Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-dwq4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-27T14:02:51.310Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The neglected variable. The coevolution of public administration and political parties in the UK and Italy (1950–2010)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 August 2019

Eugenio Pizzimenti*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Sciences, University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy
Enrico Calossi
Affiliation:
Department of Political Sciences, University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy
*
*Corresponding author. Email: eugenio.pizzimenti@unipi.it
Get access

Abstract

The relationships between the State and political parties have often been analysed in dual terms. Yet, as Katz and Mair already noticed in their well-known (and criticized) article on the emergence of the cartel party, a clear separation between parties and public institutions has never been completely achieved, in the evolution of liberal democracies. In contrast, while parties act as agencies of institutionalization, public institutions recognize (de jure or de facto) parties as the legitimate actors of political representation. From this perspective, it is worth considering party change as a process intertwined also with institutional change. To date, however, the analysis of such a relationship has been neglected by political scientists, who have privileged explanations of party change based on other factors, whether at systemic or at a micro level. By avoiding a priori assumptions about causality, our main research question is the following: is it possible to identify patterns of co-evolution between State institutions – more specifically, public administration – and party organizations? Building on a new institutional approach to organization theory, the aim of this article is to investigate to what extent the evolution in the size of party organizations and in the size of public administration has followed similar trajectories. Our study focuses on the United Kingdom and Italy, from 1950 to 2010. Our findings confirm that parties' external face expands when public spending and the number of public employees increase, and vice-versa. The same holds for parties' internal face, at least in the Italian case.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Società Italiana di Scienza Politica 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Introduction

The study of party organizational change has been characterized by two prevailing orientations (Bardi et al., Reference Bardi, Calossi, Pizzimenti, Scarrow, Webb and Poguntke2017). On the one hand, party scholars have largely focused on parties’ internal structures and dynamics, and their external linkages, to single out common patterns towards alleged new models.Footnote 1 On the other hand, a bulk of studies have analysed party organizational change by highlighting the role played by political entrepreneurs in modelling party evolution (Hellmann, Reference Hellmann2011). In both cases, party change is generally considered dependent on other factors, whether systemic (of socio-economic, technological and cultural kind) or set at a micro level (the actions and choices made by individuals or groups). While the empirical research has widely shown how patterns of organizational convergence have been characterizing party change,Footnote 2 at least in long-established liberal-democracies, the explanans of such tendencies do not include the eventual role played by State institutions.

Building on a new-institutional approach to organization theory, the aim of this article is to investigate the relationships between the evolution of State institutions – more specifically, public administration – and party organizations. The relationships between administration and politics are crucial to the functioning of democratic party government (Katz, Reference Katz, Castels and Wildenmann1986): however, to the date, this topic has not yet been analysed through an organizational approach. Probably, this is due to the uncertain nature of political parties. In fact, parties are, at the same time, the representatives of the civil society within the institutions and State institutionalization agencies (Powell and Di Maggio, Reference Powell and Di Maggio1991; Katz, Reference Katz and Bardi2006). The progressive ‘statization’ of parties – a process accelerated in the second half of the 20th century – and their supposed transformation into peculiar kinds of public utilities (van Biezen, Reference van Biezen2004; van Biezen and Kopecky, Reference van Biezen and Kopecky2014), make it difficult to precisely identify patterns of the causal direction between observable changes occurring in public administration and in political parties. This ambiguity leads us to avoid a priori and deterministic assumptions. Thus, our main research goal will be focused on the identification of possible patterns of co-evolution in the size of party organizations and in the size of public administration (SPA).

The analysis of the relationships between public administration and party organizations is relevant for a number of reasons. First, by focusing on the autonomy and the peculiarities of the politico-administrative sphere, it is possible to attenuate those explanations of party change that are based on socio-economic, cultural and technological factors. Second, a theory-driven approach to the analysis of the organizational relationships between parties and public administration may help to enhance the overall quality of the reflections on political representation in contemporary democracies. Third, this subject may favour the mutual contamination between two bodies of the literature that have been traditionally kept separated.

In the second and third sections we introduce the main theoretical assumptions of the sociological new-institutionalism in organization theory. In the fourth section we will concentrate on the parallel evolution in the size of both public administration and party organizations in Western Europe, since the end of WWII. In the fifth section, our analytical framework will be introduced and empirically applied to two very dissimilar cases, the United Kingdom and Italy, from 1950 to 2010. Our main findings will be discussed in the sixth section.

