Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-cjp7w Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-29T09:23:30.804Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Floods and money: funding drainage and flood control in coastal Flanders from the thirteenth to the sixteenth centuries

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2011

TIM SOENS
Affiliation:
University of Antwerp, Belgium.

Abstract

From the High Middle Ages on, the coastal wetlands of the North Sea area have been intensively reclaimed and settled. In order to enable intensive agricultural production in these areas, a complex drainage and flood control system was gradually installed, one that demanded a permanent investment of huge amounts of capital and labour. As the maintenance of the water control system was vital for the coastal agro-system, the long-term evolution of investments is an important, yet rarely used, indicator of the economic, social and environmental fortunes of the coastlands. Based on new and very early serial data on water control funding in late medieval Flanders, this article argues that long-term fluctuations in the funding of drainage and flood control were first and foremost related to structural changes within the coastal economy, where an overall decline of investment levels ran parallel to the fourteenth-century crisis of the peasant smallholding economy in this region. Exogenous pressures on the other hand, such as storm surges, only provoked a short-term disruption of investments.

Inondations et gros sous: financement du drainage et prévention des inondations en flandre côtière du xiiie au xvie siècle

Depuis le Haut Moyen Âge, les zones côtières de la mer du Nord ont été constamment regagnées et occupées. Afin de permettre une production agricole intensive dans ces secteurs, un système de drainage complexe a été progressivement installé, accompagné d'un contrôle des inondations. Ce système exigeait un investissement permanent en capitaux colossaux et en travail. Comme l'entretien du système de contrôle de l'eau était vital pour le fonctionnement du mode de production agricole côtier, l'évolution à long terme des investissements est un indicateur important, bien que rarement utilisé, de la situation économique, sociale et environnementale des zones du littoral. Le présent article repose sur des séries statistiques encore inédites et commençant fort tôt, concernant le financement de la maîtrise de l'eau en Flandre au Bas Moyen Age. Il montre que les fluctuations à long terme dans le financement du drainage et de la lutte contre les inondations ont été d'abord, et avant tout, liées à des changements structurels dans l'économie du littoral: une diminution globale des niveaux d'investissement se produisit en parallèle à la crise du XIVe siècle qui frappa, dans cette région, l'économie des petits paysans. Par contre, les contraintes exogènes, comme les grandes tempêtes, ne provoquaient qu'une perturbation à court terme des investissements.

Flut und geld: die finanzierung der entwässerung und flutkontrolle in den küstenregionen flanderns vom 13. bis zum 16. jahrhundert

Die Feuchtgebiete an der Nordseeküste sind vom Hochmittelalter an in großem Umfang trockengelegt und besiedelt worden. Um in diesen Regionen eine intensive landwirtschaftliche Produktion zu ermöglichen, wurde nach und nach ein komplexes Entwässerungs- und Flutkontrollsystem aufgebaut, das ständige und umfangreiche Investitionen an Kapital und Arbeitskraft erforderte. Da die Instandhaltung des Wasserkontrollsystems für das Agrarsystem der Küstenregion geradezu lebensnotwendig war, stellt die langfristige Entwicklung der Investitionen einen wichtigen – wenn auch selten genutzten – Indikator für die ökonomischen, sozialen und umweltbedingten Geschicke der Küstenregionen dar. Auf der Basis neuer und sehr früher serieller Daten zur Finanzierung der Wasserkontrolle im spätmittelalterlichen Flandern vertritt dieser Beitrag die Auffassung, dass die langfristigen Fluktuationen der Aufwendungen für Entwässerung und Flutkontrolle in allererster Linie von den strukturellen Veränderungen innerhalb der Küstenwirtschaft beeinflusst wurden. Dabei verlief der Rückgang der Investitionshöhe parallel zur Krise der kleinbäuerlichen Wirtschaft dieser Region im 14. Jahrhundert, während exogene Belastungen wie z.B. Sturmfluten nur kurzfristige Unterbrechungen der Investitionen hervorriefen.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

ENDNOTES

1 M. Bailey, ‘Per impetum maris: natural disaster and economic decline in eastern England, 1275–1350’, in B. M. S. Campbell ed., Before the Black Death (Manchester, 1991), 184–208; A. Gross and A. Butcher, ‘Adaptation and investment in the age of the great storms: agricultural policy on the manors of the principal lords of the Romney Marshes and the Marshland fringe, c. 1250–1320’, in J. Eddison ed., Romney Marsh. The debatable ground, Oxford University Committee for Archaeology Monograph, no. 41 (Oxford, 1995), 107–17.

