Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-4rdrl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-04T09:23:58.012Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Distance to hazard: an environmental policy with income heterogeneity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 September 2016

Minoru Nakada*
Affiliation:
Graduate School of Environmental Studies, Nagoya University, and Faculty of Land and Food Systems, University of British Columbia, Furo, Chikusa, Nagoya 464-8601, Japan. E-mail: mnakada@cc.nagoya-u.ac.jp

Abstract

This study examines whether voting by individuals of different income levels affects the stringency of environmental policy if their residential proximity to a pollution source is considered. A location model with heterogeneous agents is extended to include a single environmentally hazardous site at the edge of a linear city and the degree of damage from pollution is assumed to depend on the distance from this emissions site. The analysis demonstrates through majority voting that the equilibrium emissions tax rate is higher when the income level of the median voter is lower, because residents with low incomes reside near the hazardous site and thus benefit more from pollution abatement than residents with higher incomes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Becker, S.G. and Tomes, N. (1979), ‘An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility’, Journal of Political Economy 87(6): 11531189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellettini, G. and Hubert, K. (2013), ‘Why not in your backyard? On the location and size of a public facility’, Regional Science and Urban Economics 43(1): 2230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyle, M.A. and Kiel, K.A. (2001), ‘A survey of house price hedonic studies of the impact of environmental externalities’, Journal of Real Estate Literature 9(2): 117144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brasington, D.M. and Hite, D. (2005), ‘Demand for environmental quality: a spatial hedonic analysis’, Regional Science and Urban Economics 35(1): 5782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, N. and Sethi, R. (1997), ‘The distribution of pollution: community characteristics and exposure to air toxics’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32(2): 233250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brookshire, D.S., Thayer, M.A., Schulze, W.D., and d'Arge, R.C. (1982), ‘Valuing public goods: a comparison of survey and hedonic approaches’, American Economic Review 72(1): 165177.Google Scholar
Brueckner, J.K. and Selod, H. (2006), ‘The political economy of urban transport-system choice’, Journal of Public Economics 90(6–7): 9831005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brueckner, J.K., Thisse, J.F., and Zenou, Y. (1999), ‘Why is central Paris rich and downtown Detroit poor? An amenity-based theory’, European Economic Review 43(1): 91107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brueckner, J.K., Thisse, J.F., and Zenou, Y. (2002), ‘Local labor markets, job matching and urban location’, International Economic Review 43(1): 155171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farber, S. (1998), ‘Undesirable facilities and property values: a summary of empirical studies’, Ecological Economics 24(1): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fujita, M. (1989), Urban Economic Theory: land use and city size, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gayer, T., Hamilton, J.T., and Viscusi, W.K. (2000), ‘Private values of risk tradeoffs at superfund sites: housing market evidence on learning about risk’, Review of Economics and Statistics 82(3): 439451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotte, L. and Winer, S.L. (2012), ‘Environmental regulation and trade openness in the presence of private mitigation’, Journal of Development Economics 97: 4657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahn, M.E. and Matsusaka, J.G. (1997), ‘Demand for environmental goods: evidence from voting patterns on California initiatives’, Journal of Law and Economics 40(1): 137174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAusland, C. (2003), ‘Voting for pollution policy: the importance of income inequality and openness to trade’, Journal of International Economics 61(2): 425451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McConnell, K.E. (1997), ‘Income and the demand for environmental quality’, Environment and Development Economics 2(4): 383399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neidell, M.J. (2004), ‘Air pollution, health, and socio-economic status: the effect of outdoor air quality on childhood asthma’, Journal of Health Economics 23(6): 12091236.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tiebout, C.M. (1956), ‘A pure theory of local expenditures’, Journal of Political Economy 64(5): 416424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar