned for the researcher in that demarcating the differences between as well as the lineages of the many conversations in the field can point the way forward towards interesting future research questions in relation to strategic management. What is deemed impossible is to synthesize everything into one ‘grand’ institutional theory. The fundamental differences are just too large.

The relevance of institutional theory will be assessed on the basis of a depiction of the strategy process that distinguishes between three different spheres (Reference SminiaSminia, 2022) (see Figure 1). In its broadest sense, there is a process of firms and organizations surviving and being successful in a larger environment. The textbook understanding in the strategy field is that this sphere is characterized by competition and that survival and success depends on having competitive advantage (cf. Reference BarneyBarney, 1986; Reference PorterPorter, 1980).

Figure 1 Textbook strategizing.

Zooming into the detail of this environmental survival process there are all these firms and organizations each engaging in their own organizational strategy process, expecting that this somehow will aid the organization’s success and survival. The textbook recommendation for this sphere is that there should be a form of explicit strategic planning in place by which a strategy is formulated (cf. Reference AnsoffAnsoff, 1965). Ideally, such a plan should describe how the organization should position itself in the competitive environment, how the organization’s unique capabilities pose a competitive advantage that allows for this positioning, and how this positioning should be executed.

Zooming in even more, there are people – individual strategists – who contribute their thinking and acting to the organizational strategy process. In this third sphere, the textbook strategist is depicted as a rational decision-maker who processes all the relevant information to make the right choices. Realizing a strategy then is a matter of executing a plan (cf. Reference Hrebiniak and JoyceHrebiniak & Joyce, 1984), of designing and structuring an organization, of putting the right culture and people in place, of acquiring the finance and investments needed, and of monitoring key performance indicators (cf. Reference Kaplan and NortonKaplan & Norton, 1996) to check whether the implementation is on track.

In a way, sketching out strategic management as a planning process that deals with competition is a bit of a caricature, yet is still the dominant theory-in-use with strategy practitioners as well as with many strategy scholars. Most of the strategy textbooks are written around and endorse this model. It is the distinction between the three spheres of the environmental survival process, the organizational strategy process, and the activities of the individual strategist which will help with pinpointing how various variants of institutional theory have questioned and changed how each sphere can be understood. In doing so, the traditional planning model and the problematization of strategy as being about competitive advantage has been amended or on occasion completely dismissed, although there are instances where the planning model has been maintained with contributions being offered accordingly. What we will end up with is not only an appreciation that there is much more to strategic management than what the basic textbook model tells us. Applying institutional theory to strategy also tells us how basic the textbook model is.

There already are various overviews of institutional theory. These either describe the intellectual development over time (Reference Glynn and D’AunnoGlynn & D’Aunno, 2023; Reference ScottScott, 1987) or attempt to provide a synthesis (Reference Micelotta, Lounsbury and GreenwoodMicelotta et al., 2017; Reference ScottScott, 2014).Footnote 1 There also are earlier attempts at describing how institutional theory can be made relevant for strategic management (Reference Ingram and SilvermanIngram & Silverman, 2002; Reference Raynard, Johnson, Greenwood, Jenkins and AmbrosiniRaynard et al., 2016; Reference Smets, Greenwood, Lounsbury, Golsorkhi, Rouleau, Seidl and VaaraSmets et al., 2015a; Reference Suddaby, Seidl and LêSuddaby et al., 2013). The attempts to make institutional theory relevant for strategy tend to concentrate on one or just a few variants of institutional theory. The overviews do not relate institutional theory specifically to strategy. This text fills that gap. It works its way through all variants that can be made useful for strategy. These are New Institutional Economics, Old Institutionalism, New Institutionalism, institutional entrepreneurship and change, intra-organizational institutionalism, institutional logics, and institutional work. There is some arbitrariness in how the different variants of institutional theory have been distinguished. It follows the precedents set by previous overviews but also was led by the distinctive contributions to strategy by which different variants can be characterized.

Each of these institutional theory variants will be treated to a concise description of how it came about, what it tries to explain, how this explanation is provided, the underlying process principles, and how it develops the notion of institution. Table 1 provides an initial, yet course, overview. From this, the application of each variant to strategic management is developed by indicating what it has to say about the environmental survival process, the organizational strategy process, and the strategist. With some variants, applications have already been developed or research in the strategy field has referenced them, and this will be made use of. This concerns Non-Market Strategy, some research in international business/strategy, research on strategic change, and some research under the Strategy-as-Practice banner. Particular attention will be given to what each variant does with the notion of ‘strategic choice’ because this is so pivotal for the whole idea of strategic management.

Table 1 Overview of Institutional Theory Variants

Process PrincipalsInstitutionAgencyProcess animated byProvides explanation of
New Institutional Economicsmethodological individualismrules of the gameindividual choice with cognitive limitationsefficiencyeconomic exchange
Old Institutionalismmethodological individualisman organization infused with valueleadership within negotiated compromisemeaningwhether an organization is an institution or a bureaucracy
New Institutionalismsocial constructionnorms and values outside organizationsdetermined by norms and valuescomplianceisomorphism/how an organization behaves
Institutional entrepreneurshipstructuration theoryregular and recurrent activity patternsimplicated by the duality of structurereflexivityepisodic institutional change
Intra-organizational institutionalizationstructuration theory/sensemakingan organization’s interpretative schemeimplicated by the duality of structurereflexivityincremental change alternated with strategic change
Institutional logicsinstitutional logics perspectivean institutional logicdistributed among many actorsindividual reflectionheterogeneity/accommodation of institutional complexity
Institutional workstructuration theoryregular and recurrent activity patternsimplicated by the duality of structurereflexivityinstitutional continuity and change
Institutional performative workactor-network theory/theory of practiceregular and recurrent activity patternsagencementteleoaffectivityconstant institutional becoming

Eventually, some synthesis will be provided by proposing three different strategic management styles as emerging out of the applications of institutional theory to strategy. These are competitiveness-based strategic management, legitimacy-based strategic management, and performativity-based strategic management. Each style provides an outline of how strategy is to be done with which a strategist can compare their own theory-in-use. Each style also is suggestive of further research in the strategy field. More specifically, while the competitive-based style would utilize institutional theory to further develop mainstream strategy research by adding additional variables and considerations for explaining and managing competitiveness, the legitimacy-based style and particularly the performativity-based style have the potential to be developed into much needed alternatives to mainstream strategy research. In this way, institutional theory offers an opportunity for the strategy field to re-think what strategy and strategic management is about.

2 Institutions as Constraints: New Institutional Economics

Economics’ dominant neo-classical approach has little room for institutions or arrangements of social order that somehow influence what people do. It assumes a Homo economicus or rational actor who is free to make any choice based on information that is equally and universally available for everybody. Reference VeblenThorstein Veblen (1909) was an early dissident voice who argued that people when making economic decisions might not be as rational as assumed. He suggested that economists should develop economic theory assuming that people are creatures of habit. They seldomly make deliberate and rational choices. Instead, they just do what they are used to do, because it is customary or due to tradition. This alternative to neo-classical economics lingered on for quite some time under the label of institutional economics. The basic idea is that habits develop into institutions that tell people what to do and how to do it, rather than them being free to rationally choose what they like.

Douglas Reference NorthNorth (1986, Reference North1990, Reference North1991) eventually took this on and developed what is now referred to as New Institutional Economics (NIE). He was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1993. His project concentrates on answering the question how economic activity can be explained when we abandon the neo-classical ideal of frictionless exchange. Frictionless exchange is what rational actors do in perfect markets when making buy and sell decisions with all information being available. His basic argument is that economic exchange is far from frictionless, especially because of cognitive limitations in human information processing. Drawing on Herbert Reference SimonSimon (1957), he assumes economic actors are only capable of bounded rationality. To him: ‘Individuals make choices based on subjectively derived models that diverge among individuals and the information that actors receive is so incomplete that in most cases these divergent models show no tendency to converge’ (17). This lack of convergence is what is responsible for generating uncertainty. People just cannot know how other people will act because everybody thinks differently. In turn, this uncertainty adds transaction costs: the costs of engaging in economic exchange. For economic exchange, some kind of effort is required, which translates into what can be understood as the costs of doing business. To North, economic exchange is far from frictionless.

The reasons why this inherent uncertainty about how other people might think and act adds transaction costs is twofold. One reason is that because of this inherent uncertainty some kind of assessment or measurement is required for both parties in the transaction regarding what is being exchanged. Will the seller deliver value? Will the buyer be able pay up? Before doing the deal, people want to know what they get out of it. They need to put effort, time, money into investigating what they will get. The other reason is the costliness of enforcement. Especially if a deal is not instantaneous but requires a seller to perform for a buyer over an extended period and payment comes in instalments, some form of mutual supervision is required to make sure the seller keeps its promise and the buyer pays up.

The solution to this inherent uncertainty is institutions – which are defined as ‘the rules of the game in a society’ (Reference NorthNorth, 1990: 3) – that constrain economic activity. These are rules that prohibit or permit what economic actors can do. This can be a good thing or a bad thing because institutions can be efficient and inefficient. Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) argument is that if there are rules that constrain people’s behaviour, uncertainty would diminish. Institutions that accomplish this are considered efficient. Institutions that only manage to complicate economic exchange and add transaction costs are considered inefficient. Moreover, he argues that economic activity cannot exist without institutions.

Institutions as rules of the game and as constraints are either formal or informal. Informal constraints are ‘part of the heritage that we call culture’ (Reference NorthNorth, 1990: 37) with culture referred to somewhat simply as ‘knowledge, values, and other factors that influence behavior’ (citing Reference Boyd and RichardsonBoyd & Richardson, 1985: 2). Informal rules are also referred to as being ‘embodied in customs, traditions, and codes of conduct’ (Reference NorthNorth, 1990: 6) as well as ‘(1) extensions, elaboration, and modifications of formal rules, (2) socially sanctioned norms of behavior, and (3) internally enforced standards of conduct’ (40). A distinguishing feature that sets them apart from formal rules to North is that informal rules tend to be self-imposed and emerge somewhat spontaneously.

It feels as if Reference NorthNorth (1990) sees informal rules as all norms and values that have not been formalized, albeit recognizing that formalization is a matter of degree. Formal rules are explicitly formulated and enforceable, and vary ‘from constitutions, to statue and common laws, to specific bylaws, and finally to individual contracts’ (47). Formal rules exist as and apply to jurisdictions, mostly in the form of a country, with a government and a judiciary ultimately being responsible for formalization and enforcement.

Having proposed why and how institutions as constraints and as rules of the game are essential for economic exchange, Reference NorthNorth (1990) goes on to explain why some countries are more prosperous than others. This is because institutions in rich countries have developed in a way that makes their institutions efficient and minimize transaction costs. Efficient institutions facilitate economic exchange and therefore economic growth. Poorer countries are hampered by institutions that are inefficient and make economic exchange more difficult, therefore adding transaction costs. In making that argument, the institutions that matter include labour regulation, the justice and judicial system, political rights and civil liberties, property rights, taxation policies, the financial system, political stability in general, but also corruption. Reference NorthNorth (1990) has something to say about firms as well but does not really develop it. He likes to refer to firms as players in a sports game, having to find strategies to win while adhering to the rules of the game.

Oliver Williamson, well-known for developing Transaction Costs Economics (TCE) (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1975, Reference Williamson1981), is more specific about how institutions as constraints appear with individual firms. He is also considered a representative of New Institutional Economics. He often refers to John Reference CommonsCommons (1934) – another early institutional economist – who proclaimed the transaction as the basic unit of analysis for the economist. Oliver Williamson was awarded the Nobel Prize in 2009. Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000) proposes to differentiate between four levels of analysis when dealing with institutions to then position firms as playing within the rules of the game at level 3. However, each level from top to bottom constrains the level below while from bottom to top there are presumed feedback effects.

The highest level (1) of analysis is the level of embeddedness (cf. Reference GranovetterGranovetter, 1985) which Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000) elaborates by way of referring to Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) informal rules or constraints, also denoted as ‘culture’. Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000) claims that economists have not been able to satisfactorily explain how and why informal institutions appear and take shape.Footnote 2 Level 2 is Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) formal rules, with Williamson picking up North’s thesis that countries need to get the institutions right, that is, efficient, by having these institutions minimalizing transaction costs. Williamson refers to this as ‘1st order economizing’, and largely the responsibility of governments. Level 3 is – in Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) terms – about playing the game within the existing rules. This is for firms to get right to maximize their performance. To Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000), this is a matter of choosing the appropriate mode of governance in terms of his TCE (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1975), which he refers to as 2nd-order economizing. Level 4 then is about resource allocation and employment, and firms organizing themselves according to the appropriate governance mechanism. This is the level of 3rd-order economizing, where Williamson claims that neo-classical economics still applies.

In a way Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000) positions TCE as a further elaboration of the inherent uncertainty that according to Reference NorthNorth (1990) frustrates the neo-classical ideal of frictionless economic exchange and which generates transaction costs, and for which efficient institutions as constraints are the solution, although his classic Markets and Hierarchies book was published fifteen years earlier. Rather than just bounded rationality, there are several compounded factors that create this inherent uncertainty or, as Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (1975) prefers, ‘moral hazards’. A moral hazard to him is any reason why an economic exchange might not have been satisfactory for either the seller or the buyer, and therefore will cause market failure.

Moral hazards are present because of the ‘human factors’ of ‘bounded rationality’ as with North, but also because of ‘opportunism’, the ‘environmental factors’ of ‘uncertainty/complexity’ and ‘small numbers’, and because of ‘information impactedness’, all entrenched within ‘atmosphere’ (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1975). Bounded rationality has already been explained as associated with the cognitive limitations on human information processing. To Williamson, this combines with uncertainty/complexity as the reason why information is always questionable. Opportunism refers to the likelihood that people will cheat if given a chance, which creates uncertainty because you will never know whether they will. The risk is mitigated when you are dealing with many buyers and sellers because the risk of being cheated averages out, but is especially present when there are only small numbers and is particularly pressing in situations of ‘asset specificity’. Asset specificity is a situation where that what is exchanged is specific to one buyer and one seller. Information impactedness is about all actors knowing something about the exchange but this not being evenly shared. Consequently, different actors must gather different information to level up, and therefore their transaction costs will be different while they will never know how much information asymmetry is still left. All of this is entrenched in atmosphere. With atmosphere Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (1975) appears to express that different actors might appreciate an economic exchange differently, especially with regard to the value of what is being exchanged.

Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (1975) goes on to argue that to deal with this uncertainty some form of governance will appear. Governance in a way is an institution of some sort that constraints economic actors and therefore mitigates uncertainty and minimizes transaction costs. For this he assumes there exists a ‘“natural order” with which governance structures take shape in relation to the attributes of transactions’ (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1999a: 314). If there are no moral hazards, the neoclassical ideal of frictionless exchange will prevail. Frictionless exchange is the market end of a continuum between markets and hierarchies; with many hybrids appearing in between. What form this hybrid takes or whether we end up at the other end of hierarchy depends on what kind of safeguards to mitigate the moral hazards can be put in place. If no safeguards are possible at all, the hybrid form will be a contract that just incorporates all risk in the price that is agreed. If stipulating safeguards becomes so extensive that you end up with such a detailed specification of what needs to be done and how it must be done, you effectively end up with an organization. If that is the case, you might as well organize yourself into a hierarchy. Hybrids are contracts somewhere between market and hierarchy that specify the exchange in terms of price, risks, and safeguards with the lowest possible transaction costs as the guiding principle. However, Williamson continuously makes the point that contracts are never perfect. His thinking inspired Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (1991) initially to claim that rather than competitive advantage, efficiency in terms of minimizing transaction costs should be the main focus of strategy. He later positioned competitive advantage and his efficiency argument as complementary (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1999b).

NIE essentially is a variant of institutional theory that explains why economic exchange happens. It is because institutions as constraints alleviate the uncertainty about the outcomes of such economic exchange. NIE also expects that people look for efficiency in terms of minimizing transaction costs. On that basis Reference NorthNorth (1990, Reference North1991) provides suggestions about how NIE could be relevant for strategic management. In its most general sense, NIE sees the environmental survival process as firms making the most of the ‘rules of the game’ or the institutions that apply to them, although there are a few hints that firms could also involve themselves with influencing these rules (see Figure 2).

Figure 2 New institutional economics strategizing.

Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (1991) initially stipulated that the environmental survival process in strategy should focus on efficiency, but he later relented and declared efficiency and competitive advantage as complementary (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 1999b). For the efficiency part, strategy should focus on selecting arrangements that minimalize transaction costs with all the economic exchange that an organization is engaged in. This 2nd-order economizing should be followed by 3rd-order economizing of actually putting these governance arrangements in place (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 2000). This nicely fits with the presumption of the organizational strategy process being a matter of processing information about price, risk, and safeguards, with the strategist seen as a rational decision-maker albeit constrained by limited cognitive abilities. Strategy realization then happens by drafting and enforcing contracts on the continuum between market and hierarchy.

The underlying process principles of NIE are derived from Methodological Individualism (Reference Von MisesVon Mises, 1949) – as is the case with much of economics. Methodological Individualism presumes that collective effects like an institution or an organizational outcome ultimately are a consequence of individual choices and motivations. NIE does recognize that individuals when making choices are hampered by their cognitive limitations and other moral hazards, yet still are presumed to make them to the best of their abilities, motivated as they are by utility maximation and transaction costs minimalization. It is efficiency that is taken as ultimately animating the process. Just like gravity always will be moving water downstream despite obstacles getting in the way, efficiency is what drives the process forward in NIE.

Methodological Individualism also informs the conceptualization of the individual strategist as a rational decision-maker. North’s and Williamson’s theorizing then serves as cognitive aids that help with grasping the complexity of situations to draft and realize strategy. As such, NIE has been picked up by a research stream that has labelled itself as Non-Market Strategy, and by researchers in International Business/Strategy (IB/S).

Non-Market Strategy is establishing itself as a research stream within the strategic management field. It is put forward as something that strategic managers must concern themselves with just as much as with market or competitive strategy. The basic idea is that for a firm the environment is divided into two parts. The competitive environment requires competitive strategy. ‘The nonmarket environment includes those interactions that are intermediated by the public, stakeholders, government, the media, and public institutions. These institutions differ from those of the market environment because of characteristics such as majority rule, due process, broad enfranchisement, collective action, and publicness’ (Reference BaronBaron, 1995a: 47). The non-market environment requires a firm to also have a Non-Market Strategy (Reference BaronBaron, 1995a; Reference Henisz and ZelnerHenisz & Zelner, 2003; Reference Mellahi, Frynas, Sun and SiegelMellahi et al., 2016).

Most of the advice that researchers in this realm provide to strategic managers is that firms must engage with government policy to shape the non-market or regulatory environment in a way that their competitive advantage is preserved, if not enhanced. This is what is referred to as ‘corporate political activity’ (Reference GetzGetz, 1997; Reference Hillman and HittHillman & Hitt, 1999). How exactly strategic managers must do this varies with the country the firm is operating in, but more concrete theorizing and associated advice tend to be somewhat biased towards how it works in the USA (Reference Bonardi, Hillman and KeimBonardi et al., 2005; Reference de Figueirdo, Nickerson and Silvermande Figueirdo, 2009; Reference Holburn and Vanden BerghHolburn & Vanden Bergh, 2008; Reference Kingsley, Vanden Bergh and BonardiKingsley et al., 2012).

One of the basic theories underpinning Non-Market Strategy is NIE (Reference Doh, Lawton and RajwaniDoh et al., 2012). What is being picked up is that firms have to compete in an environment that is characterized by Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) rules of the game. All the theories and applications about competitive strategy still apply, yet this plays out within the confines of legislation and government policy. In terms of Reference WilliamsonWilliamson’s (2000) levels of analysis, firms are competing with each other at level 3 while being constrained by the formal rules of level 2. Some have taken up Williamson’s suggestion to strategically position a firm’s activities between market and hierarchy based on the transaction costs it faces. More concrete, this is about deciding whether to internalize activities, to go into partnerships of some sort, or to rely on the market (Reference Dorobantu, Kaul and ZelnerDorobantu et al., 2017), that is, Reference WilliamsonWilliamsons (2000) 2nd-order and 3rd-order economizing. Others focus on corporate political activity and investigate how firms can make regulation and government policies as institutions more efficient so that fewer transaction costs have to be endured (Reference Boddewyn and DohBoddewyn & Doh, 2011; Reference Henisz and ZelnerHenisz & Zelner, 2012). To Reference WilliamsonWilliamson (2000), this would be firms at level 3 contributing to 1st-order economizing by providing feedback to government who set the formal rules at level 2. Interestingly, Non-Market Strategy appears to leave the informal rules of level 1 alone.

Researchers who identify with the Non-Market Strategy research stream have also looked into how firms originating from one country can deal with the different institutional arrangements they will come across when operating in another country (Reference Boddewyn and DohBoddewyn & Doh, 2011; Reference Henisz and DeliosHenisz & Delios, 2004). With this, we move into the realm of IB/IS which also utilize NIE as one of the basic underpinning theoretical approaches (Reference Hotho, Pedersen, Wood and DemirbagHotho & Pedersen, 2012).

Like Non-Market Strategy, IB/S research has recognized that different countries have different institutional arrangements that pose different levels of transaction costs. The obvious conclusion then is that firms must take these into account when they are internationalizing. Researchers like Peng and Meyer take Reference NorthNorth’s (1990) explanation of the prosperity of a country depending on the quality of the institutions in that country to the level of firms. Whether and how to enter a country is then seen to depend on what institutions are in existence and how much transaction costs these add to the activities a firm wants to engage in. Peng and Meyer concentrated first on what they label as transition economies: Eastern European countries who had to re-organize their societies after the fall of communism (Reference MeyerMeyer, 2001; Reference Meyer and PengMeyer & Peng, 2005; Reference PengPeng, 2003; Reference Peng and HeathPeng & Heath, 1996). They then moved to mostly Asian emerging economies as being less developed or differently developed, and made the same argument (Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and PengMeyer et al., 2009; Reference Peng, Wang and JiangPeng et al., 2008).

This strand of IB/S research arrived at the same conclusion as Non-Market Strategy in that the institutional environment exists adjacent to the competitive environment (Reference PengPeng, 2006; Reference Peng, Wang and JiangPeng et al., 2008). The focus tends to be on the specific problems of entry mode, on how to operate in a foreign country, and whether to go for a trade arrangement, some kind of joint venture with a local partner, or a wholly owned subsidiary (Reference Domínguez, Gómez and MaícasDomínguez et al., in press; Reference MeyerMeyer, 2001; Reference PajunenPajunen, 2008; Reference PengPeng, 2003; Reference Peng and HeathPeng & Heath, 1996). Again, it all should be aimed at minimizing transaction costs or 2nd-order economizing (Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 2000), which in turn depends on how institutions have developed in a country. The less developed a country is, the more informal and market-based the entry mode should be, while countries with more developed institutions require more hierarchy by way of a wholly or partly owned subsidiary and direct investment (cf. Reference WilliamsonWilliamson, 2000).