2 A. de Kraker, , ‘Flood events in the southwestern Netherlands and coastal Belgium, 1400–1953’, Hydrological Sciences 51, 5 (2006), 913–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rohr, C., ‘Measuring the frequency and intensity of floods of the Traun River (Upper Austria) 1441–1574’, Hydrological Sciences 51, 5 (2006), 834–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 For example, M. Jakubowski–Tiessen, Sturmflut 1717. Die Bewältigung einer Naturkatastrophe in der frühen Neuzeit (Munich, 1992); Mauelshagen, F., ‘Flood disasters and political culture at the German North Sea coast: a long term historical perspective’, Historical Social Research 32 (2007), 133–44Google Scholar.

4 For example, the Dutch ‘Delta’ project after the disastrous 1953 flood or more recently, large-scale initiatives taken in the aftermath of 2005 Hurricane Katrina in New Orleans or the 2006 Tsunami in South-East Asia.

5 Coombes, P. and Barber, K., ‘Environmental determinism in Holocene research: causality or coincidence’, Area 37, 3 (2005), 303–11CrossRefGoogle Scholar; G. Endfield, ‘Reconsidering climate and causality: case studies from colonial Mexico’, in S. Sörlin and P. Warde eds., Nature's end. History and the environment (Basingstoke, 2009), 304–6.

6 T. Steinberg, Acts of God. The unnatural history of natural disaster in America (Oxford, 2006); various contributions in G. Massard-Guilbaud, D. Schott and H. Platt eds., Cities and catastrophes: coping with emergency in European history (Frankfurt am Main, 2002); C. Pfister and C. Mauch eds., Natural disasters, cultural responses: case studies towards a global environmental history (Lexington, 2009).

7 de Kraker, ‘Flood events’, 917–18; 925–6; A. J. Long, J. B. Innes, J. R. Kirby, J. M. Lloyd, M. M. Rutherford, I. Shennan and Tooley, M. J., ‘Holocene sea-level change and coastal evolution in the Humber estuary, eastern England: an assessment of rapid coastal change’, The Holocene 8, 2 (1998), 229–47Google Scholar; Behre, K. E., ‘Coastal development, sea-level change and settlement history during the later Holocene in the Clay District of Lower Saxony (Niedersachsen), northern Germany’, Quarternary International 112 (2004), 3753CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here 49; Knox, J. C., ‘Large increases in flood magnitude in response to modest changes in climate’, Nature 361, 6411 (1993), 430–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Holderness, B. A., ‘Landlord's capital formation in East Anglia 1750–1870’, Economic History Review 25 (1972), 434–47Google Scholar; Hilton, R., ‘Rent and capital formation in feudal society’, in Second International Conference of Economic History: Aix-en-Provence (Paris, 1965), vol. 2, 3868Google Scholar; B. Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture 1250–1450 (Cambridge, 2000), 14.

9 Brenner, R., ‘The agrarian roots of European capitalism’, Past and Present 97 (1982), 103CrossRefGoogle Scholar; R. Brenner, ‘The Low Countries in the transition to capitalism’, in P. Hoppenbrouwers and J. L. van Zanden eds., Peasants into farmers? The transformation of rural economy and society in the Low Countries (Middle Ages–19th century) in light of the Brenner debate, CORN Publication Series 4 (Turnhout, 2001), 187–8.

10 J. de Vries, The Dutch rural economy in the Golden Age, 1500–1700 (New Haven, 1974), 196; J. de Vries, ‘The transition to capitalism in a land without feudalism’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 78.

11 R. C. Allen, Enclosure and the yeoman (Oxford, 1992), 191–210.

12 McCloskey, D., ‘The prudent peasant: new findings on open fields’, Journal of Economic History 51, 2 (1992), 343–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13 T. Soens, ‘Explaining deficiencies of water management in the late medieval Flemish coastal plain, 13th–16th centuries’, Jaarboek voor Ecologische Geschiedenis, 35–61; M. K. E. Gottschalk, Storm surges and river floods in the Netherlands (Assen, 1971–1977), 3 vols.

