Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-g5fl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-26T20:14:40.673Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Comparative Analysis of Coalition Formation and Duration: Distinguishing Between-Country and Within-Country Effect

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

Dodd is generally credited with providing clear empirical support for the proposition that, in the period after the Second World War, minimal winning coalitions in European party governments will tend to last longer in office than non-minimal winning coalitions. There has been a considerable body of research on this and related questions. Dodd, as well as most other authors treating cabinet coalition formation, has attempted to model features of cabinet formation such as cabinet duration or cabinet type (e.g. minimal winning v. minority government v. oversized coalitions) largely or entirely using data pooled from all cabinets in each of a number of different countries over some considerable time period. One difficulty with this method is that system-level variables (such as number of parties, or the presence of large anti-system parties), which might be able to explain aggregate-level between-county variations in cabinet type or cabinet durability, are not likely to be the same variables that are useful in explaining within-country differences. A second difficulty is that certain system-level characteristics such as effective number of parties or number of cleavage dimensions are highly correlated with both cabinet type and cabinet duration and, as a consequence, these variables are highly correlated with one another when pooled cross-national data are used. Thus, if the analyst is not very careful, results of pooled cross-national data may lead to mistakes about causal structure and a confusion of within-country and between-country effects.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Dodd, Lawrence D., Coalitions in Parliamentary Government (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1976).Google Scholar

2 See, for example, Warwick, Paul, ‘The Durability of Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies’, Comparative Political Studies, 11 (1979), 465–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Daalder, Hans, ‘Cabinets and Party Systems in Ten European Democracies’, Acta Politica, 6 (1971), 282303Google Scholar; Sanders, David and Herman, Valentine M., ‘The Stability and Survival of Governments in Western Democracies’, Acta Politica, 12 (1977), 346–77Google Scholar; Strom, Kaare, ‘Party Goals and Government Performance in Parliamentary Democracies’, American Political Science Review, 79 (1985), 738–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lijphart, Arend, Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-one Countries (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lijphart, Arend, ‘Measures of Cabinet Durability: A Conceptual and Empirical Evaluation’, Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 265–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lijphart, Arend, ‘A Note on the Meaning of Cabinet Durability’, Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 163–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Taylor, Michael and Herman, Valentine M., ‘Party Systems and Government Stability’, American Political Science Review, 65 (1971), 2837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 Rae, Douglas, The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, 2nd edn (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1971).Google Scholar

5 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

6 See Laakso, Marku and Taagepera, Rein, ‘Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 12 (1979), 327CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Taagepera, Rein and Grofman, Bernard, ‘Effective Size and Number of Components’, Sociological Methods and Research, 10 (1981), 63–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Taagepera, Rein and Grofman, Bernard, ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law: Predicting the Effective Number of Parties in Plurality and PR Systems – Parties Minus Issues Equals One’, European Journal of Political Research, 13 (1985), 341–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Taylor, and Herman, , ‘Party Systems’.Google Scholar

8 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

9 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

10 Dodd, , Coalitions.Google Scholar

11 Dodd, , Coalitions, p. 18.Google Scholar

12 Dodd, , Coalitions, p. 24.Google Scholar

13 Dodd, , Coalitions, pp. 28–9.Google Scholar

14 Dodd, , Coalitions.Google Scholar

15 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

16 Luebbert, G. M., Comparative Democracy: Policymaking and Governing Coalitions in Europe and Israel (New York: Columbia University Press, 1986).Google Scholar

17 Luebbert, , Comparative Democracy, pp. 85–6.Google Scholar

18 Riker, William, The Theory of Political Coalitions (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1962).Google Scholar

19 While we might propose Hypothesis 4'(b): ‘Countries with either oversized or undersized coalitions will tend to be low in cabinet durability; and cabinet durability will be least in countries where both oversized and undersized coalitions are common. In contrast, countries with minimum winning coalitions will tend to have durable cabinets’, we find that Proposition 4'(a) fits the data marginally better than Proposition 4'(b) because Iceland, Japan, Luxembourg and Belgium, which belong to cell 2 due to fractionalization, are, unlike the other countries in cell 2, not characterized by either undersized or oversized coalitions. Thus, according to Proposition 4'(b), we should expect them to have long-lived cabinets. In fact, cabinet longevity in these countries is at an intermediate level.