With NIE and its applications in Non-Market Strategy and IB/IS, both strategic choice and implementation are taken as squarely within the agency of a strategist. A strategist is presumed to be free and able to formulate and execute a strategy. An organization is assumed to have the agency to position itself on the continuum between market and hierarchy by adopting the governance arrangements of its choice. In that sense, NIE strategizing is clearly agentic. It supposes that strategists and organizations can take initiatives and have control over their actions and outcomes. Both are taken to be autonomous, capable (albeit with cognitive limitations), and independent actors, who will behave purposefully to efficiently generate organizational outcomes.

3 Organizations as Institutions: Old Institutionalism

Old Institutionalism only got its label because New Institutionalism needed something to criticize to set out its own stall (Reference DiMaggio, Powell, Powell and DiMaggioDiMaggio & Powell, 1991). New Institutionalism will be introduced later and is not to be confused with the New Institutional Economics (NIE) from the previous chapter. Old Institutionalism is one of several institutional theories rooted in sociology, with Philip Reference SelznickSelznick (1949, Reference Selznick1957) often put at the heart of and seen as exemplary of this variant. Just like NIE, Old Institutionalism as a research project is a reaction to a dominant approach but on this occasion in organization theory. Like NIE rallying against neo-classical economics, Selznick was arguing against the then dominant conceptualization of the organization as a bureaucracy; as a collection of procedures, functions, and roles to achieve a specific goal as if it is a mechanism that can be engineered and fine-tuned to deliver a pre-defined set of outcomes as efficiently as possible. His study of the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) showed him that this organization did not comply with this ideal, yet the TVA was not deemed dysfunctional (Reference SelznickSelznick, 1949). The TVA was a 1933 initiative of the Roosevelt administration to economically develop the Tennessee River basin. Selznick found the TVA as an organization adapting its purpose and understanding of itself as it developed, mostly because it was focusing on specific stakeholders. This made it move away from its original purpose; making it difficult to understand this organization as a bureaucracy and as an efficient device to achieve specific pre-defined goals.

Reference SelznickSelznick’s (1957) book Leadership in Administration was an attempt to understand what was going on. In it he proposes an institutional theory that recognizes there is more to an organization than it being a bureaucracy designed to achieve a specific end in the most efficient and effective manner. Like NIE questioning the assumption of rational choice in economics, Selznick questioned the means-ends assumption of rationality in organization theory. His institutional theory distinguishes between organizations as bureaucracies and organizations as institutions. To him, many organizations exist and can be understood and managed as a bureaucracy. However, some organizations develop into an institution. Some organizations institutionalize: ‘to institutionalize is to infuse with value’ (Reference SelznickSelznick, 1957: 17).

The word ‘value’ here appears to denote something like ‘meaning’ in that the organization’s significance to those who are involved with it exceeds it just being a means to a specific end. The organization in a way has become an end itself. Selznick likes to refer to this as fulfilling ‘the expendability test’. An organization has become an institution if people care enough to want it to continue despite it having outlived its original purpose. The TVA started as a bureaucracy but became an institution because it became meaningful to a specific community for which it then became an end by itself. As the community changed the TVA adapted. More particularly, the TVA adopted environmental protection and the plight of poor African Americans and farm tenants as an important part of its remit. An organization’s identification with a community ‘involves the taking on of values, ways of acting and believing that are deemed important for their own sake’ by this community and therefore by the organization (Reference SelznickSelznick, 1957: 21).

Selznick writes about legitimacy – without using the word as such – as being super-imposed on and possibly replacing efficiency as the criterion by which an organization’s existence should be explained at least for an organization that has become an institution. His institutional theory, which is core to Old Institutionalism, is a theory that explains whether and why an organization takes on the form of a bureaucracy or of an institution. An organization develops from a bureaucracy into an institution or institutionalizes when it becomes meaningful for and in a specific community. Selznick’s institutional theory points at legitimacy as an important factor for understanding organizations.

Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) goes on to argue that when an organization has developed into an institution, it requires leadership rather than management. Management to Selznick is technocratic and about designing and running a bureaucracy. In contrast, leadership is about developing, maintaining, but also changing when required, the meaning of the organization in relation to the community it serves. On the one hand, this is a take on running an organization that was echoed later in the literature on transformational leadership (e.g. Reference BassBass, 1991; Reference Bennis and NanusBennis & Nanus, 1985) where a charismatic leader is urged to take charge by formulating and propagating meaning for the organization’s members. On the other hand, Selznick describes the process by which an organizations pursues its relevance for a community and also the choice of community to which it aligns itself as a negotiation and as a process characterized by organizational politics (cf. Reference Narayanan and FaheyNarayanan & Fahey, 1982; Reference PfefferPfeffer, 1981).

Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) also adopted the notion of ‘mission’ to refer to the reason why an organization as institution exists. He derived this from the military use of the term where mission is used to express the purpose of a specific military operation. He referred to the capability of an organization as institution to deliver on its mission as ‘distinctive competence’, which has been put forward as an early expression of the Resource-based View’s core capability concept (Reference FossFoss, 1997; Reference Mahoney and PandianMahoney & Pandian, 1992), although Selznick did not associate distinctive competence with competitive advantage. Mission as the expression of an organization’s purpose (Reference CampbellCampbell, 1987), however, has become a staple term in almost every strategic management textbook.

Apart from Old Institutionalism and the work of Reference SelznickSelznick (1949, Reference Selznick1957) being positioned as a stepping off point for New Institutionalism (Reference DiMaggio, Powell, Powell and DiMaggioDiMaggio & Powell, 1991), it saw application in International Business/Strategy (IB/S) by Reference KostovaKostova (1999; Reference Kostova and RothKostova & Roth, 2002). She problematizes multinational corporations (MNCs) as having each subsidiary organized differently because each subsidiary adapted to the values and ways of acting and thinking that are characteristic of the country in which it operates. These differences then explain why the adoption of headquarter designed and prescribed universal practices and procedures among all subsidiaries in an unequivocal manner is so difficult if not impossible. The argumentation subsequently was extended by seeing it as essential for local subsidiaries of MNCs to adapt to what is considered legitimate in the countries they operate in, explicitly criticizing the ‘isomorphism’ thesis (that will be explained later) of New Institutionalism (Reference Kostova and ZaheerKostova & Zaheer, 1999; Reference Kostova, Roth and DacinKostova et al., 2008).

Applying Old Intuitionalism in the realm of strategic management further, recognizing that organizations as an institution are ‘infused with value’, and as being meaningful for internal and external stakeholders rather than just being a ‘tool’ for achieving pre-defined goals, the environmental survival process is about being legitimate for the community the organization serves (see Figure 3). That is a legitimacy that is mostly about providing meaning for stakeholders. Meaning is what animates the process. Which community to pick happens by way of negotiation and consequently strategists are negotiators. Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) also recognizes that strategists have to provide meaning by formulating the organization’s mission as reflecting the values of the community the organization associates with. By implication, the organizational strategy process is a combination of organizational politics (Reference Narayanan and FaheyNarayanan & Fahey, 1982) and management of meaning (Reference Smircich and MorganSmircich & Morgan, 1982).

Figure 3 Old institutionalism strategizing.

The underlying process principles, by Reference SelznickSelznick’s (1996) own admission as with NIE, are derived from Methodological Individualism. The institutionalization of an organization by infusing it with value is taken to be the consequence of the actions and choices of organization members, although Selznick does recognize this happens through negotiation and compromise rather than by design. For this reason, there is some ambivalence about a strategist’s agency. On the one hand, Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) appears to propagate a form of leadership with a strategist taking charge of providing meaning for the organization, much like what was later proposed as transformational leadership (Reference BassBass, 1991; Reference Bennis and NanusBennis & Nanus, 1985). Selznick’s use of the word ‘mission’ chimes with this as well, preceding its later popularity for expressing an organization’s purpose (Reference CampbellCampbell, 1987). On the other hand, which constituents the organization associates with or, in other words, for whom the organization is meaningful and what this meaning is about, develops by way of negotiation, downplaying the possibility of a strategist or leader taking charge. Reference KostovaKostova (1999; Reference Kostova and RothKostova & Roth, 2002; Reference Kostova and ZaheerKostova & Zaheer, 1999; Reference Kostova, Roth and DacinKostova et al., 2008) puts a finer point on this by investigating and confirming how difficult it is for MNCs to manage different legitimacy requirements across various countries. Apparently, you cannot provide meaning by decree.

4 Organizations and Isomorphism: New Institutionalism

Up to the 1970s, the idea of organizations having to have a formal structure was not questioned as such. If organization structure was problematized, it was by enquiring how you could best translate the organization’s purpose or reason for its existence into an organizational design of departments, functions, job descriptions, procedures, and layers of management. Old Institutionalism originating with Reference SelznickSelznick (1949, Reference Selznick1957) contrasting organizations that are designed and structured in pursuit of rationally and of efficiently getting a job done with organizations that are infused with value to the extent that rationality and efficiency became less important. Selznick branded organizations infused with value as institutions.

Reference Meyer and RowanMeyer and Rowan (1977) and Reference Tolbert and ZuckerTolbert and Zucker (1983) went another route in questioning whether organizations are just means to an end. They started wondering about this because it became commonly recognized that for organizations to be effective, these had to rely more on the informal organization than on how an organization formally had been structured. ‘Doing everything by the book’ is a sure way of tripping an organization up. To answer this conundrum, they in a way extended the ‘infused with value’ argument by claiming that rationality and efficiency are also values. This means that an organization having a formal structure in pursuit of rationality and efficiency is a norm to which every organization must submit to be considered legitimate. Having a formal structure then is more of a symbol to signal that the organization is legitimate instead of formal structure contributing to the organization being efficient and effective.

Reference Meyer and RowanMeyer and Rowan (1977) and Reference Tolbert and ZuckerTolbert and Zucker (1983) with Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio and Powell (1983) took the argument one step further by not only claiming that organizations have a formal structure to remain legitimate rather than efficient; often sticking with organizational designs long beyond these having been effective and rational if these ever were, but also that organizations are isomorphic. Organizations all appear the same because organizations have to conform to the same norms and values. It are the norms and values as these exist outside the organization, which are referred to as institutions in what was labelled as New Institutionalism (Reference Powell and DiMaggioPowell & DiMaggio, 1991). Even the idea of organization itself as a means to get something done was put forward as having been institutionalized as a norm (Reference Zucker and BacharachZucker, 1983).

The process principles that underpin this line of thought moved away from the Methodological Individualism of New Institutional Economics and Old Institutionalism. Instead of institutions either as constraints or as organizations infused with value appearing as an effect that can be reasoned back to some form of deliberate choice by individual actors, New Institutionalism assumed institutions as having been socially constructed (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966).

Social construction is presented as a collective endeavour involving several, if not many, people. It is a process that still acknowledges that people make choices but also sees an effect of extra-human arrangements that are referred to as social constructions to which people must conform. Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger and Luckmann (1966) present these social constructions as emerging by way of the three steps of habitualization, externalization, and socialization. Habitualization occurs when people develop ways of dealing with situations or problems to then deploy the same solution every time a specific situation occurs or as a particular problem arises. At some point, this solution becomes the norm for dealing with the problem, with such a norm taking on an existence outside or externally from the people who deploy solutions to situations. In this way norms and values of how you should interpret a situation and of how you should behave in this situation become institutionalized as a social construction. People who might not be familiar with the norms and values can then be socialized into them so that they know how to behave and how to think.

Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger and Luckmann (1966) provided their Social Construction theory to explain how social order in society emerges. Reference Meyer and RowanMeyer and Rowan (1977), Reference Tolbert and ZuckerTolbert and Zucker (1983), and Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio and Powell (1983) took this sociological theory to explain how and why organizations are isomorphic, predominantly by stating that institutions are social constructions. Further research in the realm of New Institutionalism quickly moved beyond the norm of organizations having to have a formal structure and the values of having to be rational and efficient, to apply the requirement of legitimacy and its effect on organizations more generally to many other norms and values that are present. The thesis is that organizations strive to be legitimate to justify their existence and to avoid being sanctioned and starved from the resources they need to function. It is perhaps this thesis of isomorphism that is the main distinction between Old Institutionalism and New Institutionalism, with old institutionalism providing an explanation of why organizations (as institutions themselves) are all unique, as they identify with their respective communities, while new institutionalism purports that all organizations are the same, as they all conform to the same institutionalized expectations.

Indeed, to some New Institutionalism is just about isomorphism (Reference Glynn and D’AunnoGlynn & D’Aunno, 2023; Reference Ocasio and GaiOcasio & Gai, 2020). Isomorphic effects have been observed, for instance, with the adoption of certain technologies (Reference Robertson, Swan and NewellRobertson et al., 1996), entering strategic alliances (Reference Garcia-Pont and NohriaGarcia-Pont & Nohria, 2002), or adopting ISO 9000 standards (Reference Guler, Guillén and MacphersonGuler et al., 2002). Organizations were found to take these on not because of their inherent qualities or usefulness, but because adopting a particular technology, entering strategic alliances, or becoming ISO certified had become the norm and therefore everybody did this.

To others it developed into being about organizations remaining legitimate by conforming to norms and values exogenous to them (Reference Jepperson, Powell and DiMaggioJepperson, 1991; Reference ScottScott, 2014). More generally, the organizational field became the locus of the institutionalized norms and values that prescribe how organizations are expected to behave (Reference Zietsma, Groenewegen, Logue and HiningsZietsma et al., 2017). An organizational field is defined by Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio and Powell (1983: 148) as ‘those organizations that, in the aggregate, constitute a recognized area of institutional life: key suppliers, resource and product consumers, regulatory agencies, and other organizations that produce similar services or products’.

This inspired research that linked the activities and success of organizations to institutionalized expectations that exist at field level. For instance, Reference Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and KingLeblebici et al.(1991) took US radio broadcasting as an organizational field to find that over time, it was institutionalized differently. Initially radio broadcasting was about manufacturing radio sets, then about listening to national radio networks, to become about listening to local radio stations, with each era providing a different way in which you could make a profit from radio broadcasting. Reference Hargadon and DouglasHargadon and Douglas (2001) explained that Edison’s innovation of the electric light bulb had been successful because the way in which he set himself up as a business of providing illumination mimicked how illumination was provided already by way of gas lighting technology. Such observations and explanations led to suggestions that firm success and survival are not just a matter of competitive advantage but also a matter of compliance to institutionalized expectations to the extent that the way in which competition occurs and what defines competitive advantage is also a consequence of these institutionalized expectations (Reference DiMaggio, Powell, Powell and DiMaggioDiMaggio & Powell, 1991; Reference LawrenceLawrence, 1999).

Some ambiguity crept in about what exactly an ‘institution’ is and in its wake how we are to understand legitimacy. One of the discrepancies is whether an institution is something cognitive or something social. When an institution is seen as cognitive, it is taken as an attribute of an individual person and as residing in somebody’s mind, albeit with large numbers of people sharing the same thoughts to qualify as an institution. An institution as a cognitive phenomenon then is an idea or a thought and is likened to ‘schemata’ and ‘frames’ or thinking modes as developed in cognitive psychology. For instance, from a cognitive point of view an institution like ‘primary school’ is a thinking frame in people’s minds by which they attach meaning to a building by recognizing it as a school as well as providing an understanding of the activities that happen inside. When an institution is seen as social, it is taken as having an existence outside and independently from human perception. An institution as a social phenomenon has a largely intangible, but real, presence as a norm or a value despite of how individual people think about it, albeit can manifest itself in tangible ways. From a social point of view, ‘primary school’ as an institution is the norm by which children of a certain age are educated as opposed to home schooling or to not being educated at all, which exists whether you agree with it or not; even when you as an individual do not understand the idea of education whatsoever. The school building and how it is laid out is the tangible manifestation of primary education and how it is supposed to be done.

Another discrepancy is about whether an institution is only an institution when it is in some way formalized as a rule or a form of regulation or whether institutions exist largely in informal ways with some of them formalized into rules and regulations. From a formal regulation point of view primary education and primary schools are an institution because legislation obliges people to send their children to school from a certain age onwards. From an informal point of view, the primary school is a formalized form of the norm of having children educated alongside more informal arrangements like home schooling.

These discrepancies also translate into different understandings of legitimacy. Cognitive legitimacy then refers to how well an organization fits with common thought patterns or shared ideas. Normative legitimacy is about conforming to social norms and values. Regulative legitimacy is about how well an organization abides by the formal rules and regulations that apply to it. Reference ScottScott (2014) attempts to synthesize all three approaches by referring to the regulative, normative, and cognitive as the three pillars of institutions. He defines institutions as ‘consist[ing] of cognitive, normative, and regulative structures and activities that provide stability and meaning to social behavior. Institutions are transported by various carriers – cultures, structures, and routines – and they operate at multiple levels of jurisdiction’ (Reference ScottScott, 2014: 33). Scott’s three pillars have been popular in research on institutions and their effects even beyond the realm of New Institutionalism (Reference Boddewyn and DohBoddewyn & Doh, 2011; Reference Glynn and D’AunnoGlynn & D’Aunno, 2023; Reference HoffmanHoffman, 1999; Reference KostovaKostova, 1999; Reference OliverOliver, 1992). Nevertheless, declaring the cognitive, normative, and regulative as aspects of an institution ignores the somewhat fundamental differences that exist between each of these different understandings of what an institution is.

With his definition of what an institution is Reference ScottScott (2014) also extends the original focus of New Institutionalism away from organizational fields as the source and benchmark of what is legitimate and where institutions reside as per Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio and Powell (1983). Institutions to him can be rooted in at least six different levels. These are the levels of the world system, the societal level, the organizational field, the organizational population, the organization, and the organizational subsystem. Rather than just the organizational field, to Scott organizations must abide with institutionalized expectations originating from at least six different sources.

The more general New Institutionalism requirement that organizations and firms in particular have to be legitimate by conforming to institutionalized norms, values, and ideas made Reference OliverOliver (1991) propose that organizations have five ways to strategically respond. The options are acquiesce, compromise, avoidance, defiance, or manipulation. ‘Acquiesce’ means that the organization accepts the norms, values, and ideas for what these are and conforms to them. If we take the primary school example again, norms, values, and ideas manifest themselves in what it is that is to be taught, and in some countries, this developed into a national curriculum. Acquiesce means that a school unquestionably adopts this. This will also lead to isomorphism among all organizations that choose this option. Oliver recognizes that there are occasions that some institutionalized requirements are at odds with each other. For instance, with contentious subjects in a curriculum when nationally agreed ways of teaching certain elements are at odds with local sentiments and convictions. In those situations, an organization can opt to ‘compromise’. A school can teach both what is nationally required and what is locally preferred. Organizations can also opt to conceal not conforming to (some) institutionalized expectations. That happens when a school decides to deviate from the national curriculum but does not officially acknowledge this. That is the ‘avoid’ option. ‘Defiance’ as an option means that the organization openly resists conforming to what is expected. This happens when a school deviates and openly acknowledges that it is doing this. ‘Manipulation’ means that the organization actively tries to change (some) institutionalized norms, values, and ideas. A school might become active in a social movement to change the national curriculum.

There is a whole range of considerations that organizations are expected to take into account when choosing for either one of these options, roughly depending on how it understands its interests and how much scope there is to follow an option through. Reference OliverOliver (1991, Reference Oliver1997a, Reference Oliver1997b) sees legitimacy as separate from competitive advantage, or as she prefers it, the institutional environment and the task environment. When the organization identifies more with the demands from the task environment and the demands from the institutional environment are getting in the way, organizations would see their interests in terms of competitive advantage rather than legitimacy and will go against what the institutional environment tells them to do.

Looking at the various ways in which the notion of institution is understood in New Institutionalism it can be easily recognized that Non-Market Strategy as an area of research within strategic management is pre-occupied mostly with institution as formal rule or regulation and with regulative legitimacy; all at the level of a country because a country is taken as the primary legislative entity. This is especially the case because Non-Market Strategy is seen as adjacent to and separate from competitive strategy and as being about corporate political activity aiming to affect legislation from impeding a firm’s competitive advantage, if not enhancing it (Reference BaronBaron, 1995a, Reference Baron1995b; Reference de Figueirdo, Nickerson and Silvermande Figueirdo, 2009; Reference Hillman and HittHillman & Hitt, 1999; Reference Holburn and Vanden BerghHolburn & Vanden Bergh, 2008). There have been calls to extend the notion of institution within Non-Market Strategy to include cognitive and normative legitimacy but that has remained rather underdeveloped (Reference Doh, Lawton and RajwaniDoh et al., 2012; Reference Henisz and ZelnerHenisz & Zelner, 2012; Reference Mellahi, Frynas, Sun and SiegelMellahi et al., 2016).

A similar focus on regulative legitimacy is present in IB/S research, with a call for extending how the notion of institution is conceptualized having been made as well (Reference Hotho, Pedersen, Wood and DemirbagHotho & Pedersen, 2012). That is apart from the work done by Richard Reference WhitleyWhitley (1992, Reference Whitley1999, Reference Whitley2007) who developed almost singlehandedly the Business Systems approach in IB/S. He took the basic New Institutionalism idea that every firm has to comply with existing institutionalized expectations to argue that these expectations are different for different parts of the world (Reference WhitleyWhitley, 1990, Reference Whitley1994). Consequently, and drawing on the isomorphism argument, the way business is done will be the same within a country but vary between them. In Reference WhitleyWhitley (1991, Reference Whitley1994) the idea of country specific institutionalized patterns of doing business is developed into the notion of ‘business system’. A business system is characterized by institutionalized norms, values, and ideas about how people in organizations are managed and controlled, how governance and ownership play their part, and how exchange relationships between firms are configured. With these three aspects, he found striking differences between how this was arranged in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan/Hong Kong and by implication with the USA and the UK. The differences between each business system were traced back to a country’s historical development as a distinct society.

More specifically, in the USA and the UK managers are expected to control firms with formal structures and systems, with ownership and shareholding being emphasized for creating conglomerates, while relying on impersonal market exchange to trade goods and services between firms and with customers. Reference WhitleyWhitley (1991) found that Japan’s business system centres on the keiretsu: an informal business group in which loyalty plays a large part rather than formal structure, ownership, and impersonal economic exchange. Korea’s business system is characterized by the cheabol: a diversified conglomerate run and controlled by a single person or family, while Taiwan/Hong Kong’s business system is organized around family firms and kinship relations. In a way, Whitley took Reference ScottScott’s (2014) societal and organizational field levels and brought them to bear upon the organization level for the countries that he investigated.

All this allows him to make several points that are relevant for strategic management. Most importantly, he concludes that every firm has to function within a business system. This means that rather than seeing legitimacy as a requirement adjacent to competitive advantage – as is done by Reference OliverOliver (1991, Reference Oliver1997a, Reference Oliver1997b), in Non-Market Strategy, and up to this point in IB/IS – the norms, values, and ideas that come with a business system define how a firm has to operate in a country. In short and agreeing with Reference DiMaggio, Powell, Powell and DiMaggioDiMaggio and Powell (1991) and Reference LawrenceLawrence (1999), legitimacy tells firms how to compete because all business and economic activity is institutionally embedded. Therefore, differences between business systems explain differences in innovation patterns and strategies on a country-by-country basis, while firms act largely isomorphic – that is variations on a theme – within a country (Reference WhitleyWhitley, 2000).