14 T. Soens and E. Thoen, ‘The origins of leasehold in the former county of Flanders’, in B. J. P. Van Bavel and P. R. Schofield eds., The development of leasehold in Northwestern Europe, c. 1200–1600, CORN Publication Series 10 (Turnhout, 2008), 31–56.

15 E. Thoen, ‘“Social agrosystems” as an economic concept to explain regional differences. An essay taking the former county of Flanders as an example (Middle Ages–19th Century)’, in B. J. P. van Bavel and P. Hoppenbrouwers eds., Landholding and land transfer in the North Sea area (late Middle Ages–19th century), CORN Publication Series 5 (Turnhout, 2004), 47–66; P. van Cruyningen, Behoudend maar buigzaam. Boeren in West-Zeeuws-Vlaanderen 1650–1850, AAG Bijdragen 40 (Wageningen, 2000).

16 T. Soens, ‘Threatened by the sea, condemned by man? Flood risk and environmental inequalities along the North Sea coast (1200–1800 AD)’, in G. Massard-Guilbaud and R. Rodger eds., Environmental and social inequalities in the city. Historical perspectives (Cambridge, 2011), 91–111.

17 T. Soens, De spade in de dijk? Waterbeheer en rurale samenleving in de Vlaamse kustvlakte (1280–1580), Historische Economie en Ecologie (Ghent, 2009), 17–57.

18 De Moor, T., ‘The silent revolution: a new perspective on the emergence of commons, guilds and other forms of collective action in Western Europe’, The International Review of Social History 53 (2008) 16, 114CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 S. Ciriacono, Building on water. Venice, Holland and the construction of the European landscape in early modern times (New York, 2006), 196–250.

20 H. C. Darby, The changing fenland (Cambridge, 1983), 36–56. For a recent reappreciation: Knittl, M. A., ‘The design for the initial drainage of the Great Level of the Fens: an historical whodunit in three parts’, Agricultural History Review 55, 1 (2007), 2350Google Scholar.

21 Soens, Spade in de dijk, Appendix. Today, the Flemish coastal plain stretching from Calais in northern France to the Western Scheldt estuary in the north covers about 250,000 hectares of land: my sample thus represents about 65% of the coastal wetlands within the castellany of Bruges and about 25% of coastal Flanders. The latter data are based on the actual size of the coastal water districts in the Belgian provinces of West-Vlaanderen (99,783 hectares of coastal lands); Oost-Vlaanderen (54,238 hectares); in Zeeland-Flanders (73,150 hectares) and in Northern France (Départements du Nord et du Pas de Calais), estimated at about 30,000 hectares. Source www.vvpw.be (Flemish association of Polders and Wateringues) and http://www.wszv.nl/ (Water District Zeeuws-Vlaanderen).

22 M. Boone, Geld en macht. De Gentse stadsfinanciën en de Bourgondische staatsvorming (1384–1453) (Ghent, 1990), table 6.

23 P. Stabel, Dwarfs among giants. The Flemish urban network in the late Middle Ages (Leuven-Apeldoorn, 1997), 37–8; budgets estimated by T. Soens based on the respective city accounts.

24 Soens, T., ‘Evolution et gestion du domaine comtal en Flandre sous Louis de Male et Philippe le Hardi (1346–1404)’, Revue-du Nord-Histoire 83, 1 (2001), 2563CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 The average wheat price of 54.7 denarii groten per hoet of 172 litres in 1400–1409 is based on A. Verhulst, ‘Prijzen van granen, boter en kaas te Brugge volgens de “slag” van het Sint-Donatiaanskapittel (1348–1801)’, in C. Verlinden and E. Scholliers eds., Dokumenten voor de geschiedenis van prijzen en lonen in Vlaanderen en Brabant. Deel II (Bruges, 1965), 34.

26 See Appendix: from 1400 to 1409, an unskilled labourer engaged in maintenance works on the water control system was paid 4 to 5 d. groten a day.

27 J. Mertens, De laat-middeleeuwse landbouweconomie in enkele gemeenten van het Brugse Vrije (Bruges, 1970), 77–9.

28 H. Werveke, Van, ‘Currency manipulation in the Middle Ages. The case of Louis de Male, count of Flanders’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society (Fourth Series) 31 (1949), 115–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Munro, J., ‘Mint policies, ratios, and outputs in England and the Low Countries, 1335–420: some reflections on new data’, The Numismatic Chronicle 141 (1981), 110–11Google Scholar.