20 Instead of regressing the variable ‘cabinet duration’ on cabinet type, we might be better advised to regress a variable which expressed cabinet duration relative to a country's own norm against cabinet type. Pooling data for seven countries (from Finland to Israel) we obtain a correlation of 0.14 between relative cabinet duration and cabinet type compared to a correlation of 0.434 for the non-normalized bivariate relationship between cabinet duration and cabinet type. Thus, this line of approach does not seem promising.

21 For an alternative approach see Taagepera, Rein, ‘Reformulating the Cube Law for Proportional Representation Elections’, American Political Science Review, 80 (1986), 489504CrossRefGoogle Scholar, which proposes a new model to account for parameter values of a posited non-linear relationship.

22 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

23 Taagepera, and Grofman, , ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law’Google Scholar; Sartori, Giovanni, ‘The Influence of Electoral Systems: Faulty Laws or Faulty Method?’ in Grofman, B. and Lijphart, A., eds, Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences (New York: Agathon Press, 1986).Google Scholar

24 See Schattschneider, E. E., The Semi-Sovereign People (New York: Holt, Rinehart, 1968).Google Scholar

25 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

26 Taagepera, and Grofman, , ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law’.Google Scholar

27 Taagepera, , ‘Reformulating the Cube Law’.Google Scholar

28 Taagepera, and Grofman, , ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law’; (personal communication, 02 1987).Google Scholar

29 See Duverger, Maurice, ‘The Influence of Electoral Systems on Political Life’, International Social Science Bulletin, 3 (1951), 314–52Google Scholar; Duverger, Maurice, ‘Duverger's Law: Forty Years Later’Google Scholar, in Grofman, and Lijphart, , eds, Electoral Laws and Their Political ConsequencesGoogle Scholar; Riker, William, ‘The Two-Party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science’, American Political Science Review, 76 (1982), 753–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Sartori, Giovanni, ‘Political Development and Political Engineering’, Public Policy, 17 (1968), 261–98.Google Scholar

30 Taagepera, and Grofman, , ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law’.Google Scholar

31 Lijphart, , Democracies.Google Scholar

32 There are other ways in which the cabinet duration variable might have been operationalized, but it is not likely that such differences would have affected our results (see Lijphart, , ‘Measures of Cabinet Durability’).Google Scholar However, like Lijphart, (‘A Note on the Meaning of Cabinet Durability’)Google Scholar, I would caution against ‘the facile assumption that cabinet durability necessarily spells regime stability’ in some broader meaning of the latter term. Like Lijphart, I find cabinet duration to be a variable of sufficient intrinsic interest to be worthy of study.

33 Lijphart, Arend, Bruneau, Thomas C., Diamandouros, P. Nikifors and Gunther, Richard, ‘A Mediterranean Model of Democracy: The Southern European Democracies in Comparative Perspective’, West European Politics, 11 (1988), 725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 See Lijphart, , DemocraciesGoogle Scholar; Luebbert, , Comparative DemocracyGoogle Scholar; and Schofield, Norman, ‘Coalitions in West European Democracies: 1945–1986’, in Schofield, N., ed., Coalition Models (Boston, Mass.: Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1989, forthcoming).Google Scholar

35 Taagepera, , ‘Reformulating the Cube Law’.Google Scholar

36 See also Blondel, Jean, ‘Party Systems and Patterns of Government in Western Democracies’, Canadian Journal of Political Science, 1 (1968), 180203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

