Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-m8s7h Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-18T02:18:23.070Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Accountability and Patterns of Alternation in Pluralitarian, Majoritarian and Consensus Democracies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2013

Abstract

One of the core values in a democracy is the possibility for citizens to bring about alternation in power if they disapprove of the governmental policy. This article examines patterns of alternation and the degree of accountability in three different democratic systems: pluralitarian (characterized by a two-party system), majoritarian (moderately fragmented party system) and consensus (very fragmented party system) democracies. The extent of non-alternation as well as wholesale alternation decreases as we move from pluralitarian to majoritarian and further on to consensus democracy. When alternation is related to election results, majoritarian systems are the most responsive ones, whereas consensus systems generate the lowest degree of accountability.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2011.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Manin, Bernard, Przeworski, Adam and Stokes, Susan C., ‘Elections, Accountability, and Representation’, in Przeworski, Adam, Stokes, Susan and Manin, Bernard (eds), Democracy, Accountability and Representation, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1999, pp. 2954, at p. 50CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 G. Bingham Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press, 2000, p. 122.

3 Kaiser, André, Lehnert, Matthias, Miller, Bernhard and Sieberer, Ulrich, ‘The Democratic Quality of Institutional Regimes: A Conceptual Framework’, Political Studies, 50: 2 (June 2002), pp. 313–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

4 Ibid., p. 325.

5 Lupia, Arthur, ‘Delegation and its Perils’, in Strom, Kaare, Müller, Wolfgang C. and Bergman, Torbjörn (eds), Delegation and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracies, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2003, pp. 3354, at p. 35CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Torbjörn Bergman, Wolfgang C. Müller, Kaare Strom and Magnus Blomgren, ‘Democratic Delegation and Accountability: Cross-National Patterns’, in Strom, Müller and Bergman, Delegation and Accountability, pp. 109–220, at p. 110.

7 Ibid., at p. 111.

8 Strom, Kaare, Minority Government and Majority Rule, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1990, p. 131 Google Scholar.

9 Manin, Przeworski and Stokes, ‘Elections, Accountability, and Representation’.

10 Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy, p. 9.

11 Anthony Downs, Economic Theory of Democracy, New York, HarperCollins, 1957.

12 Mair, Peter, Party System Change: Approaches and Interpretations, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1997 Google Scholar.

13 Arend Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press, 1999.

14 Nagel, Jack H., ‘Expanding the Spectrum of Democracies: Reflections on Proportional Representation in New Zealand’, in Crepaz, M., Koelble, T. and Wilsford, D. (eds), Democracy and Institutions. The Life Work of Arend Lijphart, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press, 2000, pp. 113–28Google Scholar.

15 Kaiser et al., ‘The Democratic Quality of Institutional Regimes’, p. 326.

16 Ibid., p. 317.

17 Sartori, Giovanni, Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1976 Google Scholar.

18 Kaiser et al., ‘The Democratic Quality of Institutional Regimes’, pp. 317–19.

19 Sartori, Parties and Party Systems, p. 123.

20 Laakso, Markku and Taagepera, Rein, ‘“Effective” Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 12: 1 (1979), pp. 327 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21 Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy, p. 11.

22 Blais, André and Carty, R. K., ‘The Impact of Electoral Formulae on the Creation of Majority Governments’, Electoral Studies, 6: 3 (1987), pp. 209–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 Narud, Hanne M. and Valen, Henry, ‘Coalition Membership and Electoral Performance’, in Strom, K., Müller, W.C. and Bergman, T. (eds), Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2008, pp. 369402, at p. 371Google Scholar.

24 Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy, p. 68.

25 Powell, G. B. and Whitten, G. D., ‘A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context’, American Journal of Political Science, 37: 2 (1993), pp. 391414 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Åsa Bengtsson, Ekonomisk röstning och politisk kontext. En studie av 266 val i parlamentariska demokratier, Åbo, Åbo Akademi University Press, 2002.

27 Narud and Valen, ‘Coalition Membership and Electoral Performance’, pp. 371, 382.

28 Strom, Minority Government.

29 See e.g. Narud, and Valen, , ‘Coalition Membership and Electoral Performance’, p. 379; Martin Paldam, ‘The Distribution of Electoral Results and the Two Explanations of the Cost of Ruling’, European Journal of Political Economy, 2 (1986), pp. 524 Google Scholar; Powell Elections as Instruments of Democracy, pp. 47–8; Powell and Whitten, ‘A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting’, p. 398; Richard Rose and Thomas T. Mackie, ‘Incumbency in Government: Asset or Liability’, in Hans Daalder and Peter Mair (eds), Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change, Beverly Hills, Sage, 1983; Strom, Minority Government, pp. 123–4.

30 Strom, Kaare, Budge, Ian and Laver, Michael J., ‘Constraints on Cabinet Formation in Parliamentary Democracies’, American Journal of Political Science, 38: 2 (1994), pp. 305–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Sartori, Giovanni, Comparative Constitutional Engineering: An Inquiry into Structures, Incentives, and Outcomes, London, Macmillan, 1994, p. 132 Google Scholar.

32 Duverger, Maurice, ‘A New Political System Model: Semi-Presidential Government’, European Journal of Political Research, 8: 2 (1980), pp. 165–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 The parliamentary elections in 2003 and 2007 are not included, although the political practice since 2000 has been more parliamentary than semi-presidential.

34 Sartori, Parties and Party Systems, pp. 121–31.

35 Ibid., pp. 138–9.

36 Data on a few elections and government formations are missing during the relevant time period: Iceland 1959 and 1999, Italy 2006, Japan 1995, 1996 and 2000, New Zealand 1996 and Portugal 1983.

37 All data used in the article may be obtained from the author upon request.

38 Among the countries that score both 1 and 0.

39 Lijphart, Arend, Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press, 1984, p. 1 Google Scholar.