29 B. van Bavel, , ‘Rural wage labour in the sixteenth century Low Countries: an assessment of the importance and nature of wage labour in the countryside of Holland, Guelders and Flanders’, Continuity and Change 21, 1 (2006), 42–3Google Scholar and 62; P. Van Dam, ‘Digging for a dike. Holland's labour market ca. 1510’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 222–4.

30 Account of the Blankenbergse Watering 1293–1294, edited by M. Gysseling, Corpus van Middelnederlandse teksten. Reeks I ambtelijke bescheiden (Den Haag, 1977), nr. 1329: ‘Operarii de feria sexta post medium aprilem usque translationem Beati Thome DC XXVI man dachwerc pro die VII s. d.: summa 19 l. 11 s. 3 d. Item operarii de translatione Beati Thome usque festum Beati Mathei CCCCLIX man dachwerc pro die IX d. summa 17 l. 4 s. 3 d. … Johanni Fachelare de bedrivene dikers & operarios CXVII dies pro die XII d., summa 5 l. 17 s’.

31 E. Thoen, Landbouwekonomie en bevolking in Vlaanderen gedurende de late Middeleeuwen en het begin van de Moderne Tijden. Test-regio: de kasselrijen van Oudenaarde en Aalst (Gent, 1988), 1318–24.

32 J. Murray, Bruges, cradle of capitalism. 1280–1390 (Cambridge, 2005), 177.

33 Gysseling, Account of the Blankenbergse Watering 1293–1294.

34 The silver content of the Flemish d. groten stabilised during the long reign of Phillip the Good of Burgundy (1419–1467). Afterwards the d. groten depreciated from about 0.7 to about 0.5 grams of silver in the first decades of the sixteenth century; see also Munro, J., ‘Wage stickiness, monetary changes, and real incomes in late-medieval England and the Low Countries, 1300–1500: did money matter?’, Research in Economic History 21 (2003), 185297CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 B. Augustyn, ‘De landschapsgeschiedenis van de Lage Moer van Meetkerke (13de–20ste eeuw)’, in E. Huys and M. Vandermaesen eds., Polders en wateringen. Studiedag georganiseerd te Damme op 19 mei 2000 (Brussels, 2001), 55–64.

36 N. Vanslembrouck, Thoen, E. and Lehouck, A., ‘Past landscapes and present-day techniques. Reconstructing submerged medieval landscapes in the western part of Sealand Flanders’, Landscape History 27 (2005), 518Google Scholar.

37 B. Augustyn, ‘Evolution of the dune ecosystem in Flanders during the Middle Ages: anthropogenic factors versus sea level change theory’, available on http://www.armara.be/augustyn/dune-ecosystem.htm [last accessed on 6 June 2011].

38 Thoen, Landbouwekonomie, 1318–1324. A further article on this subject is being prepared by E. Thoen and T. Soens.

39 Gross and Butcher, ‘Adaptation and investment’, 116.

40 S. Wade Martins and Williamson, T., ‘Labour and improvement: agricultural change in East Anglia, circa 1750–1870’, Labour History Review 62, 3 (1997), 277–9Google Scholar.

41 P. van Dam, , ‘Ecological challenges, technological innovations. The modernization of sluice building in Holland, 1300–1600’, Technology and Culture 43, 3 (2002), 499520CrossRefGoogle Scholar; K. Davids, ‘Technological change and the economic expansion of the Dutch Republic, 1580–1680’, in K. Davids and L. Noordegraaf eds., The Dutch economy in the Golden Age (Amsterdam, 1993), 79–104.

42 The yearly coefficient of variation of water taxes in the Blankenbergse Watering, converted into silver evolves from 83.8% between 1280 and 1350 to 58.0% between 1351 and 1425; 50.3% from 1426 to 1530 and 40.4% from 1531 to 1580.

43 Bruges, State Archives [hereafter BSA], Blankenbergse Watering, 334: account of the contractor Jan Barbesaen for the year 1476–1477. The contractor – belonging to a wealthy family from Bruges – received 60 l. groten a year to be spent on maintenance work, mainly of ditches and roads. Already in 1433 the same water board had negotiated a similar agreement with a contractor for the duration of three years: Bruges, Archives of the Public Welfare Centre [hereafter BAPW], Blankenbergse Watering, box 8 (old number 1A).

