Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-4hhp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-09T06:01:05.835Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Preface

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Preface
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. For an overview, see Tyson, Laura D'Andrea, Economic Adjustment in Eastern Europe (Santa Monica: Rand, 1984)Google Scholar; on Eastern Europe see Marer, Paul, “East European Economies: Achievements, Problems, Prospects,” in Rakowska-Harmstone, Teresa and Gyorgy, Andrew, eds., Communism in Eastern Europe (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1981), pp. 244–90Google Scholar.

2. See Crozier, Michel, Huntington, Samuel, and Watanuki, Joji, The Crisis of Democracy (New York: New York University Press, 1975)Google Scholar; King, Anthony, “Overload: Problems of governing in the 1970's,” Political Studies 23 (1975), pp. 162–74Google Scholar; Logue, J., “The Welfare State—Victim of Its Success?Daedalus 108, no. 4 (1979), pp. 6987Google Scholar; Offe, Claus, “Competitive Party Democracy and the Keynesian Welfare State: Factors of Stability and Disorganization,” in Ferguson, Thomas and Rogers, Joel, eds., The Political Economy (Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1984), pp. 349–69Google Scholar. Essays in Hirsch, Fred and Thorpe, John Gold, The Political Economy of Inflation (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1978)Google Scholar, and Berger, Suzanne, ed., Organizing Interests in Western Europe (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar, are also preoccupied with the theme of “governability.”

3. See Biró, József, “Hungarian Foreign Trade in the Seventies,” in Simon, Denis, ed., Modern Hungary (Bloomington: University of Indiana Press, 1973), pp. 164–85Google ScholarPubMed.

4. For example, see Evans, Peter, Dependent Development: The Alliance of Multinational State and Local Capital in Brazil (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1979)Google Scholar; Grunwald, Joseph, ed., Latin America and the World Economy (Beverly Hills: Sage, 1978)Google Scholar; McMillion, Charles W., “International Integration and Intra-national Disintegration: The Case of Spain,” Comparative Politics 13 (04 1981), pp. 291313Google Scholar; Fields, G. S., “Who Benefits from Economic Development? —A Reexamination of Brazilian Growth in the 1960s,” American Economic Review 67 (09 1977), pp. 570–82Google Scholar; Chinn, D. L., “Distributional Equality and Economic Growth: The Case of Taiwan,” Economic Development and Cultural Change 26 (10 1977), pp. 6579Google Scholar; Cumings, Bruce, “The Northeast Asian Political Economy,” International Organization 38 (Winter 1984), pp. 141Google Scholar.

5. See Katzenstein, Peter, Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Katzenstein, , “Introduction: Domestic and International Forces and Strategies of Foreign Economic Policy,” and his “Conclusion: Domestic Structures and Strategies of Foreign Policy,” International Organization 31 (Autumn 1977), pp. 587607, 879–920Google Scholar.

6. Gourevitch, Peter suggests such possibilities in “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics,” International Organization 32 (Autumn 1978), pp. 881913Google Scholar, and in Hirschman, Albert, “Beyond Asymmetry: Critical Notes on Myself as a Young Man and on Some Other Old Friends,” International Organization 32 (Winter 1978), pp. 4551Google Scholar.

7. Machiavelli, Niccolo, The Prince and the Discourses (New York: Random, 1950), p. 92Google Scholar.