Whitley also argues against the assumption of increasing globalization based on what to him is a misconception of there being universally applicable insights and ‘best practice’ ways of working. At best this is the spread of the Anglo-Saxon business system prevalent in the USA and the UK to other parts of the world, yet with alternative business systems in other countries not necessarily being converted (Reference WhitleyWhitley, 1998, Reference Whitley2003). He also reckons that multinational corporations who manage to be successful across different business systems develop an advantage specific to them of dealing with different institutionalized requirements compared to exclusively domestic firms (Reference WhitleyWhitley, 2007).

New Institutionalism set out to explain why organizations behave in the way that they do. The explanation put forward is about having to remain legitimate by conforming to norms, values and ideas as institutionalized arrangements that have developed external to the organization. Regarding the relevance of New Institutionalism for strategic management, for the environmental survival process, the requirement to remain legitimate, as with Old Institutionalism, has been clearly stated. On this occasion, rather than the organization becoming an institution because it has become infused with value (Reference SelznickSelznick, 1957), institutions primarily appear external to the organization as institutionalized arrangements of norms, values, and ideas by which an organization is expected to abide. This has been elaborated as specific as the norm of being effective and rational (Reference Meyer and RowanMeyer & Rowan, 1977), and more general as a configuration of expectations and requirements, which takes on the form of a business system (Reference WhitleyWhitley, 1999), or as an almost all-encompassing world system within which five more specific levels reside (Reference ScottScott, 2014). Interestingly, if competitive advantage is about being different (Reference PorterPorter, 1996), conforming to institutional pressures and isomorphism is about being the same.

However, some ambiguity about what exactly an institution is crept in. The first issue is about how an institution exists. Is an institution a cognitive phenomenon residing in people’s minds as a cognitive scheme or framework albeit shared among many? Or is an institution a social phenomenon existing independently from how people think about it; as having a real but intangible presence, albeit sometimes manifested in tangible ways. The second issue is about whether and when something is institutionalized. Is the term of ‘institution’ reserved for formal rules and legislation and do we only take formal regulation into account when we explain why an organization behaves in the way that it does? Or are all norms, values, and ideas that might be present referred to as institutions, the formal and the informal, the clear and the not-so-clear? Can you simply ignore these issues and like Reference ScottScott (2014) declare the cognitive, the social, and the regulative as the three pillars of an institution?

A third issue is about whether institutions occupy a realm or institutional environment that is separate from the resource and competitive constrictions put upon organizations and firms. The latter has been either referred to as the task environment (Reference OliverOliver, 1991) or the market environment (Reference Doh, Lawton and RajwaniDoh et al., 2012). Or whether everything in the environment is institutionally embedded? This position assumes that the way in which resources are distributed and become available, and the way competition takes place, is all dictated by institutionalized norms, values, and ideas. Both assumptions are present within New Institutionalism, and they are mutually exclusive.

The process principles underpinning New Institutionalism are mostly derived from Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger and Luckmann (1966) with institutions taken as coming into existence by way of social construction. When it comes to making this relevant for strategic management there is a parting of ways. Going in one direction, institutional pressures and the requirement of legitimacy is separated from competitive pressures and the requirement of competitive advantage. Going in the other direction, socially constructed institutional arrangements are seen as structuring how competition takes place.

Reference OliverOliver’s (1991) distinction between institutional environment and task environment is indicative for going in the first direction. It separates being legitimate from being competitive. Researchers in Non-Market Strategy appear to argue that competitiveness always trumps legitimacy (Reference BaronBaron, 1995a, Reference Baron1995b; Reference de Figueirdo, Nickerson and Silvermande Figueirdo, 2009; Reference Hillman and HittHillman & Hitt, 1999; Reference Holburn and Vanden BerghHolburn & Vanden Bergh, 2008). The environmental survival process for the non-market part of strategy then is about how to protect the firm from legislative interference that impedes its competitiveness, and possibly lobby for government action that enhances competitiveness (see Figure 4). The notion of legitimacy is restricted to adhering to formal rules and legislation. To execute Non-Market Strategy, firms are told to engage in corporate political activity. It very much fits with the textbook notion of strategic management as planning for competitive positioning to then also take the non-market environment into account. Like textbook strategic management, the process is animated by competitiveness.

Figure 4 New institutionalism strategizing as per non-market strategy.

The alternative direction for strategic management that applies New Institutionalism is to suppose that the way in which competition is structured is a consequence of a socially constructed institutionalized arrangement. This argument is found in Reference WhitleyWhitley’s (1999) concept of business systems. In the strategic management literature, the argument is also present in concepts like cognitive communities (Reference HuffHuff, 1982; Reference Porac, Thomas and Baden-FullerPorac et al., 1989) and industry recipes (Reference SpenderSpender, 1989) that denote that executives who manage companies that are in the same line of business, by way of how they have firms operate and compete, socially construct an industry structure or a market segmentation, which in turn informs how they understand their environment.

The environmental survival process then is about complying with institutionalized expectations as these are pressing down on the organization, and resulting in isomorphism (see Figure 5). The organizational strategy process reflects – and is informed by how well executives are socialized in – the institutionalized arrangements as these exist in the environment. There might well be a strategic planning process in place, but this largely serves the function of abiding by institutionalized arrangements, especially because it is the norm to plan when you do strategy. Because it makes sense that if you want to be in a certain line of business, you operate in the way that these businesses are expected to operate. If you would not conform, customers, suppliers, personnel, anybody, would not understand what your business is about and would therefore not engage with you. Consequently, the process is animated by compliance.

Figure 5 New institutionalism strategizing.

The isomorphism thesis in New Institutionalism questions the notion of strategic choice. A strategist essentially is a conformist who agrees with what is being expected. With the task or market environment seen as embedded within an institutional environment, carving out the possibility of strategic agency becomes problematic because all activity results from what institutions prescribe people to do (Reference BeckertBeckert, 1999; Reference HolmHolm, 1995). Despite social construction (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966) being phenomenological and therefore leaning towards the agentic side of the spectrum, its application here emphasizes the externalization aspect. An institution is mostly taken as prescribing how people are supposed to behave. However, by seeing competitiveness and legitimacy as separate demands put upon an organization, Non-Market Strategy has circumvented this rather deterministic quality of New Intuitionalism. Because legitimacy is taken as subordinate to competitiveness, the assumption of strategic choice is restored. The textbook form of strategizing remains intact with strategists and organizations free to choose their competitive strategy to treat institutions – understood as formal rules and legislation – as subjected to their corporate political activity.

5 Explaining Institutions: Institutionalization and Institutional Entrepreneurship as Episodic Change

If New Institutionalism is about the presence of institutions explaining what organizations and people do, then institutionalization is about explaining the presence of institutions and how these have taken shape to have this effect on organizations and people. Reference DiMaggio and ZuckerDiMaggio (1988) came up with the notion of institutional entrepreneurship. He suggested that institutions ‘arise when organized actors with sufficient resources (institutional entrepreneurs) see in them an opportunity to realize an interest that they value highly’ (14). He expects that this will involve a highly politicized process because anyone who has an interest in preserving the existing institutionalized arrangements will put up a fight. There have been many case studies of institutional change that indeed report on there being a struggle. Furthermore, a large proportion of these case studies identify a particular actor as the institutional entrepreneur. Some of these case studies even provide indications as to what it takes to be a successful institutional entrepreneur. This would fill the void left by New Institutionalism as to how to understand the strategic agency by which organizations can create institutionalized arrangements that are amenable to them, and possibly what a strategist can do to make this happen.

In these case studies of institutional change and institutional entrepreneurship, the emphasis on what an institution is, moves away somewhat from the norms, values, and ideas that prescribe what activities are legitimate towards the activities themselves as these happen to be legitimized by norms, values, and ideas. Activities that have been investigated and found to be institutionalized – that is to have become taken-for-granted, regular and customary ways of doing things as a consequence of a process of institutional change – include the different ways in which firms made money in the US radio broadcasting industry (Reference Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and KingLeblebici et al., 1991), mandated sales in Norwegian fisheries (Reference HolmHolm, 1995), caesarean births in US hospitals (Reference Goodrick and SalancikGoodrick & Salancik, 1996), nineteenth-century thrift plans in the USA (Reference Haveman and RaoHaveman & Rao, 1997), environmentalism in the US chemical industry (Reference HoffmanHoffman, 1999, Reference Hargadon and Douglas2001), forensic accounting in Canada (Reference LawrenceLawrence, 1999), electric lighting replacing gas lighting (Reference Hargadon and DouglasHargadon & Douglas, 2001), recycling by US universities (Reference LounsburyLounsbury, 2001), the Java programming language (Reference Garud, Jain and KumaraswamyGarud et al., 2002), the multidisciplinary practice among accountancy firms in Canada (Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Greenwood, Suddaby and HiningsGreenwood et al., 2002), whale watching as a business (Reference Lawrence and PhillipsLawrence & Phillips, 2004), HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in Canada (Reference Maguire, Hardy and LawrenceMaguire et al., 2004), product categorization and diversification in the American mutual fund industry (Reference Lounsbury and LeblebiciLounsbury & Leblebici, 2004; Reference Lounsbury and RaoLounsbury & Rao, 2004), the popularization of photography by Kodak (Reference Munir and PhillipsMunir & Phillips, 2005), the digitization of photography (Reference MunirMunir, 2005), nurse practitioners in Alberta (Reference Reay, Golden-Biddle and GermannReay et al., 2006), the Indian modern art market (Reference Khaire and WadhwaniKhaire & Wadhwani, 2010), and sharing economy platforms in China (Reference Li and SchoenherrLi & Schoenherr, 2023). This is not an exclusive list but gives a flavour of the wide range of activities that can be thought of as being subjected to institutionalization. These activities having been institutionalized not only means that these are done in a particular way, but also that these are done at all. The examples all involve organizations whose existence and success depends on how they deal with their respective institutionalized arrangements, if not having had a hand in how the institutionalized arrangement took shape.

The locus of where the institutionalization and institutional change happens in these case studies is the organizational field, made up of those organizations and actors who regularly interact with each other (Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio & Powell, 1983). However, Reference HoffmanHoffman (1999) proposed and worked with an alternative field definition based on organizations and actors having an interest in a particular issue. As a consequence, issue field and exchange field became alternative conceptualizations of the organizational field (Reference Zietsma, Groenewegen, Logue and HiningsZietsma et al., 2017).

To be able to explain institutional change as being the consequence of institutional entrepreneurship, researchers had to deal with what Reference Seo and CreedSeo and Creed (2002) dubbed as the ‘paradox of embedded agency’. This paradox became the dominant issue in research on institutional change and a persistent conceptual problem for institutional theory (Reference Barley and TolbertBarley & Tolbert, 1997; Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al., 2009; Reference BeckertBeckert, 1999; Reference DoradoDorado, 2005; Reference FligsteinFligstein, 1997; Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008; Reference Haveman and RaoHaveman & Rao, 1997; Reference HoffmanHoffman, 1999; Reference HolmHolm, 1995; Reference Kondra and HiningsKondra & Hinings, 1998; Reference Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and KingLeblebici et al., 1991; Reference Munir and PhillipsMunir & Phillips, 2005; Reference Smets, Morris and GreenwoodSmets et al., 2012; Reference SminiaSminia, 2011). If we accept that people’s ability to act and their activities are a consequence of institutionalized arrangements that are external to them, how then can we account for the strategic agency required to put these institutionalized arrangements in place or change them? The cases studies on institutional entrepreneurship and institutional change came up with four solutions.

Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al. (2009), Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood and Suddaby (2006), Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy and Maguire (2008), Reference Haveman and RaoHaveman and Rao (1997), Reference HolmHolm (1995), Reference Lawrence and PhillipsLawrence and Phillips (2004), Reference Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and KingLeblebici et al. (1991), and Reference Seo and CreedSeo and Creed (2002) develop the ‘imperfect institutionalization’ argument as a first solution to bring agency back in. They claim that the institutionalized arrangements always will have inconsistencies and contradictions within them, with the pockets of ambiguity providing opportunities for institutional entrepreneurship to manifest itself. Some contend that these ambiguities appear within the institutionalized arrangements that characterize an organizational field. Others claim these ambiguities appear because of differences between the organizational field and larger institutionalized spheres like professions, communities, or society at large. Reference HolmHolm (1995) conceptualizes the multitude of spheres as a nested system, with a larger system bearing down on a system nested within it. A smaller system might see a push for change when it runs into practical difficulties when simultaneously abiding by the institutionalized pressures from the larger system and the institutionalized requirements posed by the smaller system. Overall, strategic agency that allows for institutional entrepreneurship is brought in by assuming that contradictions within the institutionalized arrangements offer opportunities for change.

Reference BeckertBeckert (1999), Reference Goodrick and SalancikGoodrick and Salancik (1996), and Reference Kondra and HiningsKondra and Hinings (1998) came up with a second solution by presuming that people have leeway when confronted with institutionalized expectations. The norms, values, and ideas are taken as just providing guidance. People are assumed to have discretion to abide by them or not. This is effectively an argument that splits up agency and institutions and puts them into two different realms, with agency always having the upper hand. It devalues if not dismisses any explanatory power that institution might have as its effect is essentially mediated by agency and people pursuing their interests. The argument chimes with Reference OliverOliver (1991) and those in Non-Market Strategy (e.g. Reference BaronBaron, 1995a) and IB/S (e.g. Reference PengPeng, 2003) who separate out the market or resource environment from the institutional environment. The strategic agency that allows for institutional entrepreneurship is brought in by presuming that people act on their own interests despite the presence of institutionalized arrangements.

Reference Barley and TolbertBarley and Tolbert (1997) and Reference Lawrence and PhillipsLawrence and Phillips (2004) separate agency and institution out in time as a third solution. For this, they draw on a particular interpretation of structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984). Giddens distinguishes between agency as a capability to act and social structure as rules and resources that enable and constrain actions. Both agency and structure are mutually implicated, as the activity that comes forth from agency reproduces or challenges the rules and resources while this activity is simultaneously facilitated by structure. This mutual implicating of agency and structure is referred to as ‘structuration’. Reference Barley and TolbertBarley and Tolbert (1997) suggest equating Giddens’ social structure with institution to propose separating the enabling and constraining of agency by structure and the challenging and reproducing of structure by activity as happening sequentially in a kind of seesaw fashion. In this way, strategic agency that allows for institutional entrepreneurship is presumed to appear as events that are separated out in time from events during which institutions have their constraining and enabling effect.

As a fourth solution, Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al. (2009), Reference Greenwood, Suddaby and HiningsGreenwood et al. (2002), Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy and Maguire (2008), Reference HoffmanHoffman (1999, Reference Hoffman2001), and Reference LawrenceLawrence (1999) argue that exogenous shocks or jolts are the prime reason why institutional entrepreneurship occurs. Such incidents originate from outside the organizational field. These are claimed to have the effect of upsetting the existing institutionalized arrangements in such a way that the strategic agency of institutional entrepreneurship is required to restore order, or the upset is seized upon by people who want change.

The institutional change that happens because of institutional entrepreneurship is presented as episodic (Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al., 2009; Reference Greenwood, Suddaby and HiningsGreenwood et al., 2002; Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008). Periods of ordered activity is interspersed with periods of change during which a new and different institutionalized arrangement develops. Further specifications of how such a change process takes shape distinguishes between initial conditions and the activities that an institutional entrepreneur must engage in to effectuate change. There are also indications of what attributes an institutional entrepreneur must have to be able to act as an effective change agent.

The two arguments for strategic agency of exogenous shocks and imperfect institutionalization also appear as conditions for institutional entrepreneurship to occur (Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al., 2009). Imperfect institutionalization is elaborated either as the degree of institutionalization with lesser institutionalized organizational fields providing more opportunity for change initiatives (Reference BeckertBeckert, 1999; Reference Goodrick and SalancikGoodrick & Salancik, 1996; Reference Kondra and HiningsKondra & Hinings, 1998) or as latent contradictions that are ready to be exploited (Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Seo and CreedSeo & Creed, 2002). Exogenous shocks or jolts can create practical problems which in turn are opportunities for change (Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008; Reference HolmHolm, 1995).

As Reference DiMaggio and ZuckerDiMaggio (1988) already predicted, the process by which institutional entrepreneurship plays out is highly political with proponents of change clashing with those who want to preserve the existing institutionalized arrangements (Reference BeckertBeckert, 1999; Reference FligsteinFligstein, 1997, Reference Fligstein2001; Reference Garud, Jain and KumaraswamyGarud et al., 2002; Reference HoffmanHoffman, 1999, Reference Hoffman2001; Reference HolmHolm, 1995). The actual process is maybe best described as a war of words and as highly discursive in making contrastive claims about what is right and what is wrong; what is legitimate and what is not legitimate (Reference FligsteinFligstein, 1997, Reference Fligstein2001; Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008; Reference Leblebici, Salancik, Copay and KingLeblebici et al., 1991; Reference Maguire, Hardy and LawrenceMaguire et al., 2004; Reference Munir and PhillipsMunir & Phillips, 2005; Reference Reay, Golden-Biddle and GermannReay et al., 2006). Ideas and interpretations define what interests people have, while interests tell them what ideas and interpretations to favour (Reference HolmHolm, 1995). Reference Greenwood, Suddaby and HiningsGreenwood et al. (2002: 75) introduced the notion of ‘theorization’ – ‘the rendering of ideas into understandable and compelling formats’ – as being key for how the institutionalized arrangements will take shape anew (also see Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Maguire, Hardy and LawrenceMaguire et al., 2004; Reference MunirMunir, 2005; Reference Suddaby and GreenwoodSuddaby & Greenwood, 2005). However, the process is seen as essentially indeterministic in that it is not clear from the outset whether a change initiative will succeed and what shape the institutionalized arrangements will be in when things have settled down again (Reference Lawrence and PhillipsLawrence & Phillips, 2004). The activities that institutional entrepreneurs engage in include resource mobilization, providing rationales in favour of and against change, and developing relations and coalitions by making people understand that their interests are aligned (Reference Battilana, Leca and BoxenbaumBattilana et al., 2009; Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008). Those who oppose the change initiative do the same.

An institutional entrepreneur as an actor has been endowed with various attributes. As a person, they are expected to have reflexivity (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984) in being able to recognize issues with existing institutionalized arrangements and to be visionaries by being able to sketch out new and better arrangements (Reference BeckertBeckert, 1999; Reference Garud, Jain and KumaraswamyGarud et al., 2002; Reference MutchMutch, 2007). The latter is reminiscent of Reference SelznickSelznick’s (1957) leadership in Old Institutionalism. Reference FligsteinFligstein (1997: 398) reckons that an institutional entrepreneur must be an operator with the ‘social skill’ ‘to motivate cooperation in other actors by providing those actors with common meanings and identities in which actions can be undertaken and justified’. Drawing on Reference LukesLukes (1974), he provides a range of power play tactics that can be utilized (Reference FligsteinFligstein, 1997, Reference Fligstein2001).

Part of the attributes of an institutional entrepreneur is also their position in the organizational field. Their subject position – ‘a socially constructed and legitimated identity available to actors in the field’ (also see Reference Hardy, Maguire, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyHardy & Maguire, 2008; Reference Maguire, Hardy and LawrenceMaguire et al., 2004: 658) – can make a person more or less suitable to advocate change. Ironically, being able to become an institutional entrepreneur depends on the existing institutionalized arrangements. Often, the institutional entrepreneur is taken to be a person. However, institutional entrepreneurship has also been associated with an organization or seen as a collective endeavour (Reference Wijen and AnsariWijen & Ansari, 2007). Regarding an organization’s position in the organizational field, to some it is being located at the fringes (Reference HolmHolm, 1995; Reference Luo, Chen and ChenLuo et al., 2021), to others it is being the leader in the field (Reference Greenwood and SuddabyGreenwood & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Greenwood, Suddaby and HiningsGreenwood et al., 2002; Reference LawrenceLawrence, 1999), which makes somebody best suited to be an institutional entrepreneur.

While developing and understanding institutional entrepreneurship, researchers moved away from social construction (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966) for the underlying process principles, mostly in favour of structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984), with Reference BourdieuBourdieu (1977, Reference Bourdieu1990) and (Reference SewellSewell, 1992) occasionally referred to as structuration-like alternatives. Structuration theory has a more developed conceptualization of agency than social construction. As was explained earlier, agency as an ability to act and exercise choice is mutually implicated with social structure or the institutionalized arrangements. Giddens labels this as ‘the duality of structure’. Social structure is drawn upon when activity occurs, as it enables and constrains agency, and is simultaneously reproduced or challenged, as activity is happening. Instead of an institution being understood as a social construction and as bearing down on people and organizations as in New Institutionalism, in trying to get to grips with institutional entrepreneurship and change, the focus is now on institutionalization being understood and elaborated as a process of structuration within which agency has a presence, albeit enabled and constrained by structure. Furthermore, structuration and therefore institutional entrepreneurship are animated by reflexivity. Reflexivity refers to ‘the monitored character of the ongoing flow of social life’ (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984: 3). To Giddens, it is more than a cognitive ability of an individual human actor to rationalize but also to question what is going on because reflexivity also plays out socially, implicating rules, resources, and other actors as activity happens. Nevertheless, it makes that a purposeful actor can always decide to act differently.

The notion of legitimacy has been expanded to also include pragmatic legitimacy (Reference SuchmanSuchman, 1995). New Institutionalism already had normative or moral legitimacy which is about whether activity is allowed, and cognitive legitimacy which is about the definition of the situation and what is the right interpretation. Pragmatic legitimacy is about resource allocation and what people get out of the activity. If normative/moral and cognitive legitimacy references the normative and discursive rules in Reference GiddensGiddens’ (1984) social structure, pragmatic legitimacy is about resources. Similarly, any activity can be found to communicate cognitive legitimacy, sanction normative or moral legitimacy, and exercise power by using and allocating resources.

Institutionalization is the process by which institutions come about. The notion of institutional entrepreneurship was coined and developed to account for the strategic agency by which people and organizations can have a hand in how the institutionalized arrangements take shape. The individual strategist then becomes an institutional entrepreneur and a challenger of existing institutions (see Figure 6). With it, the organizational strategy process is always politically charged. If there is a formal strategic planning process in place, this is one of the many opportunities to negotiate. The strategist therefore must be understood as being a political animal, pursuing interests by negotiating about meaning, norms and values, rules, and resources.

Figure 6 Institutional entrepreneurship strategizing.

