Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-rvbq7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-09T18:31:49.342Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Steering the Ship of State: One Tiller but Two Pairs of Hands

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

Policy-making reflects the combined activity of both politicians and higher civil servants; both have their hands on the tiller of the ship of state. But they approach problems of governing from different perspectives – partisan or bureaucratic – and each has a different contribution to make. This article considers six models of the relationship, varying according to inputs of political will and the probability of programmes achieving success. They are: willpower dominates; perfectly informed trade-offs; everything is uncertain; everything is predetermined; capture by civil servants; and policies dominate. The analysis emphasizes that there is a greater need for changes in the knowledge and behaviour of politicians in office than for further reform of the civil service.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1987

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 The Greek word kubernetes is the root of the Latin word gubernare and of the English word ‘govern’, as well as of the word cybernetics. For the quotation, see Deutsch, Karl W., The Nerves of Government (New York: Free Press, 1966), p. xxviii.Google Scholar For a view of politics as simply ‘a boundless and bottomless sea’, where the only aim is to keep afloat, see Oakeshott, Michael, Political Education (Cambridge: Bowes & Bowes, 1951), p. 22.Google Scholar

2 Aberbach, Joel D. and Rockman, Bert A., The Administrative State in Industrialized Democracies (Washington, DC: American Political Science Association, 1986), p. 7.Google Scholar For a classic discussion, see ‘Politics as a Vocation’ and ‘Bureaucracy’ in Gerth, H. W. and Mills, C. W., eds, From Max Weber, (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1948).Google Scholar

3 For survey data documenting differences, see Aberbach, Joel D., Putnam, Robert D. and Rockman, Bert A., Bureaucrats and Politicians in Western Democracies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1981).Google Scholar For institutional and career differences (and sometimes overlaps), see the national studies in two volumes edited by Suleiman, Ezra, Bureaucrats and Policy Making (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1984)Google Scholar, and Parliaments and Parliamentarians in Democratic Politics (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1986).Google Scholar

4 Wilson, Woodrow, ‘The Science of Administration’, Political Science Quarterly, II (1887), 209f.Google Scholar

5 Although the comments may seem platitudinous, their assertion in the wake of a decision of a civil servant, Clive Ponting, to claim a duty to Parliament above that of his responsibility to a Minister, was controversial. Cf. ‘The Duties and Responsibilities of Civil Servants in Relation to Ministers’ (London: Cabinet Office, duplicated, 25 02 1985)Google Scholar; Norton-Taylor, Richard, The Ponting Affair (London: Cecil Woolf, 1985)Google Scholar; and Rose, Richard, A House Divided: Political Administration in Britain Today (Glasgow: University of Strathclyde Studies in Public Policy No. 158, 1986).Google Scholar

6 For an early statement, see Rose, Richard, The Problem of Party Government (London: Macmillan, 1974), especially pp. 429ff.CrossRefGoogle Scholar For a recent analysis systematically applying Weberian concepts imaginatively and comparatively, see Page, Edward C., Political Authority and Bureaucratic Power (Brighton: Wheatsheaf, 1985).Google Scholar

7 Heclo, Hugh and Wildavsky, Aaron, The Private Government of Public Money (London: Macmillan, 1974)Google Scholar; Aberbach, et al. , Bureaucrats and Politicians in Western Democracies, pp. 916Google Scholar; and Ronge, Volker, ‘The Politicization of Administration in Advanced Capitalist Societies’, Political Studies, XXII (1974), 8693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 The locus classicus is the Fulton Committee, Report: The Civil Service (London: HMSO, Cmnd. 3638, 1968)Google Scholar. For an American example, see Heclo, Hugh, A Government of Strangers: Executive Politics in Washington (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1977).Google Scholar

9 ‘Bureaucracy’, in From Max Weber, p. 232.Google Scholar

10 See Rose, Richard, ‘Giving Direction to Civil Servants: Signals from the Law, Expertise, the Market and the Electorate’, in Lane, Jan-Erik, ed., Bureaucracy and Public Choice (London: Sage Publications, in press).Google Scholar

11 For a review of Marxist writings, see, for example, Etzioni-Halevy, Eva, Bureaucracy and Democracy (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983), especially Chaps 1 and 6Google Scholar. On right-wing American distrust, see, for example, Nathan, Richard, The Administrative Presidency (New York: John Wiley, rev. edition, 1983).Google Scholar

12 See Kingdon, John W., Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies (Boston: Little, Brown, 1984).Google Scholar

13 See, for example, the comments by Messarra, Antoine Nasri, ‘Arab Political Science in Search of its Authenticity’, Participation, X (1986), p. 12Google Scholar. Cf. Rose, Richard and Garvin, Tom, ‘The Public Policy Effects of Independence: Ireland as a Test Case’, European Journal of Political Research, XI (1983), 377–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 Deutsch, , The Nerves of Government, pp. 246f.Google Scholar

15 See Oakeshott, Michael's denunciation of ‘the illusion that in politics there is anywhere a safe harbour, a destination to be reached’ in Political Education, p. 28Google Scholar. Oakeshott confuses the inability to reach a destination with the fact that it may none the less be a goal to steer towards, and for use in telling whether one is closer to or further from a desired goal.