37 If I replaces C, and with D (as usual) the dependent variable, we obtain a multivariate equation with I, MWC and P which has a multiple correlation of 0.77. If the mean vote share of the largest party replaces N (with data for twenty countries, 1945–80, from Midlarski, Manus, ‘Political Stability of Two-Party and Multiparty Systems: Probabilistic Bases for the Comparison of Party Systems’, American Political Science Review, 78 (1984), 929–57, p. 944)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, we obtain a multiple correlation of 0.8, again with P as the second significant variable. If mean total number of parties in the legislature replaces N (data for eighteen countries for the period 1964–74 taken from Mayer, , ‘Party Systems and Government Stability’, in Merkl, Peter H., ed., Western European Party Systems: Trends and Prospects (New York: Free Press, 1980), pp. 335–57, p. 342)Google Scholar, we obtain a multiple correlation of 0.77, with i rather than P as the second significant variable. In a stepwise regression with eight independent variables available, N and P are the two variables which enter as significant at an F cutoff of 2.0.

38 See Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John and Gleiber, Dennis, ‘An “Events” Approach to the Problem of Cabinet Stability’, Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 167–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John and Gleiber, Dennis, ‘Dissolution of Governments in Scandinavia: A Critical Events Perspective’, Scandinavian Political Studies, 9 (1986), 93110CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John and Gleiber, Dennis, ‘The Process of Cabinet Dissolution: An Exponential Model of Duration and Stability in Western Democracies’, American Journal of Political Science, 30 (1986), 628–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ciofli-Revilla, Claudio, ‘The Political Reliability of Italian Government: An Exponential Survival Model’, American Political Science Review, 78 (1984), 318–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Frendreis, John P., ‘Dennis Gleiber and Eric C. Browne, The Study of Cabinet Dissolutions in Parliamentary Democracies’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 11 (1986), 619–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

39 See Robertson, John D., ‘The Political Economy and the Durability of European Coalition Cabinets: New Variations on a Game-Theoretic Perspective’, Journal of Politics, 45 (1983), 933–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Robertson, John D., ‘Toward a Political-Economic Accounting of the Endurance of Cabinet Administrations: An Empirical Assessment of Eight European Democracies’, American Journal of Political Science, 28 (1984), 693709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 McKelvey, Richard, ‘Covering, Dominance, and Institution Free Properties of Social Choice’, American Journal of Political Science, 30 (1986), 283315CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Ferejohn, J. A., McKelvey, R. D. and Packel, E. W., ‘Limiting Distributions for Continuous State Markov Models’, Social Choice and Welfare, 1 (1984), 4567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

41 Feld, Scott L., Grofman, Bernard, Hartley, Richard, Kilgour, Mark O. and Miller, Nicholas, ‘The Uncovered Set in Spatial Voting Games’, Theory and Decision, 23 (1987), 129–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Feld, Scott L., Grofman, Bernard and Miller, Nicholas R., ‘Limits of Agenda Control in Spatial Voting Games’, Mathematical Modelling (1988, forthcoming).Google Scholar

42 See Schofield, Norman, Grofman, Bernard and Feld, Scott L., ‘The Core and Stability of Group Choice in Spatial Voting Games’, American Political Science Review, 82 (1988), 196211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

43 Schofeld, , Grofman, and Feld, , ‘The Core and Stability’.Google Scholar

44 Taagepera, and Grofman, , ‘Effective Size’Google Scholar; ‘Rethinking Duverger's Law’. Taagepera, , ‘The Inverse Square Law’Google Scholar, offers a similar sort of explanation, although its inspiration is not in game theoretic models but in terms of his own earlier work on seats-votes relationships (see Taagepera, , ‘Reformulating the Cube Law’).Google Scholar

45 See Budge, Ian and Laver, Michael, ‘Party, Ideology and Party Distance: Analysis of Election Programmes in 19 Democracies’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 11 (1986), 607–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Budge, Ian, Robertson, David and Hearl, Derek, eds, Ideology, Strategy and Party Movement: A Comparative Analysis of a Post-war Election Programme in Nineteen Democracies (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987).CrossRefGoogle Scholar