Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-m9pkr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-13T04:46:39.523Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Political Economy of Pork: Project Selection at The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

John A. Hird
Affiliation:
University of Massachusetts, Amherst

Abstract

In previous studies of distributive politics scholars have investigated legislative influence without accounting for the policies' independent merits. As a result, they have failed to include a plausible explanation of the counterfactual (i.e., which projects would have been funded in the absence of congressional committee influence), which has led to invalid inferences regarding legislative influence. The model of distributive politics is reformulated to account for an assumed efficient and/or equitable project allocation in the absence of legislative influence. Using data from proposed Army Corps of Engineers' projects and the funding recommendations of three institutions, the findings indicate that pork barrel politics indeed exists and imposes significant efficiency costs but that both equity and economic efficiency play prominent roles in the decision-making process as well. Cost-benefit analysis is seen to play a constructive role by improving the efficiency of project choice; and the corps's cost-benefit analysis guidelines are beneficial from the agency's organizational perspective, as well.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andrews, Richard N. L. 1979. Environmental Policy and Administrative Change: Implementation of the National Environmental Policy Act. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Arnold, R. Douglas. 1979. Congress and the Bureaucracy: A Theory of Influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Ashball, Bernard. 1978. The Senate Nobody Knows. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Barone, Michael, and Ujifusa, Grant. 1985. Almanac of American Politics: 1986. Washington: National Journal.Google Scholar
Barone, Michael, and Ujifusa, Grant. 1987. Almanac of American Politics: 1988. Washington: National Journal.Google Scholar
Congressional Quarterly. Congressional Quarterly Almanac. 1986. Washington: Congressional Quarterly.Google Scholar
Crandall, Robert W. 1983. Controlling Industrial Pollution: The Economics and Politics of Clean Air. Washington: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Drew, Elizabeth. 1970. “Dam Outrage: The Story of the Army Engineers.Atlantic April:5162.Google Scholar
Drew, Elizabeth. 1979. Senator. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. 1974. Pork Barrel Politics: Rivers and Harbors Legislation, 1947–1968. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Goss, Carol F. 1972. “Military Committee Membership and Defense Related Benefits in the House of Representatives.Western Political Quarterly 25:215–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1965. Water Resource Investment and the Public Interest: An Analysis of Federal Expenditures in Ten Southern States. Nashville: Vanderbilt University Press.Google Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1972. The Economic Performance of Public Investments: An Ex Post Evaluation of Water Resource Investments. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P., and Zupan, Mark A. 1984. “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.American Economic Review 74:279300.Google Scholar
Kelman, Steven. 1987. Making Public Policy: A Hopeful View of American Government. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1973. Congressmen's Voting Decisions. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1951. Muddy Waters: The Army Engineers and the Nation's Rivers. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, Christopher. 1988. Hardball: How Politics Is Played—Told by One Who Knows the Came. New York: Summit Books.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1978. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle: Democratic Committee Assignments in the Modern House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R. 1981. “Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization.American Journal of Political Science 25:96111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinberg, Bory. 1984. “Flood Damage Prevention Services of the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers.” Ph.D. diss., George Washington University.Google Scholar
Train, Kenneth. 1986. Qualitative Choice Analysis: Theory, Econometrics, and an Application to Automobile Demand. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1987. Statistical Abstract of the United States. Washington: Bureau of the Census.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Moran, Mark J. 1983. “Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission.Journal of Political Economy 91:765800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Johnsen, Christopher. 1981. “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics.Journal of Political Economy 89:624–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, David L. 1989. “Scanning Heaven and Earth for Dollars.National Journal, 18 February, p. 419.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.