16 See Aberbach, Joel D. and Rockman, Bert A., ‘Clashing Beliefs within the Executive Branch: the Nixon Administration Bureaucracy’, American Political Science Review, LXX (1976), 456–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 Hood, C. C., The Limits of Administration (Chichester, Sussex: Wiley, 1976).Google Scholar

18 Sir Armstrong, William, The Role and Character of the Civil Service (London: Oxford University Press for the British Academy, 1970), p. 13fGoogle Scholar; Bancroft, Lord, ‘Memorandum’, Treasury and Civil Service Committee, Civil Servants and Ministers: Duties and Responsibilities (London: HMSO, HC 92–II, 1986), p. 245.Google Scholar

19 See Weaver, R. Kent, ‘The Politics of Blame Avoidance’, Journal of Public Policy, VI (1986), 371–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Braybrooke, David and Lindblom, C. E., A Strategy of Decision (New York: Free Press, 1963)Google Scholar. Cf. Dunsire, Andrew, ‘A Cybernetic View of Guidance, Control and Evaluation in the Public Sector’, in Kaufmann, Franz Xavier, Majone, G., Ostrom, V., eds, Guidance, Control and Evaluation in the Public Sector (Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter, 1986), pp. 327–46.Google Scholar

21 Cf. Pressman, Jeffrey and Wildavsky, Aaron, Implementation (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1973)Google Scholar, and Bowen, Elinor, ‘The Pressman-Wildavsky Paradox’, Journal of Public Policy, II (1982), 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

22 See Wildavsky, Aaron, ‘The Self-Evaluating Organization’, Public Administration Review, 09/10 (1972)Google Scholar; Rose, Richard, Managing Presidential Objectives (New York: Free Press, 1976), Chap. 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 Cf. Cohen, M. D., March, J. G. and Olsen, J. P., ‘A Garbage Can Model of Organizational Choice’, Administrative Science Quarterly, XVII (1972), 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

24 Diamant, Alfred, ‘Tradition and Innovation in French Administration’, Comparative Political Studies, I (1968), pp. 251–74, p. 255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

25 See Rose, Richard and Karran, Terence, ‘Inertia or Incrementalism?’ in Groth, A. and Wade, L. L., eds, Comparative Resource Allocation (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1984), pp. 4371Google Scholar; and Rose, Richard and Karran, Terence, Taxation by Political Inertia (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1987).Google Scholar

26 Mayhew, David, Congress: the Electoral Connection (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1974), pp. 49ff.Google Scholar

27 For a good discussion of the differences between the two, see Peters, B. Guy, The Relationship between Civil Servants and Political Executives (Glasgow: University of Strathclyde Studies in Public Policy No. 153, 1986), pp. 10ff.Google Scholar

28 See, for example, national chapters in Suleiman, , Bureaucrats and Policy Making: Meyers, François, ed., La Politisation de l'Administration (Brussels: Institut International des Sciences Administratives, 1985)Google Scholar; and Bruce Smith, L. R., ed., The Higher Civil Service in Europe and Canada: Lessons for the United States (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1984).Google Scholar

29 See evidence and questions in Treasury and Civil Service Committee, Civil Servants and MinistersGoogle Scholar; Working Group Report, Top Jobs in Whitehall (London: Royal Institute of Public Administration, 1987).Google Scholar

30 See, for example, Leadership in Jeopardy (Washington, D.C.: National Academy of Public Administration Presidential Appointee Project, 1985)Google Scholar; Moe, Terry, ‘The Politicized Presidency’, in Chubb, John E. and Peterson, Paul E., eds, The New Direction in American Politics (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1985), pp. 235–72.Google Scholar

31 See the wide-ranging discussion on the relationship between will and technical skills in the Soviet Union and alternative interpretations of this relationship, in Amann, Ronald, ‘Searching for an Appropriate Concept of Soviet Polities’, British Journal of Political Science, XVI (1986), 475–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