The organizational survival process is about how to change institutionalized arrangements in the organizational field for the benefit the organization. Or if these arrangements happen to be beneficial already, how to prevent them from being altered. Such contestation can see high levels of ambiguity as the process plays out. The change process also is taken as largely indeterministic in that outcomes are not clear from the onset. How things eventually settle down only becomes clear in the course of time. Over time, strategists are expected to see episodes of institutional change alternated with periods of institutional stability. However, to theoretically accommodate strategic choice, a solution to the paradox of embedded agency had to be found. Four have been proposed: leeway, imperfect institutionalization, separation of agency and structure in time, and exogenous shock.

The indeterministic nature of the process puts an additional spin on the possibility of strategic choice. The strategic agency that makes institutional entrepreneurship only refers to the possibility of initiative. Despite an entrepreneur’s best efforts and maybe having all the required characteristics, there is no guarantee of success. Consequently, in periods of change and ambiguity, strategy is about ploys at best (Reference MintzbergMintzberg, 1987). It is about attempts to outmanoeuvre the opposition about what should be considered as cognitively, normatively, and pragmatically legitimate without knowing in advance whether the ploy will work. Possibly only in periods of relative stability, strategic planning and execution could work because it is reasonable to expect that the institutional continuity can be relied upon to sketch out what the future will look like, to then act accordingly, albeit always having the threat of an institutional entrepreneur upsetting things.

6 Intra-organizational Institutionalization: Convergent Incremental and Radical Strategic Change

The notion of isomorphism in New Institutionalism suggests that organizations adapt to institutionalized arrangements that exist in the organizational field and beyond to remain legitimate. Institutional change and entrepreneurship are about going against these institutionalized arrangements and are mostly problematized and investigated as happening at field level. You would expect that organizations participating in institutional entrepreneurship and change would have to organize themselves accordingly and maybe have to change themselves to be part of field-level change. Reference ScottScott (2014) describes organizations and organizational sub-units as levels below the field where institutionalized arrangements and therefore institutionalization also appear. However, how to understand intra-organizational institutionalization has received relatively little attention (Reference Smets, Morris and GreenwoodSmets et al., 2012). This is apart from Old Institutionalism where Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) supposes that all organizations that have become institutions as he defines them – that is only those organizations that have become ‘infused with value’ – display decision-making processes that are predominantly political in nature when these decisions are about which values to pursue.

To get to grips with institutionalization inside organizations, Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1996) propose to combine New Institutionalism with Old Institutionalism. They arrived at this proposition in a somewhat roundabout way by questioning the concept of ‘organizational structure’ as it was used in contingency theory (Reference Ranson, Hinings and GreenwoodRanson et al., 1980) to end up developing the concept of ‘design archetype’ and arrive at a theory of strategic change (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1988, Reference Greenwood and Hinings1993; Reference Hinings and GreenwoodHinings & Greenwood, 1988a, Reference Hinings, Greenwood and Zucker1988b). In doing so, they abandoned Reference SelznickSelznick’s (1957) distinction between organizations as bureaucracies and organizations as institutions by taking every organization as having been institutionalized.

Reference Ranson, Hinings and GreenwoodRanson et al. (1980) open a discussion whether to understand ‘organization structure’ as it was conceptualized within contingency theory (Reference BlauBlau, 1974; Reference WoodwardWoodward, 1965) as referring to formal structure. They argue that an organization’s structure should be understood as centred on an organizations ‘interpretative scheme’. ‘Organizational structures are shaped and constituted by members’ provinces of meaning, by their deep-seated interpretive schemes, and by the surface articulation of values and interests’ (Reference Ranson, Hinings and GreenwoodRanson et al., 1980: 5). They contend that the concept of organization structure should be based on how actually people engage with each other in organizations. The resulting interaction structure is informed by how people understand their organization and their own activities within it; not on how it is designed to function. Part of their argument to emphasize the interpretative scheme for understanding organization structure is the New Institutionalism thesis that organizational-level interpretative schemes are derived from field-level institutionalized expectations (Reference Meyer and RowanMeyer & Rowan, 1977).

Subsequently, Reference Hinings and GreenwoodHinings and Greenwood (1988a, Reference Hinings, Greenwood and Zucker1988b) and Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1988, Reference Greenwood and Hinings1993) move away from contingency theory into a more configurational approach (Reference Miles and SnowMiles & Snow, 1978; Reference Miller and FriesenMiller & Friesen, 1984; Reference MintzbergMintzberg, 1979). Organization, environment, and strategy process characteristics are taken to appear in distinctive packages or configurations, yet all underpinned by a specific interpretative scheme that provides meaning. They propose the concept of ‘design archetype’ to recognize that ‘organizations operate with a limited number of configurations of structure, strategy and environment’ (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1988: 294). ‘The structural elements and organizational processes making up the design type are strongly underpinned by provinces of meaning and interpretive schemes which bind them together in an institutionally derived normative order’ (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1988: 295; citing Reference Hinings, Greenwood and ZuckerHinings & Greenwood, 1988b: 54). To bolster their argument, they refer to various strategic change case studies that also point at the role of meaning and interpretation in the process (Reference Child and SmithChild & Smith, 1987; Reference JohnsonJohnson, 1987; Reference PettigrewPettigrew, 1985; Reference Whipp and ClarkWhipp & Clark, 1986).

Taking distinct design archetypes as the point of departure, Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1988) hypothesize that strategic change within an organization is a movement between different archetypes and that such a transformation involves the people inside the organization changing their interpretative scheme. Furthermore, they hypothesize that these movements between archetypes will appear as four different identifiable tracks. These tracks are ‘inertia’ where an organization sticks to a specific archetype, ‘abortion’ where an organization attempts to move from one archetype to another but abandons it and moves back, ‘reorientation’ or ‘transformation’ where an organization successfully moves between archetypes, and ‘unresolved excursion’ where an organization ends up being stuck halfway.

Testing this they found that English Local Authorities feature two archetypes (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1993; Reference Hinings and GreenwoodHinings & Greenwood, 1988a).

The heteronomous professional bureaucracy archetype conceives organizations as administrative vehicles for the delivery of essentially services [ … ]. In this conception, the range of a municipal government’s responsibilities is a consequence of historical accident rather than of policy intent, and the domain of the local authority is the sum of its responsibilities, each treated as a separate activity. The corporate bureaucracy archetype, in contrast, emphasizes the organization as an instrument of community governance. [ … ] The role of the organization is not administrative, implementing legally prescribed services, but governmental, combining packages of services and interventions in a strategic fashion.

They also found that many authorities operate in a way that comes close to either template but that some are incoherent in that they display characteristics of both. Additionally, they report that observing these local authorities over time indicates that each of the four tracks of inertia, abortion, transformation, and unresolved reorientation are discernible. These patterns are also found with Canadian sports organizations, albeit with archetypes specific to this field (Reference Kikulis, Slack and HiningsKikulis et al., 1992, Reference Kikulis, Slack and Hinings1995).

This process conceptualization of combining archetypes with change tracks or trajectories is presented as bringing New Institutionalism to bear upon the institutionalization happening inside organizations (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1996). Going into the detail of what happens between the people inside organizations as these organizations move along one of these change tracks, they go back to Old Institutionalism and Selznick’s reporting of political behaviour in decision-making. Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1996) propose a framework that combines exogenous factors (‘market, context, institutional context) with endogenous dynamics (‘interests, values, power dependencies, and capacity for action’). More specifically, they presume there are different ‘interests’ and ‘value commitments’ in an organization (cf. Reference SelznickSelznick, 1957). Dissatisfaction with whether interests are catered for inspires attempts at change and the amount of dissatisfaction indicates a pressure for change. There are also differences in value commitments in terms of both how committed people are and how many different value commitments are present, which point at whether there will be change.

Furthermore, power dependencies and the capability for action facilitate or impede change. Power dependencies are described as ‘The relations of power and domination that enable some organizational members to constitute and recreate organizational structures according to their preferences thus becomes a critical point of focus’ (Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood & Hinings, 1996: 1038). Capability for action is described as ‘having sufficient understanding of the new conceptual destination, its having the skills and competencies required to function in that new destination, and its having the ability to manage how to get to that destination’ (1040).

Similar frameworks are developed by Reference NewmanNewman (2000), Reference HoffmanHoffman (2001), and Reference Delmas and ToffelDelmas and Toffel (2008), also referencing Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) for the inherent political nature of intra-organizational institutionalization. Reference HoffmanHoffman (2001) and Reference Delmas and ToffelDelmas and Toffel (2008) are interesting because they link the different interests and value expectations to the different functions within an organization and the associated departments. Reference ZilberZilber (2002) links the political nature of intra-organizational institutionalization to rival interpretative schemes that are local adaptations of wider held beliefs. Additionally, Reference Kondra and HurstKondra and Hurst (2009) suggest that the isomorphism mechanisms of coercion, mimicry, and norms (Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio & Powell, 1983) operate within an organization just as much as on it. Reference Battilana and CasciaroBattilana and Casciaro (2012) concentrate on the individual change agent and find that this person’s network in the organization is linked with the likelihood this agent will initiate change, yet that this same network will also affect whether the initiative will be successful, depending on how much the initiative diverges from the institutionalized arrangements.

Most of this research on the politics of intra-organizational institutionalization – with the exception of Reference ZilberZilber (2002) – is what Reference Van de VenVan de Ven (1992) would describe as aprocessual variance theorizing. It treats process as a set of variables among others to hypothesize causal relationships between them, resulting in nothing more but comparative statics (Reference PettigrewPettigrew, 1997). This kind of research theorises and on occasion tests what circumstances inside and outside the organization increase the likelihood of change happening. There is little about how this change plays out. However, the strategic change case studies that were referenced (Reference Child and SmithChild & Smith, 1987; Reference JohnsonJohnson, 1987; Reference PettigrewPettigrew, 1985; Reference Whipp and ClarkWhipp & Clark, 1986) as well as others (Reference Grinyer, Mayes and McKiernanGrinyer et al., 1988; Reference QuinnQuinn, 1980; Reference SminiaSminia, 2005; Reference ZilberZilber, 2002) are of a more processual nature in that these look at what is happening over time.

Reference QuinnQuinn (1980) and Reference JohnsonJohnson (1987) find that change is realized incrementally as a sequence of compromises as and when problems occur. Like Reference HoffmanHoffman (2001) and Reference Delmas and ToffelDelmas and Toffel (2008), Reference QuinnQuinn (1980) links the existence of conflicting interests with the different functions and sub-units in an organization, a point also made by Reference Prahalad and BettisPrahalad and Bettis (1986) for the different businesses in diversified firms. Reference JohnsonJohnson (1987) refers to this as ‘problem solving according to the paradigm’, where the notion of paradigm refers to a shared interpretative scheme, ‘dominant logic’ (Reference Prahalad and BettisPrahalad & Bettis, 1986) or ‘strategic recipe’ (Reference Child and SmithChild & Smith, 1987). They claim that problems are appreciated, and solutions developed through the lens of an interpretative scheme that is typical and possibly unique to an organization. Consequently, change develops incrementally while simultaneously confirming the plausibility of this interpretative scheme, especially when solutions appear to work.

Some managers are found to have caught on to this ‘problem solving according to the paradigm’ in that they deliberately play a game of confirming the interpretative scheme or undermining it to further their interests. Reference PettigrewPettigrew (1985) labels this as ‘politics as the management of meaning’: ‘The content of strategic change is thus ultimately a product of a legitimisation process shaped by political/cultural considerations, though often expressed in rational/analytical terms’ (443). Those who comprehend the organization as being understood in terms of an interpretative scheme use opportunities inherent in this understanding to alter the interpretative scheme to favour their interests. Managers who recognize the interpretative scheme for what it is and what it does, and the process by which it takes shape, are the ones who tend to get the decision made in the way they want. Problems that confound the interpretative scheme and cause ambiguity are prime opportunities to challenge it (Reference JohnsonJohnson, 1987). The strategy process as a process of institutionalization is seen as layered in that it solves problems while simultaneously confirming or challenging and possibly changing the interpretative scheme (Reference SminiaSminia, 2005; Reference Sminia and de RondSminia & de Rond, 2012).

A later research stream under the Strategy-as-Practice banner, focusing more specifically on what strategists do (Reference Jarzabkowski, Balogun and SeidlJarzabkowski et al., 2007; Reference WhittingtonWhittington, 2006), also developed a conceptualization of the strategy process that plays out over the interpretative scheme (Reference Balogun and JohnsonBalogun & Johnson, 2005; Reference Maitlis and LawrenceMaitlis & Lawrence, 2003; Reference MantereMantere, 2008), with some going into the detail of the language game by which strategist play the politics of meaning game (e.g. Reference RouleauRouleau, 2005; Reference Samra-FredericksSamra-Fredericks, 2003; Reference Vaara, Kleymann and SeristöVaara et al., 2004). The distinction made by Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1996) between convergent change as an organization adapting to a design archetype and radical change as moving between archetypes resembles the distinction made by Reference JohnsonJohnson (1987) between incremental change and strategic change. With convergent or incremental change, the interpretative scheme of an organization remains intact. Radical or strategic change involves moving between interpretative schemes. Reference JohnsonJohnson (1987) reserves the adjective of strategic to indicate that it is about radical change that alters the organization’s paradigm. Reference Grinyer, Mayes and McKiernanGrinyer et al. (1988) even argue that strategic/radical change is an essential requirement for the turnaround of an ailing firm on the brink of bankruptcy.

By drawing on the strategic change literature and on Strategy-as-Practice, we end up with an understanding of institutionalization within organizations that is very similar to how institutional change and entrepreneurship at the level of the field is understood to take place. The process is seen as highly politicized and episodic in that periods of convergent incremental change are alternated with periods of radical strategic change (see Figure 7). We can refer to this as politics of meaning that makes use of the layered nature of the strategy process. The underlying process principles predominantly are derived from structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984). Reference Ranson, Hinings and GreenwoodRanson et al. (1980) explicitly refers to it while many of the strategic change case studies are underpinned by structuration theory as well (Reference PozzebonPozzebon, 2004; Reference SminiaSminia, 2009), as is the research stream in Strategy-as-Practice reported on here (Reference Whittington, Golsorkhi, Rouleau, Seidl and VaaraWhittington, 2015). There is some Strategy-as-Practice research in this realm that favoured Reference WeickWeick’s (1995) sensemaking, effectively concentrating on the rules part of the social structure at the expense of the resources part. Also similarly, intra-organizational institutionalization is indeterministic in that the outcome only becomes clear as the process plays out. And with it being based on structuration theory, the process is animated by reflexivity (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984). There is some further specification in that the process is understood to be layered. And we have a clear distinction between convergent incremental change and radical strategic change. The environmental survival process has seen less elaboration here, being mostly seen as presenting institutional change that the organization must follow or be liable to becoming obsolete and fail.

Figure 7 Intra-organizational institutional strategizing.

Nevertheless, one of the conceptual issues that appeared with New Institutionalism appears here as well. Like the question whether an institution is essentially a cognitive phenomenon or a social phenomenon that appeared with New Institutionalism, the issue here is whether an organizational-level interpretative scheme is cognitive or social. Those basing themselves on structuration theory like Reference Ranson, Hinings and GreenwoodRanson et al. (1980) and Reference PettigrewPettigrew (1985) see it as something social. Those basing themselves on sensemaking like Reference Balogun and JohnsonBalogun and Johnson (2005), as well as Reference JohnsonJohnson (1987) earlier, elaborate it as something cognitive. Furthermore, there is the question whether an interpretive scheme is unique to an organization as the strategic change case studies seem to imply, or whether there are only a limited number of interpretive schemes that are part of organizational archetypes that are configured within an organizational field as was put forward in Reference Greenwood and HiningsGreenwood and Hinings (1988) and Reference Hinings and GreenwoodHinings and Greenwood (1988a).

The possibility of strategic choice is similarly problematic as with institutional entrepreneurship. There is the possibility of initiative, but the essential indeterministic nature of radical strategic change makes that the outcome is never a certainty. During periods of convergent incremental change, strategic planning might work because such change better allows for extrapolation.

7 Institutional Logics: Dealing with Institutional Complexity

The concept of institutional logics originates from Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggioFriedland and Alford (1991). This is a chapter in the book edited by Reference Powell and DiMaggioPowell and DiMaggio (1991) that marks the start of the New Institutionalism variant of institutional theory. Ironically, Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggioFriedland and Alford (1991) are at odds with New Institutionalism in at least two ways. Firstly, instead of an institutional arrangement that compels an organization to be isomorphic to remain legitimate, to Friedland and Alford there are many institutional arrangements that together pose ‘a potentially contradictory interinstitutional system’ (240); turning the requirement to be legitimate into an impossible quest. Secondly, they presume institutional arrangements to be non-deterministic: ‘no institutional order should be accorded causal primacy a priori’ (240). Their argument goes against isomorphism and against a rather passive understanding of agency as conforming to institutional pressure. In effect, because of the contradictions, individual actors and organizations are presumed to be able to pick and choose which institutional arrangement they want to adhere too. It is this dealing with a range of different and often conflicting institutional logics that became the core issue that this variant of institutional theory concentrated on.

The definition of ‘institutional logics’ settled down with Reference Thornton, Ocasio, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyThornton and Ocasio (2008). They define it as ‘the socially constructed, historical patterns of material practices, assumptions, values, beliefs, and rules by which individuals produce and reproduce their material subsistence, organize time and space, and provide meaning to their social reality’ (101). As such, it is not that different from many other definitions that try to express what an institution is. Both elements of regularity in activity and legitimization by norms, values, and ideas are present. They do make a point of distinguishing between the material and the symbolic aspects of institutional logics. The symbolic refers to the meaning that an institution provides and is linked to the norms, values, and ideas that provide legitimacy. The material refers to the non-symbolic aspect, described as ‘market mechanisms [that] aggregate individual utilities and preferences, organizational competition, technology, and resource dependence’ (105). The material aspect resembles what Reference OliverOliver (1997a) referred to as the task environment while the symbolic aspect is similar to her institutional environment. While Oliver, Non-Market Strategy (e.g. Reference BaronBaron, 1995a), and IB/S (e.g. Reference PengPeng, 2003) separate out the symbolic and the material and treat these as two different domains, with Institutional Logics both are seen as institutionalized. ‘Key constructs in the analysis of organization, such as efficiency, rationality, participation, and values are not neutral, but are themselves shaped by the logics of the inter-institutional system’ (Reference Thornton, Ocasio, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyThornton & Ocasio, 2008: 104).

The use of ‘socially constructed’ does not mean that social construction theory is informing the process principals underpinning institutional logics. Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger and Luckmann (1966) are scarcely referenced. Structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984) is dismissed as well as not incorporating human cognition (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012). In developing the notion of institutional logics, Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggioFriedland and Alford (1991) explicitly argue against Methodological Individualism as being over-individualized and ignoring the social. Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al. (2012) develop a metatheory based on the institutional logics concept that they present as the Institutional Logics Perspective (ILP). They state their aim as offering ‘a metatheoretical framework for analyzing the interrelationships among institutions, individuals, and organizations in social systems’, and more specifically to provide an aid for answering ‘questions of how individual and organizational actors are influenced by their situation in multiple social locations in an interinstitutional system’ (2). In doing so, they – as do many authors who are identified as working with institutional logics – borrow from and combine various sociological and social psychological theoretical approaches to propose their own bespoke process principles.

Picking up on Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggioFriedland and Alford (1991), initial research utilizing institutional logics was very similar to research in institutional entrepreneurship and institutional change. These were mostly case studies of change in an institutional field, but now the change was conceptualized as moving from one institutional logic to another institutional logic. This includes Reference Thornton and OcasioThornton and Ocasio (1999) and Reference ThorntonThornton (2002), who describe a change of a ‘logic of professions’ to a ‘logic of markets’ in the higher education publishing industry in the USA. Reference GumpertGumpert (2000) analyses change in US public higher education as a moving from a logic of ‘higher education as a social institution’ to ‘higher education as an industry’. Reference LounsburyLounsbury (2001) and Reference Lounsbury, Ventresca and HirschLounsbury et al. (2003) describe the emergence of recycling as a new industry in waste management alongside disposal as the establishment of a new institutional logic next to an existing logic. Reference LounsburyLounsbury (2002, Reference Lounsbury2007) and Reference Lounsbury and LeblebiciLounsbury and Leblebici (2004) track changes with financial intermediaries and mutual funds in the field of finance as moving from a ‘regulatory logic’ to a ‘market logic’. Reference Rao, Monin and DurandRao et al. (2003) describe the emergence of nouvelle cuisine and it replacing classical cooking in French gastronomy as a new logic superseding an older one. Reference Zajac and WestphalZajac and Westphal (2004) link how stock markets react differently to stock repurchase plans with a change from a ‘corporate logic’ to an ‘agency logic’ among participants in financial markets. Changes in the Alberta healthcare system are associated with a change of dominant logic from ‘medical professionalism’ to ‘business-like health care’ (Reference Reay and HiningsReay & Hinings, 2005). Reference Thornton, Jones, Kury, Jones and ThorntonThornton et al. (2005) relate changes in accounting, publishing, and architecture to changes regarding their respective dominant logics.

Reference BhappuBhappu (2000) is an example who uses the concept of institutional logic in the singular to refer to the Japanese family as an explanation for how and why Japanese corporate networks or keiretsu exist. She in effect makes the same point as Reference WhitleyWhitley (1991) with his notion of business system. Reference MoormanMoorman (2002) does something similar when she proposes that consumer markets and how these operate are informed by an institutional logic specific to that market. Both these case studies of institutional change and the use of institutional logic in the singular offer little beyond similar studies based on respectively institutional change/entrepreneurship, New Institutionalism, or inter-organizational institutionalization. These just use the term of institutional logic and its definition to denote the institutional arrangements that appear in their studies. The change process itself is also understood in very similar terms as largely discursive and requiring skilful negotiation about meaning and what is to be considered as legitimate.

Nevertheless, there appears to be one interesting statement being made with these case studies in that economics, the notion of the market mechanism, and the expectation of efficiency are just another institutional logic among many, which might gain or lose dominance (Reference LounsburyLounsbury, 2008). The institutional logic of economics appears as a ‘logic of markets’ in educational publishing (Reference ThorntonThornton, 2002; Reference Thornton and OcasioThornton & Ocasio, 1999), a logic of ‘higher education as an industry’ (Reference GumpertGumpert, 2000), a ‘market logic’ with mutual funds (Reference LounsburyLounsbury, 2002, Reference Lounsbury2007; Reference Lounsbury and LeblebiciLounsbury & Leblebici, 2004), an ‘agency logic’ in corporate governance (Reference Zajac and WestphalZajac & Westphal, 2004) and also in Reference LokLok (2010), and as a ‘business-like health care’ logic (Reference Reay and HiningsReay & Hinings, 2005). On the one hand, taking economics as just another institutional logic is a thought-provoking turn in the argument. With institutional logics, there is just one environment that is conceptualized as an interinstitutional system. By implication, this means that competitiveness is just one of many logics that organizations must deal with. On the other hand, there is a bit of a conceptual discrepancy in that economics is seen as part of the material aspect of any institutional logic while norms, values, and ideas are the symbolic aspect (Reference Thornton, Ocasio, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyThornton & Ocasio, 2008; Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012). This implies that competitiveness appears as a material aspect of an institutional logic. The issue is whether each logic has economics as part of it or is economics a particular institutional logic of its own?