44 BAPW, Wateringen, box 11 (old number 2B).

45 BAPW, St John's Hospital, Accounts of the hospital 1444–1463.

46 BSA, Blankenbergse Watering, 339, account of 1570–1577.

47 Ordinary revenues in the period 1549–1570 amounted to 944 l. groten a year on average, while the total burden of interest on the loans contracted in 1570 did not exceed 71 l.

48 For Flanders, see T. Faes, De zeewering tussen Blankenberge en Oostende in de moderne tijden (unpublished MA thesis, Ghent, 1966); for Holland, see P. Van Dam and M. Van Tielhof, Waterstaat in Stedenland. Het Hoogheemraadschap van Rijnland voor 1857 (Utrecht, 2006), 238.

49 Galloway, J. A. and Potts, J. S., ‘Marine flooding in the Thames estuary and tidal river c.1250–1450: impact and response’, Area 39 (2007), 370–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Galloway, J. A., ‘Storm flooding, coastal defence and land use around the Thames estuary and tidal river c.1250–1450’, Journal of Medieval History 35, 2 (2009), 171–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Hilton, ‘Rent and capital formation’, 35.

51 Bavel, B. J. P. Van, ‘Land, lease and agriculture: the transition of the rural economy in the Dutch river area from the fourteenth to the sixteenth century’, Past and Present 172 (2001), 30Google Scholar. On the manors of Canterbury Cathedral Priory in Romney Marsh, an average capital expenditure of 32 per cent on gross cash income was reached in the last quarter of the thirteenth century. However, only part of the Priory's income was in cash, which seriously distorts the calculation: Gross and Butcher, ‘Adaptation and investment’, 112.

52 Holderness, ‘Landlord's capital formation’, 439.

53 Thoen, Landbouwekonomie, 595–604.

54 D. Stone, Decision-making in medieval agriculture (Oxford, 2005), 121–55.

55 Average based on more than 150 individual leases all over coastal Flanders, assembled by Soens, Spade in de dijk, 136–7.

56 Van Cruyningen, Behoudend maar buigzaam, 181–7.

57 M. K. E. Gottschalk, Historische geografie van Westelijk Zeeuws-Vlaanderen (Assen, 1955–1958), 2 vols.

58 Gottschalk, Historische geografie, II, 19–25; Soens, Spade in de dijk, 102–3.

59 T. Soens, ‘Threatened by the sea, condemned by man? Flood risk and environmental inequalities along the North Sea coast (1200–1800 AD)’, in G. Massard-Guilbaud and R. Rodger eds., Environmental and social inequalities in the city. Historical perspectives (Cambridge, 2011), 102–5.

60 Clark, G., ‘The cost of capital and medieval agricultural technique’, Explorations in Economic History 25 (1988), 269CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See, however, the critics of Jones, E.L., ‘Enclosure, land improvement and the price of capital. A comment’, Explorations in Economic History 27 (1990), 350–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

61 Thoen and Soens, The origins of leasehold; D. Nicholas, Town and countryside: social, economic and political tensions in fourteenth-century Flanders (Bruges, 1971), 268–80; E. Thoen, ‘A medieval “commercial survival economy” in evolution. The Flemish countryside and the transition debate’, in Hoppenbrouwers and Van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 130–35.

62 Soens, Spade in de dijk, 97–8.

63 Vanslembrouck, Thoen and Lehouck, ‘Past landscapes’; P. J. van Cruyningen, ‘Profits and risks in drainage projects in Staats-Vlaanderen, c. 1590–1665’, Jaarboek voor Ecologische Geschiedenis (2005/2006), 123–42; W. Reh, C. M. Steenbergen and D. Aten, Sea of land. The polder as an experimental atlas of Dutch landscape architecture (Amsterdam, 2006).

64 Ghent, State Archives, St Peter's Abbey, Cartularium 6, f 126, quitclaim dated 6 March 1502.

65 W. De Clercq, Dumolyn, J. and Haemers, J., ‘Vivre noblement: material culture and elite identity in late medieval Flanders’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History 38, 1 (2007), 131Google Scholar.

66 J. de Vries, ‘Measuring the impact of climate on history: the search for appropriate methodologies’, in R. I. Rotberg and Th. K. Rabb eds., Climate and history. Studies in interdisciplinary history (Princeton, 1981), 23.