32 For an excellent discussion of research findings on this topic, including implications for other countries, see Page, Edward C., Political Authority and Bureaucratic Power (Brighton: Wheatsheaf, 1985), pp. 55ff.Google Scholar

33 Sanera, Michael, ‘Implementing the Mandate’, in Butler, S. M., Sanera, M. and Weinrod, W. B., eds, Mandate for Leadership: Continuing the Conservative Revolution (Washington, D.C.: Heritage Foundation, 1984), pp. 459.Google Scholar

34 Quoted in Blumenthal, Sidney, ‘Building a conservative elite: after Reagan true believers will still be in place’, Washington Post, National Weekly Edition, 14 10 1985.Google Scholar

33 On the small number of special advisers – and the fact that many ministers prefer to do without any – see the evidence in Treasury and Civil Service Committee, Civil Servants and Ministers (Vol. II), pp. lilivGoogle Scholar. On their roles, see Klein, Rudolf and Lewis, Janet, ‘Advice and Dissent in British Government’, Policy and Politics, V (1977).Google Scholar

36 For different views of cabinets, see for example, Civil Servants and Ministers: Duties and Responsibilities (Vols. I, II)Google Scholar, passim, and Top Jobs in Whitehall, appendix by Ella Searls.

37 Peters, , The Relationship between Civil Servants and Political Executives, pp. 7ff.Google Scholar

38 The typology is derived from that developed by Theodore R. Marmor, with Fellman, Philip, ‘Policy Entrepreneurship in Government’, Journal of Public Policy, VI (1986), Table 1Google Scholar. It differs in substituting a more general term, programme capacity, for his narrower term, managerial skills, and in the labelling of some alternatives. For example, in the Washington context Marmor sees people who have been career bureaucrats as the most likely policy entrepreneurs, a position that might also be congenial to French graduates of ENA, especially those who become ministers.

39 On the extent to which the distribution of roles diners as between national political systems, see Peters, , The Relationship between Civil Servants and Political Executives, pp. 15ffGoogle Scholar, and Aberbach, and Rockman, , The Administrative State in Industrialized Democracies, passim.Google Scholar

40 Cf. Marmor, , ‘Policy Entrepreneurship in Government’Google Scholar; Heclo, Hugh, ‘Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment’, in King, Anthony, ed., The New American Political System (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1978), pp. 87124Google Scholar; and Pempel, T. J., ‘Organizing for Efficiency: the Higher Civil Service in Japan’Google Scholar, in Suleiman, , ed., Bureaucrats and Policy Making, pp. 72106.Google Scholar

41 See, for example, Suleiman, Ezra, ‘Presidential Government in France’, in Rose, R. and Suleiman, E., eds, Presidents and Prime Ministers (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1980), pp. 94138Google Scholar; de Baecque, F. and Quermonne, J-L., Administration et politiques sous la Ve République (Paris: Presses de la Fondation Nationale des Sciences Politiques, 1981).Google Scholar

42 See Rose, RichardMinisters and Ministries: A functional Analysis (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987), especially Chap. 4.Google Scholar

43 See, for example, Blondel, Jean, Government Ministers in the Contemporary World (London: Sage Publications, 1985)Google Scholar, Appendix II; and Headey, Bruce W., British Cabinet Ministers (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1974).Google Scholar

44 See Rose, Richard, ‘The Making of Cabinet Ministers’, British Journal of Political Science, 1 (1971), 393414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

45 It is arguable that in a hung Parliament, policymaking would become more open, conceivably giving Commons' committees substantial importance (see Marsh, Ian, Policy Making in a Three Party System (London: Methuen, 1986))Google Scholar. But it can also be argued that the inter-party deliberations of a coalition government are more likely to encourage horse-trading and log-rolling for votes, as in the United States Congress, rather than the development of programme capacity.

46 The comparison is further flawed by the fact that the American in-and-outer starts out as a politician, typically entering the executive branch at a junior but strategically significant post when young, going out of government to acquire additional skills and resources for later use when he comes back into government at a higher level. The analogy, if there be one, is with British ministers – albeit that a British M P spends time out of executive office in the purgatory of the Opposition benches of the House of Commons.

47 See Kernell, Samuel, Going Public: New Strategies of Presidential Leadership (Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press, 1986)Google Scholar; and Rose, Richard, ‘Learning to Govern or Learning to Campaign?’, in Nelson, Michael and Heard, Alexander, eds, Presidential Selection (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, in press).Google Scholar

48 Rose, Richard, Do Parties Make a Difference? (London: Macmillan, 2nd edn, 1984).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

49 Oakeshott, , Political Education, p. 11.Google Scholar