Another line of research concentrates on what is more typical of the institutional logics variant of institutional theory: the simultaneous existence of multiple logics that are contradictory and competing with each other. This is referred to as ‘institutional complexity’ (Reference Greenwood, Raynor, Kodelj, Micelotta and LounsburyGreenwood et al., 2011). It poses the question how organizations and individual actors deal with this. A range of answers has been proposed. Some suggest that a plurality of logics allows for organizations and actors to pick whatever suits them best (Reference BinderBinder, 2007; Reference Coule and PatmoreCoule & Patmore, 2013) to make it possible for organizations to tailor their rhetoric to the logic that somebody they have to deal with prefers (Reference Jones and Livne-TarandachJones & Livne-Tarandach, 2008). This is the leeway solution to the paradox of embedded agency (Reference Seo and CreedSeo & Creed, 2002), which was also present in institutional entrepreneurship.

Furthermore, institutional complexity is put forward as the explanation for heterogeneity, as different organizations reacting differently to the same set of institutional logics (Reference Greenwood, Raynor, Kodelj, Micelotta and LounsburyGreenwood et al., 2011; Reference LounsburyLounsbury, 2008; Reference Thornton, Ocasio, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyThornton & Ocasio, 2008). Heterogeneity is the opposite of the isomorphism of New Institutionalism (Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Others propose ways to understand how organizations manage the splits they have to perform to appear to comply with different institutional demands to remain legitimate in the eyes of the many institutional logics they are faced with (Reference Battilana and DoradoBattilana & Dorado, 2010; Reference Kraatz, Block, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyKraatz & Block, 2008; Reference LokLok, 2010; Reference Pache and SantosPache & Santos, 2010; Reference Reay and HiningsReay & Hinings, 2009).

Organizations have been observed utilizing various tactics that have subsequently been proposed as theoretical propositions of how multiple institutional logics are dealt with. Reference Kraatz, Block, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabyKraatz and Block (2008) offer organizations a choice between either siding with one logic and resisting other logics, compartmentalizing with different parts of the organization dealing with different logics, playing different logics against each other, or – by referring to Reference SelznickSelznick (1957) – becoming infused with value so that the organization has its own institutional logic by which it legitimizes itself. Reference LokLok (2010) looks at people inside organizations and finds three ways in which they identify with conflicting logics by either abducting parts of a conflicting logic into a favoured logic so that it looks like they are complying, by complying with different logics in parallel, or by resisting logics in favour of other logics. Reference Pache and SantosPache and Santos (2010) draw on Reference OliverOliver’s (1991) strategies of acquiescence, compromise, avoidance, defiance, and manipulation, but apply these to each institutional logic an organization has to contend with. Reference Reay and HiningsReay and Hinings (2009) found four forms of co-existence of institutional logics of separating decisions as pertaining to one logic or to another logic, of informally soliciting for opinions from one logic while adhering to the other logic, of finding another logic as a common foe, and of engaging in experimental arrangements that cater for more than one logic. Reference Battilana and DoradoBattilana and Dorado (2010: 1436) propose the concept of ‘hybrid’ organization: ‘in the absence of institutional scripts for handling logic plurality, a new type of hybrid needs to develop a common organizational identity that enables organization members to strike a balance between logics’. Reference Gümüsay, Smets and MorrisGümüsay et al. (2020b) denote this as ‘elastic hybridity’. The various forms of co-existence or hybridity are the fifth solution to the paradox of embedded agency (Reference Seo and CreedSeo & Creed, 2002). It resembles what Reference BrunssonBrunsson (2007) has labelled as ‘organized hypocrisy’.

Explaining how people and organizations deal with multiple institutional logics is at the heart of what is labelled as the Institutional Logics Perspective (ILP) (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012). This metatheory also proposes bespoke process principles for the institutional logics variant of institutional theory. It is meant to provide a framework for analysing how institutions, individuals, and organizations relate to each other so that researchers can develop explanations of how individuals and organizations are influenced by institutionalized arrangements.

Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al. (2012) sees the complex constellation of many institutional logics as a multi-level phenomenon. To them the macro-societal level is an interinstitutional system consisting of cornerstone institutions or institutional orders. Examples are family, religion, state, market, profession, and corporation, but others are possible as well. Reference Gümüsay, Claus and AmisGümüsay et al. (2020a), for instance, in discussing climate change, propose the natural environment as another cornerstone institution. Each of these cornerstone institutions consists of the same building blocks, yet these have taken shape differently for each institutional order. These nine building blocks are the root metaphor; the sources of legitimacy, authority, and identity; the basis of norms, attention, and strategy; the informal control mechanisms; and the economic system. In combination, these building blocks pose an institutional logic by ‘represent[ing] the cultural symbols and material practices particular to that order’ (54). This interinstitutional system at times is presented as just referring to the macro-societal level but also as a multilevel complex by itself, consisting of the different layers of society, field, industry, and organization, which together pose an intricate web of connected and contradictory institutional logics.

With macro referring to society, the meso level and the micro level – as often is the case – are organizations and individuals respectively. The relationship between the macro, the meso, and the micro is elaborated based on the notion of ‘microfoundations’ as derived from Reference ColemanColeman (1990) and developed by Reference Abell, Felin and FossAbell et al. (2008) and Reference Felin and FossFelin and Foss (2009) by placing individuals understood in cognitive psychological terms (the microfoundations) within social phenomena. Although the macro-societal level of the interinstitutional system has many institutional logics available, at the individual level each human actor accesses only those institutional logics that come to mind, to then inform their decision-making as to how to act in a particular situation; with the choices being made activating an apparently preferred institutional logic. The organization as an intermediate or meso level appears as a filter by way of ‘localized organizational practices’ (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012: 92) that affects which institutional logics are available to an individual for recognition. Human activity in organizations then is analysable as the cumulative effect of institutional logics, organizational practices, and boundedly rational decision-making of individual human actors while people deal with the concrete situations that appear.

Apart from this top-down effect of the macro level through the meso level influencing the micro level, the notion of microfoundations also incorporates a bottom-up effect from the micro through the meso to the macro. The argument here is that individual human activity generated by how they cognitively recognize situations is also social activity because it involves people anticipating other people in symbolic interaction (Reference MeadMead, 1934). Activity is social when individual activity becomes coordinated to generate collective effects. In a way, this deals with the ambivalence of an institution being essentially a cognitive phenomenon or essentially social, which appeared with New Institutionalism. According to Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al. (2012) coordination and collective effects appear through formal organizational decision-making (Reference Cyert and MarchCyert & March, 1963; Reference March and SimonMarch & Simon, 1958; Reference SimonSimon, 1947), through sensemaking (Reference WeickWeick, 1995; Reference Weick, Sutcliffe and ObstfeldWeick et al., 2005), and through mobilization (Reference McCarthy and ZaldMcCarthy & Zald, 1977). All three mechanisms feature communication and negotiation about ‘pragmatic concerns and social cues’ (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012: 95), creating a learning effect, as participants reflect on the efficacy of the social interactions. This then feeds back to the institutional logics either perpetuating or undermining them. The overall effect can be continuity or change.

Change is either deliberate or just emerging from everyday mundane activity (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012), and more of a consequence of distributed agency that happens to combine than the deliberate agency of an institutional entrepreneur. Therefore, deliberate institutional change is presented as cultural entrepreneurship (Reference Lounsbury and GlynnLounsbury & Glynn, 2001) to distinguish it from institutional entrepreneurship (Reference DiMaggio and ZuckerDiMaggio, 1988). Cultural entrepreneurship is elaborated as switching between institutional logics. It is proposed to be a process of ‘vertical specialization’ by moving and combining the content of building blocks across institutional orders and of ‘horizontal integration’ by putting building blocks together again to create a new institutional logic. It is presented as consisting of the three phases of recognizing and articulating a problem; theorizing, translating, and legitimatizing a solution; and mobilizing a community of solution advocates. It resembles institutional entrepreneurship very much in that it largely is seen as a discursive process of politics of meaning (cf. Reference PettigrewPettigrew, 1985) yet diverges from it with the assumption that it is essentially a process of deliberate problem-solving, albeit involving many people.

Change coming out of mundane day-to-day activity is modelled on the routine dynamics approach originating from Reference FeldmanFeldman (2003) and Reference Feldman and PentlandFeldman and Pentland (2003). In routine dynamics, daily activities evolve because people adapt what they do to the variability in circumstances that they encounter. Over time, this can create a trajectory of successive incremental adjustments. Referring to Reference Lounsbury and CrumleyLounsbury and Crumley (2007), Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al. (2012) develop this as a way to understand how ‘localized organizational practices’ develop and change, which by way of the feedback effects on the interinstitutional system can alter institutional logics.

As was written earlier, the institutional logics variant of institutional theory is not based on specific process principles like methodological individualism, social construction, or structuration theory. The writings eclectically draw on all of them while also rejecting them. There are many occasions where Reference GiddensGiddens (1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984) is referred to while structuration is dismissed because it is found lacking in taking human cognition into account (Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al., 2012). By centring the microfoundations of institutional logics on a human’s presumed ability to reflect and make decisions on what to do given the availability of various institutional logics and having to consider the situation at hand, Reference GiddensGiddens’ (1984) notion of reflexivity is somewhat present to animate the process yet understood as an individual-level cognitive faculty.

Social construction (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966) hardly gets a look in while other phenomenological approaches like symbolic interactionism (Reference MeadMead, 1934) and individual sensemaking (Reference WeickWeick, 1995) are incorporated in the microfoundations of institutional logics to provide a mechanism by which the micro level affects the meso and macro levels. Collective sensemaking is part of the organizational meso level. Despite the clear rejection of methodological individualism by Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggioFriedland and Alford (1991), it is present when institutional logics draws on behavioural theory for its elaboration of decision-making as boundedly rational (Reference Cyert and MarchCyert & March, 1963; Reference March and SimonMarch & Simon, 1958; Reference SimonSimon, 1947) and in how Reference Abell, Felin and FossAbell et al. (2008) and Reference Felin and FossFelin and Foss (2009) have developed the notion of microfoundations. There are even slight hints of actor-network theory (Reference LatourLatour, 2005) and Reference SchatzkiSchatzki’s (2002) theory of practice when Reference Lounsbury and CrumleyLounsbury and Crumley (2007) and Reference Thornton, Ocasio and LounsburyThornton et al. (2012) refer to routine dynamics (Reference FeldmanFeldman, 2003; Reference Feldman and PentlandFeldman & Pentland, 2003).

Recognizing the presence of multiple institutional logics, this variant of institutional theory mostly concentrates on how people and organizations are capable to deal with them (Reference Gümüsay, Claus and AmisGümüsay et al., 2020a). This by itself can be professed as a profound strategic problem, giving a whole new meaning to the notion of competition. Rather than firms competing with each other on the basis of their competitive advantage, organizations find their environmental survival process is about accommodating competing institutional logics to remain viable (see Figure 8). It is also interesting that economics is considered as just another logic. Instead of separating out competitiveness and legitimacy as was done in IB/S (e.g. Reference PengPeng, 2003), Non-Market Strategy (e.g. Reference BaronBaron, 1995a), and by Reference OliverOliver (1997a) in New Institutionalism, being competitive is about being legitimate in terms of an institutional logic informed by the principles of economics.

Figure 8 Institutional logics strategizing.

Strategic choice is present by way of the assumption that actors because of the contradictions are to be able to pick and choose which institutional logic they want to adhere too. However, the extent of strategic choice is qualified at the micro level by way of people only working with institutional logics that come to mind, and at the meso level by way of the localized organizational practices that happen to be present. Overall, institutionalization is the consequence of distributed agency.

8 Understanding Institutionalization: Institutional Work and Constant Becoming

The notion of institutional entrepreneurship tries to deal with the lack of strategic agency that was inherent in New Institutionalism and particularly in the isomorphism thesis. It turned institutionalization into an episodic process of institutional change interspersed with periods of stability happening mostly at the level of the organizational field. A similar sequencing was presented as happening within firms and organizations with convergent incremental change alternating with radical strategic change. The notion of institutional logics prompted a recognition of institutional complexity: a situation where people and organizations are confronted with multiple and often conflicting institutionalized arrangements. Institutional work as another variant of institutional theory initially picked up on institutional entrepreneurship, to not only concentrate on change but also on continuity; on how institutional arrangements change but also stay in place as a consequence of deliberate and purposeful activity (Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Lawrence, Leca and SuddabyLawrence et al., 2009;; Reference Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaLawrence et al., 2011). In short, institutional work is about institutionalization.

Scandinavian Institutionalism (Reference Boxenbaum, Pedersen, Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaBoxenbaum & Pedersen, 2009; Reference Sahlin, Wedlin, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabySahlin & Wedlin, 2008) as an alternative form of the institutional work approach resulted in a different and more performative understanding of institutionalization, with institutionalized arrangements seen as an accomplishment and the result of unceasing activity that generates an effect of continuity and change. Work by Smets and colleagues ended up in a similar position (Reference Smets and JarzabkowskiSmets & Jarzabkowski, 2013; Reference Smets, Morris and GreenwoodSmets et al., 2012; Reference Smets, Jarzabkowski, Burke and SpeeSmets et al., 2015b; Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and MeyerSmets et al., 2017). What they labelled as practice-driven institutionalism sees institutions continuously being recreated as practices are being enacted, especially because they recognize the presence of multiple institutional logics. The performative variant of institutional work turns institutionalization into a continuous ‘becoming’ with institutions appearing ‘as momentary effects of and for action’ (Reference Bjerregaard and JonassonBjerregaard & Jonasson, 2014: 1510).

‘Becoming’ contrast with ‘being’ as referring to fundamentally different views on the nature of reality. ‘Being’ captures a substantialist ontology with reality understood as consisting of entities to which change happens. This is very much present in all other institutional theory variants. ‘Becoming’ offers an alternative ontology where everything is seen as coming into existence because of an underlying process. What we experience as entities is the consequence of a process generating something that appears to have some persistence over time.

On introducing the concept of ‘institutional work’ Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006: 215) define it as the ‘the purposive action of individuals and organizations aimed at creating, maintaining, and disrupting institutions’. Their answer to the paradox of embedded agency (Reference Seo and CreedSeo & Creed, 2002) is a variant of the leeway solution. They endow an individual person with reflexivity (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1984) and therefore as being capable of dealing in a deliberate manner with the expectations that institutionalized arrangements in the field bring to a situation. This then allows for people being able to consider disrupting and recreating but also to decide to maintain an institution. By labelling it as ‘work’, they want to emphasize that institutionalization takes effort.

Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006) distinguish between six activity typesFootnote 3 by which an institution is maintained, and continuity generated. The ‘enabling’, ‘policing’, and ‘deterring’ activity types ensure that there is adherence to the institutionalized arrangements. The activity types of ‘valorizing/demonizing’, ‘mythologizing’, and ‘embedding and routinizing’ make that institutional arrangements are reproduced. Institutional change happens by way of disrupting existing arrangements and creating new ones. Creation requires political activity types like ‘vesting’, ‘defining’, and ‘advocacy’. Such political activity reconstructs rules, property rights, and boundaries that regulate access to resources. There are reconstruction activity types like ‘constructing identities’, ‘changing norms’, and ‘constructing networks’ that recreate the belief system. Furthermore, there are boundary activity types that recreate abstract categorizations and regulate the boundaries of meaning systems. These activity types are ‘mimicry’, ‘theorizing’, and ‘educating’. Institutional work aimed at disrupting an institution in effect attacks or undermines compliance. The activity types associated with disruption are ‘disconnecting sanctions/rewards’, ‘disassociating moral foundations’, and ‘undermining assumptions and beliefs’.

The disruption and creation activity types are very reminiscent of how the process of institutional change was understood with institutional entrepreneurship. The maintenance activities that are responsible for institutional continuity is what the institutional work variant adds to institutional theory. It also turns institutionalization into more of an ongoing process with all the activity types being present, albeit not always to the same degree. As with institutional entrepreneurship, there have been many case studies, although mostly concentrating on the disruption and creation side of institutional work and less on the maintenance aspect (Reference Lawrence, Leca and ZilberLawrence et al., 2013). These include studies of the institutional work done for establishing management fashions and fads (Reference Perkmann and SpicerPerkmann & Spicer, 2008), authority at San Francisco State College (Reference RojasRojas, 2010), logging in British Columbia (Reference Zietsma and LawrenceZietsma & Lawrence, 2010), cholesterol-lowering foods (Reference Ritvala and KleymannRitvala & Kleymann, 2012), the corporatization of law firms in the city of London (Reference Empson, Cleaver and AllenEmpson et al., 2013), and the personal computer/Intel/Microsoft platform (Reference Gawer and PhillipsGawer & Phillips, 2013). Examples of institutional work maintenance cases are about specialist doctors remaining dominant in the English National Health Service (Reference Currie, Lockett, Finn, Martin and WaringCurrie et al., 2012), a responsible investment index (Reference Slager, Gond and MoonSlager et al., 2012), and crew selection for the Oxford-Cambridge boat race (Reference Lok and de RondLok & de Rond, 2013).

Despite the variety of what is thought of as being institutionalized, as with institutional entrepreneurship the emphasis is on the patterned and regular activities rather than the norms, values, and ideas as being the crucial element of what constitutes an institution. How institutional work in terms of Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006) is understood is also very similar to how institutional change and entrepreneurship have been elaborated, and to how strategic change has been presented to happen within organizations. The process is seen mostly as discursive. The contestation plays out by making claims and counterclaims of what is cognitively, normatively, and pragmatically legitimate by way of providing descriptions and voicing interpretations. The process principles predominantly are derived from structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984) with institutionalization seen as structuration. However, in contrast to institutional entrepreneurship, the concept of institutional work covers both institutional change and institutional continuity. Moreover, the ‘work’ in institutional work signals that institutionalization is an ongoing process that continuously requires people to engage in maintenance, disruption, and re-creation activity. Furthermore, there is an acknowledgement that institutionalization and especially change initiatives are collective efforts rather than being attributable to a single institutional entrepreneur.

Mostly in parallel with Lawrence, Suddaby, and colleagues’ efforts, Scandinavian Institutionalism developed and was recognized as an alternative form of institutional work (Reference Boxenbaum, Pedersen, Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaBoxenbaum & Pedersen, 2009; Reference Sahlin, Wedlin, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabySahlin & Wedlin, 2008). This alternative to institutional work developed from New Institutionalism in that it started with isomorphism as a core construct for understanding institutionalization, yet provided a twist as to how this transpires. Doing so, it arrived at a different and more performative understanding of how institutionalization happens. Initially, the process principles of social construction (Reference Berger and LuckmannBerger & Luckmann, 1966) underpinning New Institutionalism made way for sensemaking (Reference WeickWeick, 1979, Reference Weick1995). Although both approaches have the same phenomenological roots, sensemaking concentrates on individual human actors as sensemakers and combines this with a requirement for people to have to make sense or understand what is going on for collective arrangements like organizations to function. Scandinavian Institutionalism took sensemaking into institutional theory to posit that people when confronted with institutional pressures have an ability to make sense of these pressures in different ways. Rather than expecting that institutionalized expectations turn almost inevitably into isomorphism as per Reference DiMaggio and PowellDiMaggio and Powell (1983), the possibility of making sense differently would account for variability. There was even the suggestion of a form of strategic agency with people being aware of different possible interpretations to deliberately pick one that suits their interests. This is an argument that resonates with institutional logics.

With Reference Czarniawska and SevónCzarniawska and Sevón (1996), Scandinavian Institutionalism orientated the process principles away from sensemaking. Instead, it started favouring actor-network theory and especially the notion of ‘translation’ (Reference Callon and LawCallon, 1986; Reference Callon, Latour, Knorr-Cetina and CicourelCallon & Latour, 1981; Reference Latour and LawLatour, 1986). Translation is applied here as an alternative to diffusion (Reference Boxenbaum, Pedersen, Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaBoxenbaum & Pedersen, 2009; Reference Brandtner, Powell and HorvathBrandtner, Powell, & Horvath, 2024; Reference Sahlin, Wedlin, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabySahlin & Wedlin, 2008; Reference ZilberZilber, 2006). The notion of diffusion assumes institutional pressures to be clear, unquestioned, and adhered to, and as such institutional requirements spread unaltered across the various organizations that are submitted to them. Translation sees adherence to institutional pressures as inherently problematic because these pressures are not necessarily clear and therefore require interpretation (as with sensemaking), but also adaptation, modification, and reshaping to accommodate and make them work within different organizations. Institutionalization as translation, therefore, is partly creative with the institutional expectations being re-imagined, to suit the situation, and is partly edited as elements of these expectations which are too problematic are discarded. This is regarded as institutional work because institutionalization as translation also requires effort. Moreover, there is intrinsic variability in how an institutionalized arrangement is made to bear upon an organization’s activities.

Institutionalization as translation is performative (Reference CallonCallon, 1998; Reference MacKenzie and MilloMacKenzie & Millo, 2003; Reference Sevón, Czarniawska and SevónSevón, 1996). The basic premise is that an institution is not an independently existing set of norms, values, and ideas with associated appropriate patterns of activity to which people and organizations submit, and which people can reflect on to purposefully maintain, disrupt, and re-create as per Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006). Instead, activities perform an institution. It is through activities that the effect of maintenance, adaptation, or disruption is generated. This means that institutionalized arrangements are always and continuously re-created as and when the patterned activities happen. In other words: institutions are always in a state of ‘becoming’ (Reference Tsoukas and ChiaTsoukas & Chia, 2003). The norms, values, and ideas aspect of an institution can be described as the ostensive part by providing the idealized principles that describe the institution, while the patterned activities are the performative part as an institution’s actual manifestation (Reference Latour and LawLatour, 1986; Reference Sevón, Czarniawska and SevónSevón, 1996).Footnote 4

A similar development regarding institutional work is found with Smets and colleagues (Reference Smets and JarzabkowskiSmets & Jarzabkowski, 2013; Reference Smets, Morris and GreenwoodSmets et al., 2012; Reference Smets, Jarzabkowski, Burke and SpeeSmets et al., 2015b; Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and MeyerSmets et al., 2017) who question the presupposition of purposefulness in Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby’s (2006) definition of institutional work. They argue that maintaining and changing institutionalized arrangements also can originate from people in organizations just going about doing their daily business of dealing with the day-to-day issues that they encounter. Adopting a practice-driven approach and drawing on Reference Schatzki, Schatzki, Knorr-Cetina and von SavignySchatzki’s (2001: 2) definition of a practice as ‘embodied, materially mediated arrays of human activity centrally organized around shared practical understanding’, practices are taken as norms and routines and differentiated from praxis as everyday performation, and from practitioners as the active embodiment of practices (Reference WhittingtonWhittington, 2006). The difference between practices and praxis echoes the distinction between the ostensive and performative aspects of an institution.

