Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-fnpn6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-01T16:20:11.515Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Village segmentation and class formation in southern Malaŵi

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 December 2011

Extract

This paper is about a problem which arises from James Clyde Mitchell's study of the Yao village in southern Malaŵi. When writing about the Yao, Mitchell drew our attention to their system of group segmentation which he portrayed as though it were perpetual in character (Mitchell 1952: 18-20). Here I analyse the implication of this process of group segmentation in a situation which is governed by administrative regulations that make it difficult for segmenting groups to spread as freely as they used to do before Britain colonised the country in 1891. What I want to argue is that owing to changes in population, against the background of fixed administrative or even political boundaries, group segmentation in southern Malaŵi is bound to throw into the open the old scars of structural inequality. Two types of facts are, therefore, required to carry out this demonstration: demographic and historical. Consequently, I divide this paper into three major sections: one in which I present figures showing population densities in Malaŵi in general, and in southern Malaŵi in particular; one in which I give a brief historical outline of Malaŵi; and one in which I attempt to show that from the available historical information we can discern processes that led to the formation of classes in Malaŵi and how these classes were simplified by the formation of the colonial situation which reduced, at one stroke, all Africans into a dependent class vis-à-vis the European colonisers. But despite this over-simplified picture of the two classes in the colonial situation, there is evidence at the local level which shows that as land is increasingly becoming scarce, relative to population growth, village disputes over land illuminate the traditional structure of inequalities. I hold the view that the inevitable result of the contradiction between population growth and land shortage is class formation.

Résumé

Segmentation villageoise et formation de classes sociales au Malaŵi Méridional

Le présent article évoque le problème de la segmentation continue des villages Yao telle que l'a étudiée James Clyde Mitchell. La thèse avancée par l'auteur est que le manque de terres et l'accroissement de la population mettent un frein à la création continue de groupes homogènes, et favorisent l'émergence d'une structure de classe séparant ceux qui contrôlent la distribution des terres du reste de la population. Le concept de mode de production est utilisé pour expliquer la formation de classes sociales. Dans l'histoire socio-économique du Malaŵi, l'agriculture domestique, l'esclavage domestique et le capitalisme sont les trois principaux modes de production. L'agriculture domestique était pratiquée par les chasseurs Akafula avant et après l'arrivée au Malaŵi méridional des conquérants Marave, au quatorzième siècle. Ainsi, les families produisaient-elles tout ce qui était nécessaire à leur subsistance. Par contre, l'esclavage domestique semble apparaître au moment de l'arrivée des Marave. Grâce à cette institution, les propriétaires d'esclaves commencèrent à vivre de ce que produisait cette main-d'oeuvre. Lorsque la Grande Bretagne colonisa le Malaŵi au 19° siècle, on introduisit un mode de production capitaliste qui divisa la société en employeurs colonisateurs et travailleurs colonisés, de sorte que la structure sociale traditionnelle se trouva éclipsée. Mais les querelles concernant la terre, que l'on observe encore aujourd'hui dans les villages, laissent fortement soupçonner la persistance d'une telle structure.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © International African Institute 1980

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alpers, E. A. 1975. Ivory and Slaves in East Central Africa: Changing Patterns of International Trade to the Nineteenth Century. London: Heinemann.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balandier, G. 1968. Daily Life in the Kingdom of the Kongo: From the Sixteenth to the Eighteenth Century. London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.Google Scholar
Barnes, J. A. 1954. Politics in a Changing Society. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
CO525/1/17917, 1904. Report on Trade and General Conditions in British Central Africa 1903-04.Google Scholar
CO525/109/8947, 1924. Memorandum on Land Matters.Google Scholar
Fischer, E. 1973. Marx in His Own Words. Penguin.Google Scholar
Galeski, B. 1972. Basic Concepts of Rural Sociology. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Kandawire, J. A. K. 1977. ‘Thangata in Pre-colonial and Colonial Systems of Land Tenure in Southern Malaŵi with Special Reference to Chingale’, Africa 47(2): 185–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandawire, J. A. K. 1979. Thangata: Forced Labour or Reciprocal Assistance? a case study of the conversion of a traditional African institution into a colonial institution of production with special reference to Southern Malaŵi. Zomba: Research and Publications Committee of the University of Malaŵi.Google Scholar
Livingstone, D. & C. 1865. Narrative of an Expedition to the Zambezi and its Tributaries; and of the Discovery of the Lakes Shirwa andNyasa 1858-1864. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Malaŵi Government 1966. Malaŵi Population Census 1966: Final Report. Zomba: Government Printer.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1965. Pre-capitalist Economic Formations. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
Meillessoux, C. 1973. ‘On the Mode of Production of the Hunting Band’, in Alexandre, P. (ed) French Perspectives in African Studies: A Collection of Translated Essays. London: Oxford University Press for the International African Institute.Google Scholar
Mitchell, J. C. (a) 1949. ‘The Yao of Southern Nyasaland’, Africa XIX(2).Google Scholar
Mitchell, J. C. (b) 1949. ‘The Political Organization of the Yao of Southern Nyasaland’, African Studies, VIII(3).Google Scholar
Mitchell, J. C. 1952. ‘Preliminary notes on land tenure and Agriculture among the Machinga Yao’, Nyasaland Journal 5(2): 1830.Google Scholar
Mitchell, J. C. 1956. The Yao Village: A Study in the Social Structure of a Nyasaland Tribe. Manchester: Manchester University Press for the Rhodes-Livingstone Institute.Google Scholar
Nyasaland Government, 1955. An Outline of agrarian problems and policy in Nyasaland: memorandum laid on the table of the legislative council at its sitting on the 2nd May, 1955. Zomba, Government Printer.Google Scholar
Pike, J. G. 1968. Malaŵi: A Political and Economic History. London: Pall Mall Press.Google Scholar
Read, M. 1956. The Ngoni of Nyasaland. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rotberg, R. I. 1965. A Political History of Tropical Africa. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Stokes, E. 1966. ‘Malaŵi Political Systems and the Introduction of Colonial Rule, 1891-1896’, in Stokes, E. & Brown, R. (eds) The Zambesian Past: Studies in Central African History. Manchester: Manchester University Press for the Institute of Social Research of the University of Zambia.Google Scholar
Van Velson, J. 1966. ‘Some Early Pressure Groups in Malaŵi’, in Stokes, E. & Brown, R. (eds.) The Zambesian Past: Studies in Central African History. Manchester: Manchester University Press for the Institute for Social Research of the University of Zambia.Google Scholar
Vaughan, M. 1978. Uncontrolled Animals and Aliens: Colonial Conservation Mania in Malaŵi. Zomba: Manuscript of a History Seminar Paper at Chancellor College.Google Scholar
Worsley, P. 1956. ‘The Kinship System of the Tallensi: A Re-valuation’, Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, LXXXVI: 3775.Google Scholar