Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-pfhbr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-13T16:49:49.079Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Stock-market Forecasting as Cosmography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 February 2024

Francis Mobio*
Affiliation:
Université de Paris I.

Extract

In the midst of the ultra modernity of stock exchanges and financial markets, certain practitioners are increasingly using forecasting models of changes in rates whose scientific rationality is particularly contested. We refer to ‘technical analysis’, or, in the jargon of finance, of ‘chartism’. The adherents of this practice affirm that their models offer the possibility of detecting and of reading, by means of stereotyped graphical configurations, rising or falling market trends. Now, for a large number of people who hold scientific economic and financial theories to describe the ‘nature’ of changes in rates as so many random and unpredictable phenomena, these models arise above all from the sphere of ‘superstition’ and ‘beliefs’, in the worst sense of the term. To listen to them, one would think there was hardly any difference between sorcery, prophecy, and chartism, since in short: “it works because people believe in it”. These are remarks that can only arouse the curiosity of the anthropologist, because they actually serve merely to recall epistemologica! controversies that depend on the rationality and the irrationality of observed practices and debates in various cultures. At the heart of these contradictory debates, it is precisely prophecy as a cultural mode of managing unforeseen events that has been the subject of multiple anthropological, historical, and epistemological studies which can, in a comparative perspective, clarify the structure and functioning of forecasting tools employed by the chartists in the context of financial speculation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © ICPHS 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, Alfred and András, Zempléni (1972). Le Bâton de l'aveugle. Divination, maladie et pouvoir chez les Moudang du Tchad Paris: Hermann.Google Scholar
Baré, Jean-François (1991). Image de la finance. L'Homme, 119, July-September, XXXI (3), 2340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Béchu, Thierry and Bertrand, Eric (1998). L'analyse technique, pratiques et methodes. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Bloch, Raymond (1991). La divination, essai sur l'avenir et son imaginaire. Paris: Fayard.Google Scholar
Bottéro, Jean (1974). Symptôme, signes, écritures, en Mesopotamie ancienne. Extract from yos, X: 54, in Divination et rationalité. Paris: Seuil, 71195.Google Scholar
Bouleau, Nicolas (1998). Martingales et marchés financiers. Paris: Odile Jacob.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahen, Pierre (1992). La méthode d'Elliot, outil de decision. Paris: SEFI.Google Scholar
Dupuy, Jean-Pierre (1991). La panique. Paris: Éditions Delagrange, in the series “les empêcheur de penser en rond “.Google Scholar
Dupuy, Jean-Pierre (1992). Le sacrifice et l'envie. Paris: Calmann-Lévy.Google Scholar
Eichinger, Marc (1996). La machine spéculative. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Guinzburg, Carlo (1989). Mythes, emblèmes, traces. Morphologie et histoire. Paris: Flammarion. Translated from the Italian by Monique Aymard, Christian Paoloni, Elsa Bonan, and Martine Sancini-Vignet. (Original edition Miti, emblemi, spie [ 1986]. Turin: Giulio Einaudi.)Google Scholar
Horton, Robin (1982). Tradition and modernity revisited. In Martin Hollis and Steven Lukes (eds). Rationality and Relativism Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1969). Théorie générale de l'emploi, de l'intérêt et de la monnaie. Paris: Bibliothèque scientifique Payot. Translated from the English by de Largentaye, Jean. (Original edition The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money [1936]. London: Macmillan.)Google Scholar
Lenclud, Gérard (1994). Attribuer les croyances à autrui, anthropologie et psychologie ordinaire. Gradhiva, Revue d'Histoire et d'Archive de l'Anthropologie, 15. Paris: Jean-Michel Place Édition, 325.Google Scholar
Lévi-Strauss, Claude (1962). La pensée sauvage. Paris: Plon.Google Scholar
Mancini, Silvia (1994). La notion d'ethnocentrisme critique. Gradhiva, Revue d'Histoire et d'Archive de l'Anthropologie, 15. Paris: Jean-Michel Place Édition.Google Scholar
Mignon, Valérie (1998). Marchés financiers et modelisation des rentabilités boursières. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Needham, Rodney (1972). Belief, Language and Experience. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Orléan, André (1989). Comportement mimetiques et diversités es opinions sur les marchés financiers. In Artus, Patrick and Bourguinat, Henri, Théorie économique et crises des marchés financiers. Paris: Economica, 4565.Google Scholar
Orléan, André (1999). Le pouvoir des marchés financiers. Paris: Odile Jacob.Google Scholar
Pouillon, Jean (1993). Le cru et le su. Paris: Seuil. In the series “La librairie du XXe siècle”.Google Scholar
Sabbatucci, Dario (1975). Lo stato come conquista culturale, Ricerca sulla religione romana. Rome: Bulzoni Editore.Google Scholar
Simoni-Belli, Carlo (1998). Teoria della previsione e analisi strategica. Florence: Casa Editrice Le Lettere.Google Scholar
Vaihinger, Hans (1965). The Philosophy of 'As If'. London: Kegan Paul. (1st edition 1924.)Google Scholar
Vernant, Jean-Pierre (1973). Pourquoi des astrolgues au XXe siècle, Raison presente, January-February-March. Paris: Édition Rationalistes 25, 1753.Google Scholar
Vernant, Jean-Pierre (1974). Parole et signes muets. In Divination et rationalité Paris: Seuil.Google Scholar
Walter, Christian (1996). Les marchées financiers, hasard et prévisibilité. In Les sciences de la prévision. Paris: Seuil, 125–45.Google Scholar