Smets and colleagues also argue that institutional complexity or the simultaneous presence of conflicting institutional logics (Reference Greenwood, Raynor, Kodelj, Micelotta and LounsburyGreenwood et al., 2011) is the normal state of affairs (see also Reference Bjerregaard and JonassonBjerregaard & Jonasson, 2014). Institutional logic is taken to refer to Reference SchatzkiSchatzki’s (2006) ‘general understanding’ or the overall justification why a practice is enacted there and then; an interpretation endorsed by Reference Schatzki, Lounsbury, Anderson and SpeeSchatzki (2021). Logics are instantiated in praxis as practices are enacted (cf. Reference ZilberZilber, 2024). Institutional change then originates with the mundane practicality and associated improvisations of having to accommodate conflicting logics or practical understandings when practices are enacted. The improvisations indicate what each institutional logic means for enacting a practice there and then, which then can spread across other subsequent practice enactments in the organization’s bundle.This is how Reference Smets, Morris and GreenwoodSmets et al. (2012) and Reference Smets and JarzabkowskiSmets and Jarzabkowski (2013) describe how lawyers marry the different demands of the legal profession in England and Germany when they established a bundle of blended practices that constitute a newly merged firm practicing international law. However, not every improvisation will result in institutional change of that magnitude. Reference SminiaSminia (2011) develops a very similar argument about collusion in the Dutch construction industry as a case of institutional continuity while its illegality poses a strong impetus for change. To Reference SminiaSminia (2011) and Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and MeyerSmets et al. (2017) the main driver for performing practices, for dealing with institutional complexity, and therefore for institutional continuity and change is the practicality of ‘getting the job done’. Emphasizing practicality as the main thrust for institutionalization moves the argument away from meaning (Reference Lounsbury, Anderson, Spee, Lounsbury, Anderson and SpeeLounsbury et al., 2021; Reference QuatroneQuatrone, 2015). Because this is a continuous effort, it fits the realm of institutional work.

Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro (2019) pick up on the performativity of institutional work by observing that Scandinavian Institutionalism mostly concentrated on the discursive aspect of translation of making an institutional arrangement meaningful in a particular context. They argue there is a political aspect to performativity as well. For them, the politics of translation consists of the movements of ‘problematization’, ‘interessement’, ‘enrolment’, and ‘mobilization’ (Reference Callon and LawCallon, 1986). Through problematization an institution takes shape as an ensemble of solutions that is presented as dealing with a range of problems and interests. This institution then presents an obligatory passage point for various actors as they become convinced of being stakeholders in this institution while they are pursuing their particular and often idiosyncratic interests. Interessement endows each stakeholder with an identity in terms of the institution. This identity tells them how they understand themselves and their interests in relation to this institution, what activities are expected from them, and how these activities contribute to meeting their interests. Enrolment happens when the stakeholders, having identified with their respective identities, act accordingly in pursuit of meeting the interests they have been associated with. Mobilization occurs when stakeholders identify and act in accordance with the institution to the extent that they become representable in terms of the institution. In this way, Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro (2019) turn institutional work into performative work. Institutional performative work denotes an understanding of institutionalization as translation and as an unceasing effort of problematization, interessement, enrolment, and representation.

Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro (2019) present institutional performative work as driven by a single actor or translator who carefully arranges for stakeholders to become problematized, interessemented, enrolled, and represented. In their empirical work, they concentrate on Charles (a pseudonym) who champions the development of a new product in a financial data company. Alternatively, Reference CzarniawskaCzarniawska (2009) presents institutional performative work as a collective endeavour with various actors – human and non-human – wittingly and unwittingly making contributions which happen to generate an institution. This is how she explains how the London School of Economics became established.

Both Scandinavian and Practice-driven Institutionalism suggest that institutions exist by way of the ongoing and never-ending institutional performative work or institutionalization that is taking place. Institutionalization then is about stabilization (Reference Reinecke and LawrenceReinecke & Lawrence, 2023) with institutional performative work generating the patterned activity by which it exists – the performative aspect – accompanied by descriptions in terms of norms, values, and ideas – the ostensive or discursive aspect – by which it is legitimized. The focal point of institutional performative work and therefore of how to understand how an institution exists, then, are the practices that are enacted and turned into praxis by practitioners (cf. Reference Lok and de RondLok & de Rond, 2013; Reference SminiaSminia, 2011). The suggestion also is to understand institutionalization as translation, as the problematization, interessement, enrolment, and mobilization by which an institution by way of practices takes shape performatively and discursively so that it provides identities and caters for the interests of the variety of actor/stakeholders who are then associated with and represented by this institution as practitioners.

From the perspective of institutional performative work, institutions are always in a state of becoming (cf. Reference Tsoukas and ChiaTsoukas & Chia, 2003). Rather than processes like institutionalization, or continuity and change, happening to institutions as if these are independently existing entities, it is about institutionalization as a process with the patterning appreciable as continuity or change. Up to this point, every variant of institutional theory has adhered to what has been labelled as the ‘weak’ process approach, while institutional performative work is a variant of institutional theory that is more akin to the ‘strong’ process approach (Reference Langley, Buchanan and BrymanLangley, 2009).

Furthermore and in contrast to Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006), institutional performative work is not limited to the purposeful maintenance, adaptation, disruption, and recreation of an institution, although it can feature deliberate and intentional action of individual and collective actors to keep the process going. Institutional performative work offers a nuanced understanding of agency. Overall, the agency involved in institutionalization is proposed to be understood as an ‘assemblage’ (Reference LatourLatour, 2005): as an arrangement of human and non-human agency which in combination constitute the practices by which an institution comes into existence when these practices are enacted. To refer to this processual understanding of agency, the Reference Deleuze, Guattari and MassumiDeleuze and Guattari (1987) term of ‘agencement’ has been used (Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza & Ferraro, 2019; Reference Gehman, Sharma and BeveridgeGehman et al., 2022; Reference Raviola and NorbäckRaviola & Norbäck, 2013; Reference Välikangas and CarlsenVälikangas & Carlsen, 2020). According to Reference GherardiGherardi (2019a) the French word of ‘agencement’ appeared to be difficult to translate into English and maybe has been best described by her as ‘establishing connections’ between a mixture of human and non-human actors so that preformation can be generated. By using agencement it is recognized that institutionalization relies on distributed agency, requiring a coming together of many contributions from individual actors, collective agents, but also tangible and non-tangible material resources.

To account for human actors and how they can contribute deliberately, intentionally, and meaningfully to the agencement, Reference Smets and JarzabkowskiSmets and Jarzabkowski (2013), Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and MeyerSmets et al. (2017), and Reference Raviola and NorbäckRaviola and Norbäck (2013) draw on Reference Emirbayer and MischeEmirbayer and Mische (1998) and their distinction between iterative, projective, and practical-evaluative agency. Iterative agency with its orientation on the past appears when a practice is routinely enacted as it always has been and is therefore associated with performing institutional continuity. Projective agency with its orientation towards the future appears when a practice is enacted differently because a different performation is envisioned and is thus associated with institutional change. Practical-evaluative agency is orientated towards the present with issues dealt with in the here and now to account for the variability in praxis to accommodate different institutional logics and generates the plasticity or elasticity of any institutionalized arrangement (Reference Bjerregaard and JonassonBjerregaard & Jonasson, 2014; Reference Boxenbaum, Pedersen, Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaBoxenbaum & Pedersen, 2009; Reference Lok and de RondLok & de Rond, 2013; Reference Sahlin, Wedlin, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and SuddabySahlin & Wedlin, 2008; Reference Smets, Jarzabkowski, Burke and SpeeSmets et al., 2015b).

Institutional work has been put forward to explain institutionalization. As defined and elaborated by Lawrence and Suddaby, institutionalization happens by way of various creating, maintaining, and disrupting activity types (Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence & Suddaby, 2006; Reference Lawrence, Leca and SuddabyLawrence et al., 2009; Reference Lawrence, Suddaby and LecaLawrence et al., 2011). The underpinning process principles that are referred to the most are structuration theory (Reference GiddensGiddens, 1976, Reference Giddens1979, Reference Giddens1984). As such, the process is animated by reflexivity. The organizational strategy process essentially is doing the institutional work activities by which structuration is happening (see Figure 9). Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006) purposely labelled it as ‘work’ to indicate that institutionalization requires continuous and – specific for them – deliberate effort. A strategist therefore is required to do this deliberate institutional work continuously. A departure from institutional entrepreneurship is that instead of the environmental process seeing institutionalization only happening by way of episodic change, institutional work envisions an ongoing process of institutionalization to maintain or change institutionalized arrangements.

Figure 9 Institutional work strategizing.

Institutional performative work can happen unintentionally as well as deliberately. It borrows underpinning process principles from actor-network theory (Reference CallonCallon, 1998; Reference LatourLatour, 2005) and the theory of practice (Reference SchatzkiSchatzki, 2002). Institutional performative work is another way of understanding how to accommodate institutional complexity (Reference Greenwood, Raynor, Kodelj, Micelotta and LounsburyGreenwood et al., 2011) or the ever-presence of different and conflicting institutional logics. Accommodating differences happens as a matter of course when people go about doing what they do on a day-to-day basis. What they do is enacting practices and in doing so institutional logics are instantiated – adhered to, modified, dismissed – as the work is being done. The process is animated by teleoaffectivity (Reference SchatzkiSchatzki, 2002) that tells a practitioner why a practice is to be enacted. Teleoaffectivity combines the practicality of ‘getting the job done’ (Reference Smets, Aristidou, Whittington, Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence and MeyerSmets et al., 2017) with affect or how much a practitioner cares about what needs to be done (Reference GherardiGherardi, 2019a). Adding affect resonates with the recent interest in the role of emotion in institutionalization (Reference FriedlandFriedland, 2018; Reference Voronov and VinceVoronov & Vince, 2012).

Apart from translation and therefore institutionalization happening because of practices being enacted mundanely on a day-to-day basis, institutional performative work allows for the possibility of deliberately considered and attempted institutional change. On the one hand, Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro (2019) present this as a single person – Charles, an executive at a financial data company – championing a new service that delivers data on environmental, social, and governance activity of companies to responsible investors – by him driving the translation to get this service up and running. This involves engaging with other executives in the company, people in his department, clients, responsible management activists but also with the data, to have all of this problematized, interessemented, enrolled, and mobilized.

On the other hand, Reference CzarniawskaCzarniawska (2009), writing about how the London School of Economics became established, presents institutionalization as translation as a collective effort, involving various instigators, supporters, users, opponents, money, a building, cups of tea, which all made contributions of some sort that translated a vague idea into a functioning university: an institution that is being performed by a range of different practices accompanied by specific norms, values, and ideas that legitimatize it. Among these ideas are accounts that effectively attribute leadership roles to specific human actors, despite some of them not having intended to play such a pivotal role.

These two contrasting accounts reveal a conceptual issue with institutional performative work. How can the iterative, projective, and practical-evaluative agency that individual human actors are endowed with as they are contributing to the enactment of a practice be squared with the agencement that is what allows a practice to be performed? More particularly, how is individual human agency to be singled out as possibly strategic agency while enacting a practice relies on all of this connected human and non-human agency? Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro (2019) single out Charles as a strategist or strategy practitioner whose agency drives the process. Reference CzarniawskaCzarniawska (2009) provides a tale of agencement. In a way, we appear to have encountered the paradox of embedded agency again, albeit in a different form.

The conceptual solution that is on offer here is to treat the agency with which a human actor is endowed with and the agencement that is assembled in a practice as basically the same story, but only if there is full translation. In actor-network theory, full translation is referred to as being blackboxed (Reference LatourLatour, 2005). A practice is a black box when all human and non-human actors relevant for this practice are problematized, interessemented, enrolled, and mobilized so that the agencement is present. This happens when a practice performs because the whole of the agencement acts. Without being blackboxed, individual human actors will not have agency and a practice will not perform. A human actor like Charles in Reference Beunza and FerraroBeunza and Ferraro’s (2019) case, in being singled out/singling himself out as a strategist, he is denoted/declares himself as representing strategy practices when strategy practices are being enacted. It is as if the strategy practices are being performed on his behalf. This can be any practice that is enacted while championing this new product in a financial data company and among those who are designated to become customers. Charles relies on translation to be a translator.

One of these practices, for instance, is formulating a business plan for the new product. Enacting such a practice brings together Charles who thinks up the text, the computer that processes all the words, the data that speaks in favour of the new product, the analytical frameworks by which the data are presented as a compelling argument, other people, procedures, equipment that produce this data, and more. This all comes together as an agencement, and allows for Charles to be understood – and to understand himself – as a strategist exercising iterative, projective, and practical-evaluative agency (see Figure 10).

Figure 10 Institutional performative work strategizing.

If Reference CzarniawskaCzarniawska (2009) would be about the same case, she would not have singled out Charles as a strategist driving the process. She would have mentioned him along all the other human and non-human agents that are present in the agencement. In this way, neither account is mutually exclusive. With both accounts, the organizational strategy process can be characterized as strategy-in-practices (Reference MacKay, Chia and NairMacKay et al., 2021) that combines the practical coping of practices being performed on a day-to-day basis with a the deliberate politics of practicality of discursively making claims and counterclaims about what is cognitively, normatively, and pragmatically legitimate and – maybe more importantly – performative experimentation that aims to demonstrate legitimacy by enacting (modified) practices.

Understanding the strategy process as institutional performative work, with a strategist seen as a practitioner exercising iterative, projective, and practical-evaluative agency, the organizational strategy process takes shape as strategy-in-practices that combines practical coping with some deliberate politics of practicality. The environmental survival process then can be understood as the constant becoming of a nexus of practices (Reference SchatzkiSchatzki, 2002) that are being enacted. The viability of a firm or an organization is then a matter of being denotable as representing some of these practices, as these are blackboxed through translation (Reference LatourLatour, 2005).

9 Discussion and Conclusion: Three Strategic Management Styles

It is possible to tell the story of institutional theory as an ongoing progression of insight as was done by Reference Glynn and D’AunnoGlynn and D’Aunno (2023), presenting this development as providing an increasingly improving understanding of what institutions do and of how institutionalization happens in the realm of management and organization. Such an argumentation would present the sociology-based variants of Old Institutionalism, New Institutionalism, institutional entrepreneurship and change, intra-organizational institutionalization, institutional logics, and institutional work as subsequent attempts at providing an ever-more sophisticated account, with each variant picking up problems and addressing issues inherent in earlier variants. We could even fit the economics-based variant of NIE in it somewhere as making a contribution. Alternatively, we could present the proliferation of so many different variants as evidence of the conceptual mess that institutional theory has developed into (Reference Alvesson and SpicerAlvesson & Spicer, 2019).

A story of increasing insight would turn institutional theory into a unified approach. Utilizing what institutional theory teaches us it would allow us to propose a more synoptic approach to strategic management. To do that we would have to fudge the exact chronology of publication dates and glance over the more fundamental differences between the different variants. These differences include whether an institution is a cognitive or a social phenomenon, whether an institution essentially is about norms, values, and ideas or about patterned recurrent and regular activity, and if it is about norms, values, and ideas whether an institution only refers to formal rules and regulations or does it also include informal expectations. There is also a question whether an institution is a multilevel phenomenon, and if so, how many levels do we need to distinguish and how do these levels interact? Or is institutionalization a process that happens in the same way across individuals, organizations, fields, and societies, eliminating the need to distinguish between levels? Besides, we have come across six different solutions to the paradox of embedded agency: leeway, imperfect institutionalization, separation of agency and structure over time, exogenous shock, hybridity, and blackboxing. Institutionalization has been presented as episodic change upsetting periods of institutional continuity and as a rather fragile stabilization of what essentially is a process of continuous becoming, happening either because of the activities of an individual institutional entrepreneur or as a collective effort. Moreover, underlying process principles vary from methodological individualism, social construction, and structuration theory to actor-network theory and the theory of practice, and more.

When we concentrate on how all of this has been brought to bear upon strategic management, it is possible to delineate between three different strategic management styles. Rather than distinguishing between theoretical approaches by specifying constructs and relationships, style denotes a more aesthetic sensitivity by providing a distinctive account that you recognize when you see it (Reference GherardiGherardi, 2019b). In a way, institutional theory provides us with a choice of how you would like your strategic management to be. The three styles of understanding and doing strategic management are derived from some of the fundamental differences that are present between the many variants of institutional theory. These three styles can be labelled as competitiveness-based, legitimacy-based, and performativity-based. Each of these three strategic management styles can be a reference point for a strategist’s ‘theory-in-use’ (Reference Argyris and SchönArgyris & Schön, 1978); of how they prefer to understand themselves, the strategy process, and the environment, that is, their own strategic management style. These styles are also indicative of different ways in which strategic management research could develop.

Competitiveness-based strategic management sticks with Reference PorterPorter’s (1980: 1) assumption that ‘Competition is at the core of the success or failure of firms’. Institutional theory here enhances textbook strategizing of dealing with competition by way of formulating and executing a strategy, with strategists engaged in processing relevant information to make rational decisions. Apart from information about the competitive environment and the firm’s capabilities, there is also information about the institutional environment that needs consideration, albeit all in aid of a firm’s competitiveness. This form of strategic management is evident in Non-Market Strategy and in the application of institutional theory in IB/S. NIE fits here as well, pointing at the importance of minimizing transaction costs. There is a bias here towards for-profit firms, although it can be claimed that non-profit and government organizations also face competition in some shape or form.

The bulk of mainstream strategic management research would fall within this realm because it is primarily concerned with competitive advantage. Institutional theory can and has provided further variables by which to explain competitive advantage and performance (e.g. Reference Bonardi, Holburn and Vanden BerghBonardi et al., 2006; Reference PajunenPajunen, 2008; Reference Peng, Wang and JiangPeng et al., 2008). This research mostly relied on NIE and to a lesser extent on New Institutionalism. It also limited the meaning of institution to formalized rules as put forward by governments and other (semi-)legislative bodies. If differences between institutional demands are acknowledged as per institutional logics, it is between countries. Institutional theory could tell mainstream strategy research that there is more to institutions than formal rules on a country-by-country basis. The set of institutional theory deduced variables to explain performance differences can be expanded to also include more informal norms, values, and ideas, and these sets of variables can be hypothesized and tested to vary between different settings than just countries (cf. Reference Doh, Lawton and RajwaniDoh et al., 2012). Taking this up, corporate political activity – ironically – already has been recognized as possibly normatively illegitimate on the basis of a New Institutionalism argument because it goes against a norm of private interests not interfering with public concerns (Reference LimLim, 2023). Using institutional theory as a source for more variables for explaining competitive advantage adds to and submits to mainstream strategy research, propagating a strategic management that is primarily understood as a process of formulating and executing a strategic plan.

Legitimacy-based strategic management treats the way in which firms can be competitive as resulting from the regularity in activity and the accompanying norms, values, and ideas as these have been institutionalized. Rather than limiting strategy to the question how to compete, it should primarily concern itself with the institutionalized arrangements within which competition unfolds. There are two concurrent concerns that a strategist then should pay attention to. One concern is that institutional entrepreneurship and change as well as intra-organizational institutionalization tells us that any institutionalized arrangement is always liable to be changed, undermining the competitiveness a firm might have or possibly making it obsolete. This also points at the possibility of a firm choosing to become institutionally entrepreneurial to change the institutionalized arrangements in their favour. The other concern is that institutional logics tell us that there are several different and conflicting institutionalized arrangements putting demands upon every organization. Despite accommodating different logics with the various tactics that have been identified, there is a continuous risk of a firm failing on specific institutionalized expectations and consequently loosing legitimacy to the extent that its existence is being threatened.

Non-profit and public organizations would not necessarily be worried that much about their competitiveness, yet their legitimacy is similarly fragile because, in Old Institutionalism terms, their viability depends on how well they meet changing and multiple expectations of the several communities that they are serving.

Institutional change and entrepreneurship and intra-organizational change also tell us to expect that periods of change are alternated with periods of relative stability or continuity. Institutional logics tell us that organizations have some leeway in picking which institutionalized expectations to concentrate on. Organizations are also to some extent able to appear to be conforming to different expectations. This suggests there are pockets of institutional stability and continuity in space and time within which an organization can legitimately function for as long as these pockets exist. Such pockets will see the isomorphism of New Institutionalism appearing with organizations displaying convergent incremental change. It is within such pockets that for firms, much of the theorizing about competitive advantage from mainstream strategic management can still be useful. It also suggests there always is an existential threat of these pockets disappearing or changing to such an extent that more radical strategic change is required.

Overall, the continuity and change that emerges will be the result of the institutional work that everybody will be engaging in, with organizations required to take an active interest in conducting such work as part of their strategic management. This is where the legitimacy-based style comes into its own as actively acknowledging, dealing with and possibly initiating change, with competitiveness-based strategic management only applying if there is a prolonged period of institutional continuity. Rather than seeing strategy theory as centred on explaining competitive advantage, the theorizing would focus on understanding how organizations remain legitimate under conflicting and ever-changing institutional demands.

This sketch of legitimacy-based strategic management glosses over some of the conceptual discrepancies between the variants of institutional theory that are being drawn on. Putting these aside, what we have is an opportunity to develop institutional theory into a strategy theory to create a more sociologically informed research program to balance out the strategy scholarship that is based on economics, which still dominates the field. This would be a deviation from mainstream strategy research, with institutional theory offering a promising alternative to understanding how organizations realize strategy, with it being conceptualized as a process of managing emerging change rather than a process of deliberate choice (Reference Mintzberg, Waters, Pettigrew and ButlerMintzberg et al., 1990). One research avenue, for instance, could develop a concept like dynamic capability as a capability for institutionalization, institutional entrepreneurship, and institutional change. Core capabilities are already recognized as being a ‘routine’ (Reference GrantGrant, 1991; Reference Nelson and WinterNelson & Winter, 1982). The obvious step is to conceptualize a core capability as an institutionalized activity pattern and to investigate the development, maintenance, and change of core capabilities, that is, dynamic capability as requiring institutional work. This could also be beneficial for institutional theory itself by shedding light on the efficacy of institutional work. Reference Lawrence, Suddaby, Clegg, Hardy and LawrenceLawrence and Suddaby (2006) have pointed out the presence and presumed effects of institutional work, yet we know little about what it is about creation, maintenance, and disruption work that generates the creation, maintenance, and disruption effects.

Research in strategic change and under the header of Strategy-as-Practice, which has chimed with institutional theory, already mostly fits with the legitimacy-based style of strategic management. However, it has mostly concentrated on the organizational strategy process and the activities of individual strategists. There are possibilities to make connections with the environmental survival process, basically by investigating strategy realization as a process that sees competing and surviving in the environment, organizational strategizing, and strategists’ behaviour as an institutionalization process. This would be especially useful for Strategy-as-Practice for this would allow it to start theorizing more about how what strategists and organizations do links up with organizational performance, albeit in terms of legitimacy and the pockets of relative stability within which competitiveness plays out. There has been criticism that Strategy-as-Practice has lost sight of this essential element of strategy (Reference Johnson, Melin and WhittingtonJohnson et al., 2003; Reference Sminia and de RondSminia & de Rond, 2012).

Performativity-based strategic management as a style for understanding and enacting the process and as a research stream is still in its infancy (Reference Cabantous, Gond and WrightCabantous et al., 2018; Reference Guérard, Langley and SeidlGuérard et al., 2013). It moves away from the substantialist approach to management and scholarship of ‘weak’ process, which characterizes the other two styles. Instead, entities like institutions are taken as essentially processual as these exist because of the activity by which these come into being. This means that strategy like performativity is an ongoing journey (Reference Garud, Gehman and TharchenGarud et al., 2018): a journey of ongoing institutionalization.

Although there are hints of performativity in the Institutional Logics perspective, this would mostly draw on ideas present in institutional performative work. This variant of institutional theory offers an even more radical departure from mainstream strategy. Strategic management then is more of a wayfinding that happens as you go along with the focus on keeping the organization underway while the institutionalization is happening rather than reaching pre-formulated destinations (Reference Chia and HoltChia & Holt, 2023). A performative style of strategic management would be characterized as a continuous questioning and problem-solving (Reference SminiaSminia, 2022), but also as inherently generative and creative because institutions are constantly being recreated. This provides a striking contrast with the planning mode that effectively tells you to think up problems and solve them in advance, as if you know what will be happening. Wayfinding acknowledges that the future still has to happen and that it is strategy’s job to help an organization travel into it. Wayfinding recognizes that a future is actively created with organizations making contributions as emerging issues are being dealt with.

Research that fits the performative style of strategic management is being conducted under the Strategy-as-Practice label. This concentrates mostly on organizational strategy process and sees it happening by way of enacting specific strategy practices. Such strategy practices include the many tools and techniques that are present in the strategy textbooks. However, from a performativity angle these are not analytical and cognitive aids to formulate a plan to be subsequently executed. What is put forward is that strategy tools and techniques provide a language of strategy by which the discursive aspect of the politics of practicality plays out (Reference Kornberger and CleggKornberger & Clegg, 2011; Reference LigonieLigonie, 2018). Furthermore, something like a strategic plan can become a non-human actor and part of the agencement of strategy-in-practices (Reference MacKay, Chia and NairMacKay et al., 2021). In this way, strategy formulation already is strategy implementation by bringing strategy into action (Reference Sminia, Valdovinos, Zuback, Tucker, Zwikael, Hughes and KirkpatrickSminia & Valdovinos, 2022). Additional research would look into the day-to-day coping of the strategy-in-practices (Reference MacKay, Chia and NairMacKay et al., 2021), which is going on beyond the deliberate strategy practices that are being enacted. Reference Chia and MackayChia and Mackay (2023) have already proposed for this mundane day-to-day practical coping to be understood as dynamic capability. An intriguing question then is how the deliberate practicing of strategy practices resonates with the practical coping of strategy-in-practices?

Another question that warrants further research zooms out to the organizational survival process. Here the performative aspect of institutional performative work comes into play with the way in which an organization performs its bundle of practices (Reference SchatzkiSchatzki, 2005). This is a matter of what practices are present in the bundle, their agencement as a connection of human and non-human agency, but also how these are being enacted, given the iterative, projective, and practical-evaluative agency that is available. Because practice theory tends to be based on a flat ontology by seeing everything as one process rather than distinguishing between multiple levels of different but connected processes (Reference Seidl and WhittingtonSeidl & Whittington, 2014), this is not about how the organization interacts with the environment. Enacting the bundle of practices by which the organization exists happens within many other practices in the nexus of practices being enacted, all as part of the same basic process.

Suggestions are that strategy practices make their contribution only if these inspire other practices in the bundle by which an organization exists to be enacted differently and when these experimentations appear to make a difference (Reference Merkus, Willems and VeenswijkMerkus et al., 2019; Reference Sminia, Valdovinos, Zuback, Tucker, Zwikael, Hughes and KirkpatrickSminia & Valdovinos, 2022; Reference VarghaVargha, 2018). However, the difference which is then generated has to resonate beyond the bundle of practices by which the organization exists, to also be of some practicality in the wider nexus of practices of the organizational survival process. How that is happening and can be made to happen is still largely unexplored. Overall, research inspired by this performative-style would focus on how organizations practically contribute to an ever-changing world.

Having consulted institutional theory, we have ended up with three different strategic management styles: competitiveness-bases, legitimacy-based, and performativity-based. For each style, institutional theory has something to contribute, albeit by drawing on specific variants. Overall, the potential that institutional theory shows for the further development of the strategic management field, for both theory and practice, is that there is much more to strategy than what the basic textbook approach continuous to tell us. There is much more to strategy than dealing with competition.

  • J.-C. Spender

  • Kozminski University

  • J.-C. Spender is a research Professor, Kozminski University. He has been active in the business strategy field since 1971 and is the author or co-author of 7 books and numerous papers. His principal academic interest is in knowledge-based theories of the private sector firm, and managing them.

Advisory Board

  • Jay Barney, Eccles School of Business, The University of Utah

  • Stewart Clegg, University of Technology, Sydney

  • Thomas Durand, Conservatoire National des Arts et Métiers, Paris

  • CT Foo, Independent Scholar, Singapore Robert Grant, Bocconi University, Milan Robin Holt,

  • Copenhagen Business School

  • Paula Jarzabkowski, Cass School, City University, London Naga Lakshmi Damaraju, Indian School of Business

  • Marjorie Lyles, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University

  • Joseph T. Mahoney, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

  • Nicolai Foss, Bocconi University, Milan

  • Andreas Scherer, University of Zurich

  • Deepak Somaya, College of Business, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

  • Eduard van Gelderen, Chief Investment Officer, APG, Amsterdam

About the Series

  • Business strategy’s reach is vast, and important too since wherever there is business activity there is strategizing. As a field, strategy has a long history from medieval and colonial times to today’s developed and developing economies. This series offers a place for interesting and illuminating research including industry and corporate studies, strategizing in service industries, the arts, the public sector, and the new forms of Internet-based commerce. It also covers today’s expanding gamut of analytic techniques.

Footnotes

1 The first version of this book appeared as Reference ScottScott (1992).

2 Sociologists might disagree here, albeit admitting that sociology has put forward many different explanations for how culture and institutions appear and change. Moreover, some of the institutional theory variants based on sociology presented later explicitly address this question.

3 Lawrence and Suddaby utilize the term ‘practices’ here. To distinguish their approach to institutional work from the more performative practice-driven approach that will be introduced further down in this chapter, the term ‘activity type’ is used here.

4 Reference FeldmanFeldman (2000) also utilizes this distinction in developing her notion of organizational routines in what later became known as ‘routine dynamics’. The ostensive aspect of a routine provides an idealized description how it should be done; the performative aspect denotes how the routine is done.

References

Abell, P., Felin, T., & Foss, N. 2008. Building micro-foundations for the routines, capabilities, and performance links. Managerial and Decision Economics, 29: 489501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvesson, M., Hallett, T., & Spicer, A. 2019. Uninhibited institutionalisms. Journal of Management Inquiry, 28(2): 119127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvesson, M., & Spicer, A. 2019. Neo-institutional theory and organization studies: A mid-life crisis? Organization Studies, 40(2): 199218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansoff, H. I. 1965. Corporate Strategy. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Argyris, C., & Schön, D. A. 1978. Organizational Learning: A Theory of Action Perspective. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Balogun, J., & Johnson, G. 2005. From intended strategies to unintended outcomes: The impact of change recipient sensemaking. Organization Studies, 26(11): 15731601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barley, S. R., & Tolbert, P. S. 1997. Institutionalization and structuration: Studying the links between action and institution. Organization Studies, 18(1): 93117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32(10): 12311241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D. P. 1995a. Integrated strategy: Market and nonmarket components. California Management Review, 37(2): 4765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D. P. 1995b. The nonmarket strategy system. Sloan Management Review(Fall): 7385.Google Scholar
Bass, B. M. 1991. From transactional to transformational leadership: Learning to share the vision. Organizational Dynamics, 18(3): 1931.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battilana, J., & Casciaro, T. 2012. Change agents, networks, and institutions: A contingency theory of organizational change. Academy of Management Journal, 55(2): 819836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battilana, J., & Dorado, S. 2010. Building sustainable hybrid organizations: The case of commercial microfinance organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 53: 14191440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battilana, J., Leca, B., & Boxenbaum, E. 2009. How actors change institutions: Towards a theory of institutional entrepreneurship. Academy of Management Annals, 3(1): 65107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckert, J. 1999. Agency, entrepreneurs, and institutional change: The role of strategic choice and institutionalized practices in organizations. Organization Studies, 20(5): 777799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennis, W., & Nanus, B. 1985. Leaders: The Strategies for Taking Charge. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. 1966. The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. New York: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Beunza, D., & Ferraro, F. 2019. Performative work: Bridging performativity and institutional theory in the responsible investment field. Organization Studies, 40(4): 515543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhappu, A. D. 2000. The Japanese family: An institutional logic for Japanese corporate networks and Japanese management. Academy of Management Review, 25(2): 409515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binder, A. 2007. For love and money: Organizations’ creative responses to multiple environmental logics. Theory and Society, 36: 547571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjerregaard, T., & Jonasson, C. 2014. Managing unstable institutional contradictions: The work of becoming. Organization Studies, 35(10): 15071536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blau, P. M. 1974. On the Nature of Organizations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Boddewyn, J., & Doh, J. P. 2011. Global strategy and the collaboration of MNEs, NGOs, and governments for the provision of collective goods in emerging markets. Global Strategy Journal, 1: 345361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonardi, J.-P., Hillman, A. J., & Keim, G. D. 2005. The attractiveness of political markets: Implications for firm strategy. Academy of Management Review, 30(3): 397413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonardi, J.-P., Holburn, G. L. F., & Vanden Bergh, R. G. 2006. Nonmarket strategy performance: Evidence from US electric utilities. Academy of Management Journal, 49(6): 12091228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourdieu, P. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourdieu, P. 1990. The Logic of Practice. Cambridge: Polity Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boxenbaum, E., & Pedersen, J. S. 2009. Scandinavian institutionalism: A case of institutional work. In Lawrence, T. B., Suddaby, R., & Leca, B. (Eds.), Institutional Work: Actors and Agency in Institutional Studies of Organization: 178204. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, R., & Richardson, P. J. 1985. Culture and the Evolutionary Process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Brandtner, C., Powell, W. W., & Horvath, A. 2024. From iron cage to glass house: Repurposing of bureaucratic management and the turn to openness. Organization Studies, 25(2), 193–221.Google Scholar
Brunsson, N. 2007. The Consequences of Decision-Making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cabantous, L., Gond, J.-P., & Wright, A. 2018. The performativity of strategy: Taking stock and moving ahead. Long Range Planning, 51: 407416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callon, M. 1986. Some elements of a sociology of translation: Domestication of the scallops and the fishermen of St. Brieuc Bay. In Law, J. (Ed.), Power, Action and Belief: 196233. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Callon, M. 1998. The Laws of the Markets. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Callon, M., & Latour, B. 1981. Unscrewing the big leviathan: How actors macro-structure reality and how sociologists help them to do so. In Knorr-Cetina, K., & Cicourel, A. V. (Eds.), Advances in Social Theory and Methodology: 277303. Boston, MA: Routledge.Google Scholar
Campbell, A. 1987. Mission statements. Long Range Planning, 30(6): 931932.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chia, R., & Holt, R. 2023. Strategy, intentionality and success: Four logics for explaining strategic action. Organization Theory, 4(1): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chia, R. C. H., & Mackay, D. 2023. Strategy-in-Practices. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Child, J. 1972. Organisational structure, environment and performance: The role of strategic choice. Sociology, 6(1): 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Child, J., & Smith, C. 1987. The context and process of organizational transformation – Cadbury limited in its sector. Journal of Management Studies, 24(6): 565593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. 1934. Institutional Economics. Maddison: University of Madison Press.Google Scholar
Coule, T., & Patmore, B. 2013. Institutional logics, institutional work, and public service innovation in non-profit organizations. Public Administration, 91(4): 980997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, G., Lockett, A., Finn, R., Martin, G., & Waring, J. 2012. Institutional work to maintain professional power: Recreating the model of medical professionalism. Organization Studies, 33(7): 937962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R. L., & March, J. G. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Czarniawska, B. 2009. Emerging institutions: Pyramids or anthills. Organization Studies, 30(4): 423441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Czarniawska, B., & Sevón, G. (Eds.). 1996. Translating Organizational Change. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Figueirdo, J. M. 2009. Integrated political strategy. In Nickerson, J. A., & Silverman, B. (Eds.), Advances in Strategic Management – Economic Institutions in Strategy, Vol. 26: 459486. Bingley: Emerald.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deleuze, G., & Guattari, F. 1987. A Thousand Plateaus (Massumi, B., Trans.). Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Delmas, M. A., & Toffel, M. W. 2008. Organizational responses to environmental demands: Opening the black box. Strategic Management Journal, 29: 10271055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P. J. 1988. Interest and agency in institutional theory. In Zucker, L. (Ed.), Institutional Patterns and Organizations: 332. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1991. Introduction. In Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: 138. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Doh, J. P., Lawton, T. C., & Rajwani, T. 2012. Advancing nonmarket strategy research: Institutional perspectives in a changing world. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(3) (August): 2239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domínguez, B., Gómez, J., & Maícas, J. P. in press. When does high institutional quality explain the presence of multinational enterprises in a foreign country? Experiential and vicarious learning as boundary conditions. Strategic Organization. https://doi.org/10.1177/14761270231195497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorado, S. 2005. Institutional entrepreneurship, partaking, and convening. Organization Studies, 26(3): 385414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorobantu, S., Kaul, A., & Zelner, B. 2017. Nonmarket strategy research through the lens of new institutional economics: An integrative review and future directions. Strategic Management Journal, 38: 114140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emirbayer, M., & Mische, A. 1998. What is agency? American Journal of Sociology, 103(4): 9621023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Empson, L., Cleaver, I., & Allen, J. 2013. Managing partners and management professionals: Institutional work dyads in professional partnerships. Journal of Management Studies, 50(5): 808844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, M. S. 2000. Organizational routines as a source of continuous change. Organization Science, 11(6): 611629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, M. S. 2003. A performative perspective on stability and change in organizational routines. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(4): 727752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, M. S., & Pentland, B. T. 2003. Reconceptualizing organizational routines as a source of flexibility and change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(1): 94118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felin, T., & Foss, N. 2009. Organizational routines and capabilities: Historical drift and a course-correction toward microfoundations. Scandinavian Journal of Management, 25: 157167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, N. 1997. Social skill and institutional theory. American Behavioral Scientist, 40(4): 397405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, N. 2001. Social skill and the theory of fields. Sociological Theory, 19(2): 105125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. (Ed.). 1997. Resources, Firms, and Strategies: A Reader in the Resource-based Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedland, R. 2018. Moving institutional logics forward: Emotion and meaningful material practice. Organization Studies, 39(4): 515542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedland, R., & Alford, R. R. 1991. Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices, and institutional contradictions. In Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: 232263. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Garcia-Pont, C., & Nohria, N. 2002. Local versus global mimetism: The dynamics of alliance formation in the automobile industry. Strategic Management Journal, 23: 307321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garud, R., Gehman, J., & Tharchen, T. 2018. Performativity as ongoing journeys: Implications for strategy, entrepreneurship, and innovation. Long Range Planning, 51): 500509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garud, R., Jain, S., & Kumaraswamy, A. 2002. Institutional entrepreneurship in the sponsorship of common technological standards: The case of Sun Microsystems and Java. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 196214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gawer, A., & Phillips, N. 2013. Institutional work as logics shift: The case of Intel’s transformation to platform leader. Organization Studies, 34(8): 10351071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gehman, J., Sharma, G., & Beveridge, A. 2022. Theorizing institutional entrepereneuring: Arborescent and rhizomatic assembling. Organization Studies, 43(2): 289310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Getz, K. A. 1997. Research in corporate political action: Integration and assessment. Business & Society, 36(1): 3272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gherardi, S. 2019a. How to Conduct a Practice-based Study: Problems and Methods (2nd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gherardi, S. 2019b. Theorizing affective ethnography for organization studies. Organization, 26(6): 741760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giddens, A. 1976. New Rules of Sociological Method: A Positive Critique of Interpretative Sociologies. London: Hutchinson.Google Scholar
Giddens, A. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social Analysis. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giddens, A. 1984. The Constitution of Society: Outline of a Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Glynn, M. A., & D’Aunno, T. 2023. An intellectual history of institutional theory: Looking back to move forward. Academy of Management Annals, 17(1): 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodrick, E., & Salancik, G. R. 1996. Organizational discretion in responding to institutional practices: Hospitals and cesarean births. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3): 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, R. M. 1991. The Resource-based theory of competitive advantage: Implications for strategy formulation. California Management Review, 33(3): 114135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., & Hinings, C. R. 1988. Organizational design types, tracks and the dynamics of strategic change. Organization Studies, 9(3): 293316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., & Hinings, C. R. 1993. Understanding strategic change: The contribution of archetypes. Academy of Management Journal, 36(5): 10521081.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., & Hinings, C. R. 1996. Understanding radical organizational change: Bringing together the old and the new institutionalism. Academy of Management Review, 21(4): 10221054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Sahlin, K., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.). 2008. The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. Los Angeles, CA: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., Raynor, M. E., Kodelj, H., Micelotta, E. R., & Lounsbury, M. 2011. Institutional complexity and organizational responses. Academy of Management Annals, 5(1): 155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutional entrepreneurship in mature fields: The big five accounting firms. Academy of Management Journal, 49(1): 2748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R., Suddaby, R., & Hinings, C. R. 2002. Theorizing change: The role of professional associations in the transformation of institutional fields. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 5880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grinyer, P. H., Mayes, D., & McKiernan, P. 1988. Sharpbenders: The Secrets of Unleashing Corporate Potential. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Guérard, S., Langley, A., & Seidl, D. 2013. Rethinking the concept of performance in strategy research: Towards a performative perspective. M@n@gement, 16(5): 566578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guler, I., Guillén, M. F., & Macpherson, J. M. 2002. Global competition, institutions, and the diffusion of organizational practices: The international spread of ISO 9000 quality certificates. Administrative Science Quarterly, 47: 207232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gumpert, P. J. 2000. Academic restructuring: Organizational change and institutional imperatives, higher education. International Journal of Higher Education and Educational Planning, 39: 6791.Google Scholar
Gümüsay, A. A., Claus, L., & Amis, J. 2020a. Engaging with grand challenges: An institutional logics perspective. Organization Theory, 1: 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gümüsay, A. A., Smets, M., & Morris, T. 2020b. ‘God at work’: Engaging central and incompatible institutional logics through elastic hybridity. Academy of Management Journal, 63(1): 124154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardy, C., & Maguire, S. 2008. Institutional entrepreneurship. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Sahlin, K., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism: 198217. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hargadon, A. B., & Douglas, Y. 2001. When innovations meet institutions: Edison and the design of the electric light. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 476501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, H. A., & Rao, H. 1997. Structuring a theory of moral sentiments: Institutional and organizational coevolution in the early thrift industry. American Journal of Sociology, 102(6): 16061651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J., & Delios, A. 2004. Information or influence? The benefits of experience for managing political uncertainty. Strategic Organization, 2(4): 389421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J., & Zelner, B. A. 2003. The strategic organization of political risks and opportunities. Strategic Organization, 1(4): 451460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J., & Zelner, B. A. 2012. Strategy and competition in the market and nonmarket arenas. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(3): 4051.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, A. J., & Hitt, M. A. 1999. Corporate political strategy formulation: A model of approach, participation, and strategy decisions. Academy of Management Review, 24(4): 825–824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinings, C. R., & Greenwood, R. 1988a. The Dynamics of Strategic Change. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hinings, C. R., & Greenwood, R. 1988b. The normative prescription of organizations. In Zucker, L. G. (Ed.), Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Environment: 5370. Chicago, IL: Ballinger.Google Scholar
Hoffman, A. J. 1999. Institutional evolution and change: Environmentalism and the US chemical industry. Academy of Management Journal, 42(4): 351371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, A. J. 2001. Linking organizational and field-level analysis. Organization & Environment, 14(2): 133156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holburn, G. L. F., & Vanden Bergh, R. G. 2008. Making friends in hostile environments: Political strategy in regulated industries. Academy of Management Review, 23(2): 521540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionalization: Transformation processes in Norwegian fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40: 423443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotho, J. J., & Pedersen, T. 2012. Beyond the ‘rules of the game’: Three institutional approaches and how they matter for international business. In Wood, G., & Demirbag, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Institutional Approaches to International Business: 236273. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hrebiniak, L. G., & Joyce, W. 1984. Implementing Strategy. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Huff, A. S. 1982. Industry influences on strategy reformulation. Strategic Management Journal, 3: 119131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingram, P., & Silverman, B. (Eds.). 2002. The New Institutionalism in Strategic Management. Amsterdam: Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarzabkowski, P. A., Balogun, J., & Seidl, D. 2007. Strategizing: The challenges of a practice perspective. Human Relations, 60(1): 527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jepperson, R. L. 1991. Institutions, institutional effects, and institutionalism. In Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: 143163. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, G. 1987. Strategic Change and the Management Process. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Johnson, G., Melin, L., & Whittington, R. 2003. Micro strategy and strategizing: Towards an activity-based view. Journal of Management Studies, 40(1): 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C., & Livne-Tarandach, R. 2008. Designing a frame: Rhetorical strategies of architects. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 29: 10751099.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. 1996. The Balanced Scorecard: Translating Strategy into Action. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Khaire, M., & Wadhwani, R. D. 2010. Changing landscapes: The construction of meaning and value in a new market category – modern Indian art. Academy of Management Journal, 53(6): 12811304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kikulis, L. M., Slack, T., & Hinings, C. R. 1992. Institutionally specific design archetypes: A framework for understanding change in National Sport Organizations. International Review for the Sociology of Sport, 27: 343369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kikulis, L. M., Slack, T., & Hinings, C. R. 1995. Sector-specific patterns of organizational design change. Journal of Management Studies, 32(1): 67100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kingsley, A. F., Vanden Bergh, R. G., & Bonardi, J.-P. 2012. Political markets and regulatory uncertainty: Insights and implications for integrated strategy. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(3) (August): 5267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kondra, A. Z., & Hinings, C. R. 1998. Organizational diversity and change in institutional theory. Organization Studies, 19(5): 743767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kondra, A. Z., & Hurst, D. C. 2009. Institutional processes of organizational culture. Culture and Organization, 15(1): 3958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornberger, M., & Clegg, S. R. 2011. Strategy as performative practice. Strategic Organization, 9(2): 136162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kostova, T. 1999. Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: A contextual perspective. Academy of Management Review, 24(2): 308324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kostova, T., & Roth, K. 2002. Adoption of an organizational practice by subsidiaries of multinational corporations: Institutional and relational effects. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 215233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kostova, T., Roth, K., & Dacin, M. T. 2008. Institutional theory in the study of multinational corporations: A critique and new directions. Academy of Management Review, 33(4): 9941008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 24(1): 6481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kraatz, M. S., & Block, E. S. 2008. Organizational implications of institutional pluralism. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Sahlin, K., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism: 243275. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langley, A. 2009. Studying processes in and around organizations. In Buchanan, D. A., & Bryman, A. (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of Organizational Research Methods: 409429. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Latour, B. 1986. The powers of association. In Law, J. (Ed.), Power, Action and Belief: A New Sociology of Knowledge: 264280. Keele: Methuen.Google Scholar
Latour, B. 2005. Reassembling the Social: An Introduction to Actor-Network-Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B. 1999. Institutional strategy. Journal of Management, 25(2): 161188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B., Leca, B., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.). 2009. Institutional Work: Actors and Agency in Institutional Studies of Organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B., Leca, B., & Zilber, T. B. 2013. Institutional work: Current research, new directions and overlooked issues. Organization Studies, 34(8): 10231033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B., & Phillips, N. 2004. From Moby Dick to Free Willy: Macro-cultural discourse and institutional entrepreneurship in emerging institutional fields. Organization, 11(5): 689711.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B., & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutions and institutional work. In Clegg, S. R., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. (Eds.), Handbook of Organization Studies, 2nd ed.: 215255. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, T. B., Suddaby, R., & Leca, B. 2011. Institutional work: Refocusing institutional studies of organization. Journal of Management Inquiry, 20(1): 5258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leblebici, H., Salancik, G. R., Copay, A., & King, T. 1991. Institutional change and the transformation of interorganizational fields: An organizational history of the US radio broadcasting industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 333363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lepak, D. P., Smith, K. G., & Taylor, M. S. 2007. Value creation and value capture: A multilevel perspective. Academy of Management Review, 32(1): 180194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, D., & Schoenherr, T. 2023. The institutionalization of sharing economy platforms in China. Journal of Operations Management, 69: 764793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ligonie, M. 2018. The ‘forced performativity’ of a strategy concept: Exploring how shared value shaped a gambling company’s strategy. Long Range Planning, 51: 463479.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lim, J. 2023. The balancing act of corporate political activity under institutional pressure. Strategic Organization, 21(4): 856873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lok, J. 2010. Institutional logics as identity projects. Academy of Management Journal, 53(6): 13051335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lok, J., & de Rond, M. 2013. On the plasticity of institutions: Containing and restoring practice breakdowns at the Cambridge University Boat Club. Academy of Management Journal, 56(1): 185207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M. 2001. Institutional sources of practice variation: Staffing college and university recycling programs. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46: 2956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M. 2002. Institutional transformation and status mobility: The professionalization of the field of finance. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 255266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M. 2007. A tale of two cities: Competing logics and practice variation in the professionalizing of mutual funds. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 289307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M. 2008. Institutional rationality and practice variation: New directions in the institutional analysis of practice. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 33: 349361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M., Anderson, D. A., & Spee, P. 2021. On practice and institution. In Lounsbury, M., Anderson, D. A., & Spee, P. (Eds.), On Practices and Institutions: Theorizing the Interface. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Vol. 70: 128. Bingley: Emerald.Google Scholar
Lounsbury, M., & Crumley, E. T. 2007. New practice creation: An institutional perspective on innovation. Organization Studies, 28(7): 9931012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M., & Glynn, M. A. 2001. Cultural entrepreneurship: Stories, legitimacy, and the acquisition of resources. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 545564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M., & Leblebici, H. 2004. The origins of strategic practice: Product diversification in the American mutual fund industry. Strategic Organization, 2(1): 6590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M., & Rao, H. 2004. Sources of durability and change in market classifications: A study of the reconstitution of product categories in the American mutual fund industry, 1944–1985. Social Forces, 82(3): 969999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lounsbury, M., Ventresca, M., & Hirsch, P. M. 2003. Social movements, field frames and industry emergence: A cultural-political perspective on US recycling. Socio-Economic Review, 1: 71104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lukes, S. 1974. Power: A Radical View. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, J., Chen, D., & Chen, J. 2021. Coming back and giving back: Transaction, institutional actors, and the paradox of peripheral influence. Administrative Science Quarterly, 66(1), 133176.Google Scholar
MacKay, R. B., Chia, R., & Nair, A. K. 2021. Strategy-in-practices: A process philosophical approach to understanding strategy emergence and organizational outcomes. Human Relations, 74(9): 13337–11369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. 2003. Constructing a market, performing theory: The historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 109(1): 107145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maguire, K., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2004. Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in Canada. Academy of Management Journal, 47(5): 657679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, J. T., & Pandian, J. R. 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 13: 363380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maitlis, S., & Lawrence, T. B. 2003. Orchestral manoeuvres in the dark: Understanding failure in organizational strategizing. Journal of Management Studies, 40(1): 109139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mantere, S. 2008. Role expectations and middle manager strategic agency. Journal of Management Studies, 45(2): 294316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Maurice, M. 1979. For a study of ‘the societal effect’: Universality and specificity in organisation research. In Lammers, C. J., & Hickson, D. J. (Eds.), Organizations Alike and Unlike: 4260. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. 1977. Resource mobilization and social movements: A partial theory. American Journal of Sociology, 82(6): 12121241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mead, G. H. 1934. Mind, Self, and Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mellahi, K., Frynas, J. G., Sun, P., & Siegel, D. 2016. A review of the nonmarket strategy literature: Toward a multi-theoretical integration. Journal of Management, 42(1): 143173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merkus, S., Willems, T., & Veenswijk, M. 2019. Strategy implementation as performative practice: Reshaping organization into alignment with strategy. Organization Management Journal, 16(3): 140155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, K. E. 2001. Institutions, transaction costs, and entry mode choice in Eastern Europe. Journal of International Business Studies, 32(2): 357367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, K. E., Estrin, S., Bhaumik, S. K., & Peng, M. W. 2009. Institutions, resources, and entry strategies in emerging economies. Strategic Management Journal, 30: 6180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, K. E., & Peng, M. W. 2005. Probing theoretically into Central and Eastern Europe: Transactions, resources, and institutions. Journal of International Business Studies, 36: 600621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, M. W., & Zucker, L. G. 1989. Permanently Failing Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Micelotta, E. R., Lounsbury, M., & Greenwood, R. 2017. Pathways of institutional change: An integrative review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 43(6): 18851910.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miles, R. E., & Snow, C. C. 1978. Organization Strategy, Structure, and Process. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google ScholarPubMed
Miller, D., & Friesen, P. H. 1984. Organizations: A Quantum View. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Mintzberg, H. 1979. The Structure of Organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Mintzberg, H. 1987. The strategy concept I: Five Ps for strategy. California Management Review, 30(1): 1124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintzberg, H., Waters, J. A., Pettigrew, A. M., & Butler, R. J. 1990. Studying deciding: An exchange of views between Mintzberg and Waters, Pettigrew, and Butler. Organization Studies, 11(1): 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moorman, C. 2002. Consumer health under the scope. Journal of Customer Research, 29: 152158.Google Scholar
Munir, K. A. 2005. The social construction of events: A study of institutional change in the photographic field. Organization Studies, 26(1): 93112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munir, K. A., & Phillips, N. 2005. The birth of the ‘Kodak moment’: Institutional entrepreneurship and the adoption of new technologies. Organization Studies, 26(11): 16651687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutch, A. 2007. Reflexivity and the institutional entrepreneur: A historical exploration. Organization Studies, 28(7): 11231140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Narayanan, V. K., & Fahey, L. 1982. The micro-politics of strategy formulation. Academy of Management Review, 7(1): 2534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Newman, K. L. 2000. Organizational transformation during institutional upheaval. Academy of Management Review, 25(3): 602619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. 1986. The new institutional economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 142(1): 230237.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. 1991. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1): 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ocasio, W., & Gai, S. L. 2020. Institutions: Everywhere but not everything. Journal of Management Inquiry, 29(3): 262271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review, 16(1): 145179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitutionalization. Organization Studies, 13(4): 563588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, C. 1997a. The influence of institutional and task environment relationships on organizational performance: The Canadian construction industry. Journal of Management Studies, 34(1): 99124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, C. 1997b. Sustainable competitive advantage: Combining institutional and resource-based views. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 697713.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pache, A.-C., & Santos, F. 2010. When worlds collide: The internal dynamics of organizational responses to conflicting institutional demands. Academy of Management Review, 35(3): 455476.Google Scholar
Pajunen, K. 2008. Institutions and inflows of foreign direct investment: A fuzzy-set analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 39: 652669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choice. Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 275296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2006. Global Strategy. Cincinnati, OH: South-Western Thomson.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Heath, P. S. 1996. The growth of the firm in planned economies in transition: Institutions, organizations, and strategic choice. Academy of Management Review, 21(2): 492528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W., Wang, D. Y. L., & Jiang, Y. 2008. An institution-based view of international business strategy: A focus on emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39: 920936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perkmann, M., & Spicer, A. 2008. How are management fashions institutionalized? The role of institutional work. Human Relations, 61(6): 811844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettigrew, A. M. 1985. The Awakening Giant: Continuity and Change in ICI. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Pettigrew, A. M. 1997. What is processual analysis? Scandinavian Journal of Management, 13(4): 337348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfeffer, J. 1981. Power in Organizations. Boston, MA: Pitman.Google Scholar
Porac, J. F., Thomas, H., & Baden-Fuller, C. 1989. Competitive groups as cognitive communities: The case of Scottish knitwear manufacturers. Journal of Management Studies, 26(4): 397416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E. 1996. What is strategy? Harvard Business Review, 74 (November-December): 6178.Google Scholar
Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.). 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: Chicago University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pozzebon, M. 2004. The influence of a structurationist view on strategic management research. Journal of Management Studies, 41(2): 247272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prahalad, C. K., & Bettis, R. A. 1986. The dominant logic: A new linkage between diversity and performance. Strategic Management Journal, 7: 485501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quatrone, P. 2015. Governing social orders, unfolding rationality, and Jesuit accounting practices: A procedural approach to institutional logics. Administrative Science Quarterly, 60: 411445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quinn, J. B. 1980. Strategies for Change: Logical Incrementalism. Homewood, IL: Richard D Irwin.Google Scholar
Ranson, S., Hinings, C. R., & Greenwood, R. 1980. The structuring of organizational structures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2003. Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an identity movement in French gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology, 108(4): 795843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raviola, E., & Norbäck, M. 2013. Bringing technology and meaning into institutional work: Making news at an Italian business newspaper. Organization Studies, 34(8): 11711194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raynard, M., Johnson, G., & Greenwood, R. 2016. Institutional theory and strategic management. In Jenkins, M., & Ambrosini, V. (Eds.), Strategic Management: A Multiple-Perspective Approach: 934. London: Red Globe Press.Google Scholar
Reay, T., Golden-Biddle, K., & Germann, K. 2006. Legitimizing a new role: Small wins and microprocesses of change. Academy of Management Journal, 49(5): 977998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reay, T., & Hinings, C. R. 2005. The recomposition of an organizational field: Health care in Alberta. Organization Studies, 26(3): 351384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reay, T., & Hinings, C. R. 2009. Managing the rivalry of competing institutional logics. Organization Studies, 30(6): 629652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinecke, J., & Lawrence, T. B. 2023. The role of temporality in institutional stabilization: A process view. Academy of Management Review, 48(4): 639658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritvala, T., & Kleymann, B. 2012. Scientists as midwives to cluster emergence: An institutional work framework. Industry and Innovation, 19(6): 477497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, M., Swan, J., & Newell, S. 1996. The role of networks in the diffusion of technological innovation. Journal of Management Studies, 33(3): 333360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rojas, F. 2010. Power through institutional work: Acquiring academic authority in the 1968 third world strike. Academy of Management Journal, 53(6): 12631280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rouleau, L. 2005. Micro-practices of strategic sensemaking and sensegiving: How middle managers interpret and sell change every day. Journal of Management Studies, 42(7): 14131441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sahlin, K., & Wedlin, L. 2008. Circulating ideas: Imitation, translation and editing. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Sahlin, K., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism: 218242. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samra-Fredericks, D. 2003. Strategizing as lived experience and strategists’ everyday efforts to shape strategic direction. Journal of Management Studies, 40(1): 141174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schatzki, T. R. 2001. Introduction. In Schatzki, T. R., Knorr-Cetina, K., & von Savigny, E. (Eds.), The Practice Turn in Contemporary Theory: 114. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Schatzki, T. R. 2002. The Site of the Social: A Philosophical Exploration of the Constitution of Social Life and Change. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schatzki, T. R. 2005. The sites of organizations. Organization Studies, 26(3): 465484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schatzki, T. R. 2006. On organizations as they happen. Organization Studies, 27(12): 18631873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schatzki, T. R. 2021. Forming alliances. In Lounsbury, M., Anderson, D. A., & Spee, P. (Eds.), On Practice and Institution: Theorizing the Interface. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Vol. 70: 119137. Bingley: Emerald.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R. 1987. The adolescence of institutional theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32: 493511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. R. 1992. Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R. 2014. Institutions and Organizations (4th ed.). London: Sage.Google Scholar
Seidl, D., & Whittington, R. 2014. Enlarging the strategy-as-practice research agenda: Towards taller and flatter ontologies. Organization Studies, 35(10): 14071421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selznick, P. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration: A Sociological Interpretation. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Selznick, P. 1996. Institutionalism ‘old’ and ‘new’. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(2): 270277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seo, M.-G., & Creed, W. E. D. 2002. Institutional contradictions, praxis, and institutional change: A dialectical perspective. Academy of Management Review, 27(2): 222247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sevón, G. 1996. Organizational imitation in identity transformation. In Czarniawska, B., & Sevón, G. (Eds.), Translating Organizational Change: 4967. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sewell, W. H. 1992. A theory of structure: Duality, agency, and transformation. American Journal of Sociology, 98(1): 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1947. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organizations. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1957. Models of Man: Social and Rational. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Slager, R., Gond, J.-P., & Moon, J. 2012. Standardization as institutional work: The regulatory power of a responsible investment standard. Organization Studies, 33(5–6): 763790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, M., Aristidou, A., & Whittington, R. 2017. Towards a practice-driven institutionalism. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Lawrence, T. B., & Meyer, R. E. (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism, 2nd ed.: 365391. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, M., Greenwood, R., & Lounsbury, M. 2015a. An institutional perspective on strategy as practice. In Golsorkhi, D., Rouleau, L., Seidl, D., & Vaara, E. (Eds.), The Cambridge Handbook of Strategy as Practice, 2nd ed.: 283300. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, M., & Jarzabkowski, P. A. 2013. Reconstructing institutional complexity in practice: A relational model of institutional work and complexity. Human Relations, 66(10): 12791309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, M., Jarzabkowski, P. A., Burke, G. T., & Spee, P. 2015b. Reinsurance trading in Lloyd’s of London: Balancing conflicting-yet-complementary logics in practice. Academy of Management Journal, 58(3): 932970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, M., Morris, T., & Greenwood, R. 2012. From practice to field: A multilevel model of practice-driven institutional change. Academy of Management Journal, 55(4): 877904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sminia, H. 2005. Strategy formation as layered discussion. Scandinavian Journal of Management, 21: 267291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sminia, H. 2009. Process research in strategy formation: Theory, methodology and relevance. International Journal of Management Reviews, 11(1): 97125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sminia, H. 2011. Institutional continuity and the Dutch construction industry fiddle. Organization Studies, 32(11): 15591585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sminia, H. 2022. The Strategic Manager: Understanding Strategy in Practice (3rd edn.). Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Sminia, H., & de Rond, M. 2012. Context and action in the transformation of strategy scholarship. Journal of Management Studies, 49(7): 13291349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sminia, H., & Valdovinos, F. S. 2022. Implementing strategy and avenues of access: A practice perspective. In Zuback, A., Tucker, D. A., Zwikael, O., Hughes, K., & Kirkpatrick, S. A. (Eds.), Effective Implementation of Transformation Strategies: How to Navigate the Strategy and Change Interface Successfully: 6588. Singapore: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smircich, L., & Morgan, G. 1982. Leadership: The management of meaning. Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 18(3): 257273.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Spender, J.-C. 1989. Industry Recipes: An Enquiry into the Nature and Sources of Managerial Judgement. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches. Academy of Management Review, 20(3): 571610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suddaby, R., Bitektine, A., & Haack, P. 2017. Legitimacy. Academy of Management Annals, 11(1): 451478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suddaby, R., & Greenwood, R. 2005. Rhetorical strategies of legitimacy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50: 3567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suddaby, R., Seidl, D., & , J. K. 2013. Strategy-as-practice meets neo-institutional theory. Strategic Organization, 11(3): 329344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, P. H. 2002. The rise of the corporation in a craft industry: Conflict and conformity in institutional logics. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 81101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, P. H., Jones, C., & Kury, K. 2005. Institutional logics and institutional change: Transformation in accounting, architecture, and publishing. In Jones, C., & Thornton, P. H. (Eds.), Sociology in Organizations: 125170. London: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Thornton, P. H., & Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutional logics and the historical contingency of power in organizations: Executive succession in the higher education publishing industry, 1958–1990. American Journal of Sociology, 105(3): 801843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, P. H., & Ocasio, W. 2008. Institutional logics. In Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Sahlin, K., & Suddaby, R. (Eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism: 99129. London: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, P. H., Ocasio, W., & Lounsbury, M. 2012. The Institutional Logics Perspective: A New Approach to Culture, Structure and Process. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. 1983. Institutional sources of change in the formal structure of organizations: The diffusion of civil service reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 2239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsoukas, H., & Chia, R. 2003. Everything flows and nothing abides. Process Studies, 32(2): 196224.Google Scholar
Vaara, E., Kleymann, B., & Seristö, H. 2004. Strategies as discursive constructions: The case of airline alliances. Journal of Management Studies, 41(1): 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Välikangas, L., & Carlsen, A. 2020. Spitting in the salad: Minor rebellion as institutional agency. Organization Studies, 41(9): 543561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van de Ven, A. H. 1992. Suggestions for studying strategy process: A research note. Strategic Management Journal, 13(Summer Special Issue): 169191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vargha, Z. 2018. Performing a strategy’s world: How redesigning customers made relationship banking possible. Long Range Planning, 51: 480494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. 1909. The limitations of marginal utility. Journal of Political Economy, 17(9): 620636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Von Mises, L. 1949. Human Action. Chicago, IL: Henry Regnery.Google Scholar
Voronov, M., & Vince, R. 2012. Integrating emotions into the analysis of institutional work. Academy of Management Review, 37(1): 5881.Google Scholar
Weick, K. E. 1979. The Social Psychology of Organizing (2nd ed.). New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Weick, K. E. 1995. Sensemaking in Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Weick, K. E., Sutcliffe, K. M., & Obstfeld, D. 2005. Organizing and the process of sensemaking. Organization Science, 16(4): 409421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whipp, R., & Clark, P. 1986. Innovation and the Auto Industry. London: Frances Pinter.Google Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1990. Eastern Asian enterprise structures and the comparative analysis of forms of business organization. Organization Studies, 11(1): 4774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1991. The social construction of business systems in East Asia. Organization Studies, 12(1): 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1992. European Business Systems: Firms and Markets in Their National Contexts. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1994. Dominant forms of economic organization in market economies. Organization Studies, 15(2): 153182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1998. Internationalization and varieties of capitalism: The limited effects of cross-national coordination of economic activities on the nature of business systems. Review of International Political Economy, 5(3): 445481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 1999. Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 2000. The institutional structuring of innovation strategies: Business systems, firm types and patterns of technical change in different market economies. Organization Studies, 21(5): 855886.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 2003. From the search for universal correlations to institutional structuring of economic organization and change: The development and future of organization studies. Organization, 10(3): 481501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitley, R. D. 2007. Business Systems and Organizational Capabilities. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whittington, R. 2006. Completing the practice turn in strategy research. Organization Studies, 27(5): 613634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whittington, R. 2015. Giddens, structuration theory and strategy as practice. In Golsorkhi, D., Rouleau, L., Seidl, D., & Vaara, E. (Eds.), The Cambridge Handbook of Strategy as Practice, 2nd ed.: 145164. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wijen, F., & Ansari, S. 2007. Overcoming inaction through collective institutional entrepreneurship: Insights from regime theory. Organization Studies, 28(7): 10791100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1981. The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology, 87(3): 548577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1991. Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization. Strategic Management Journal, 12(Winter Special Issue): 7594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1999a. Public and private bureaucracies: A transaction cost economics perspective. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 15(1): 306342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1999b. Strategy research: Governance and competitive perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20(12): 10871108.3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 2000. The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3): 595613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodward, J. 1965. Industrial Organization: Theory and Practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Zajac, E. J., & Westphal, J. D. 2004. The social construction of market value: Institutionalization and learning perspectives on stock market reactions. American Sociological Review, 69(3): 433457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zietsma, C., Groenewegen, P., Logue, D., & Hinings, C. R. 2017. Field or fields? Building the scaffolding for cumulation of research on institutional fields. Academy of Management Annals, 11(1): 391450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zietsma, C., & Lawrence, T. B. 2010. Institutional work in the transformation of an organizational field: The interplay of boundary work and practice work. Administrative Science Quarterly, 55: 189221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zilber, T. B. 2002. Institutionalization as an interplay between actions, meanings and actors: The case of a rape crisis center in Israel. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 234254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zilber, T. B. 2006. The work of the symbolic in institutional processes: Translations of rational myths in Israeli high tech. Academy of Management Journal, 49(2): 281303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zilber, T. B. 2024. Narrating institutional logics into effect: Coherence across cognitive, political, and emotional elements. Administrative Science Quarterly, 69(1), 172221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zucker, L. G. 1983. Organizations as institutions. In Bacharach, S. B. (Ed.), Advances in Organizational Theory and Research: 143. Greenwich, CN: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Textbook strategizing.

Figure 1

Table 1 Overview of Institutional Theory Variants

Figure 2

Figure 2 New institutional economics strategizing.

Figure 3

Figure 3 Old institutionalism strategizing.

Figure 4

Figure 4 New institutionalism strategizing as per non-market strategy.

Figure 5

Figure 5 New institutionalism strategizing.

Figure 6

Figure 6 Institutional entrepreneurship strategizing.

Figure 7

Figure 7 Intra-organizational institutional strategizing.

Figure 8

Figure 8 Institutional logics strategizing.

Figure 9

Figure 9 Institutional work strategizing.

Figure 10

Figure 10 Institutional performative work strategizing.

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Strategizing With Institutional Theory
  • Harry Sminia, Strathclyde Business School
  • Online ISBN: 9781009357654
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Strategizing With Institutional Theory
  • Harry Sminia, Strathclyde Business School
  • Online ISBN: 9781009357654
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Strategizing With Institutional Theory
  • Harry Sminia, Strathclyde Business School
  • Online ISBN: 9781009357654
Available formats
×