A new-institutional approach to the study of organizational change

Those political scientists committed to the study of party change have rarely worn the lenses of organization theory (Panebianco, Reference Panebianco1982; Harmel, Reference Harmel and Bardi2006) while, in recent years, scholars engaged in the field of organizational studies have progressively broadened their research interest towards political parties (Karthikeyan et al., Reference Karthikeyan, Jonsson and Wezel2016; Husted, Reference Husted2018).

In this contribution we resort to the theoretical assumptions and analytical tools of the new institutional approach to organization theory, in its sociological version.Footnote 3 Different from the fundamental – but unfortunately isolated – contribution by Panebianco (Reference Panebianco1982), our investigation focuses on the relationship between organizations and their environment rather than on intra-organizational power.

In their famed volume ‘Rediscovering Institutions’, March and Olsen (Reference March and Olsen1989) maintain that contemporary liberal-democracies may be described as complex ecologies of interdependent institutional spheres: politico-administrative, socio-economic, cultural, etc. Each sphere is characterized by organizational settings and organizational populations. From this perspective, all the organizations belonging to a specific institutional sphere show tendency to both conformity (Di Maggio and Powell, Reference Di Maggio and Powell1983; Meyer and Scott, Reference Meyer and Scott1983), as they tend to adopt the same rationalized myths, which ‘define new organizing situations, redefine existing ones, […] specify the means for coping rationally with each, […] enable, and often require, participants to organize along prescribed lines’ (Meyer and Rowan, Reference Meyer and Rowan1977: 343). Organizational structures, internal procedures and symbols are thus subject to isomorphic pressures (Lanzalaco, Reference Lanzalaco1995; Thoenig, Reference Thoenig, Peters and Pierre2012). The steadier the institutional sphere, in time, the more the organizations will tend to look like each other: isomorphism is a collective process and its pace is linked to the level of organizations' dependence on environmental resources (Powell and Di Maggio Reference Powell and Di Maggio1991).

The organizations that conform and help to reproduce and innovate the rationalized myths are provided with institutional legitimacy (Pfeffer and Salancik, Reference Pfeffer and Salancik1978). Legitimacy is a fundamental factor, as it is constantly exchanged by both institutions and organizations. While novel organizational settings and organizational populations will depend on each other, as both need to increase and consolidate their external and internal legitimacy, more established ones will be more autonomous from each other – although both will keep on co-evolving through a dialectical process of mutual influence (Lindblom, Reference Lindblom1977).

By reproducing the legitimated rationalized myths, the organizations may assume conservative or innovative attitudes and behaviours, according to their own interest to maintain or modify their relative positioning within the field (Scott, Reference Scott2008). In their struggle for a better positioning, the organizations contribute to institutional persistence or change. In this respect, scholars have been increasingly ‘treating institutional and organizational influences as reciprocal and intertwined instead of unidirectional’ (Hult, Reference Hult, Peters and Pierre2012: 194). While studies centred on the concept of isomorphism were based on the implicit ‘[…] idea that institutional models or prescriptions are “out there”’ (Greenwood et al, Reference Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin, Suddaby, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and Suddaby2013: 17), more recent literature has emphasized how organizations, rather than being passive subjects to environmental demands, behave as active promoters of institutional change. This foundational assumption is crucial for the interpretation of political parties' role in contemporary liberal-democracies.

Political institutions and organizations

According to organizational institutionalism applied to the study of politics, scholars should pay more attention to the autonomy of political institutions and organizations, as these cover a relatively independent positioning among the other institutional spheres and in respect of the choices made by individual actors (March and Olsen Reference March and Olsen1983; Scott, Reference Scott1995). The peculiarity of the politico-administrative institutions is founded on their legitimate power of taking and implementing coercive collective decisions, within a specific territory and with regard to a specific community (Poggi, Reference Poggi1978). More in general, the politico-administrative institutions are entitled to regulate all the other institutional spheres and organizational populations.

Like any other institutional sphere, the politico-administrative institutions persist, in time, as far as the institutional order is reproduced by their organizational populations. From the second half of the 19th Century, political parties constitute the main organizational population competing to control the politico-administrative institutions (von Beyme, Reference von Beyme1987; Ignazi, Reference Ignazi2017). In contemporary liberal-democracies, political parties are fundamental actors as they perform two crucial functions: on the one hand, they represent and promote, at the institutional level, the plurality of issues raised from the civil society (representative functions); on the other hand, they are the main actors in maintaining and reproducing the institutional order, in their vest of legislators and policy makers (procedural functions). Parties help channel the political conflict within the institutional framework, by promoting the foundational values and principles of the latter. As a reward, parties are legitimated (de jure or de facto) by the State as the main actors of the democratic representation.

This duplicity makes political parties' nature rather ambiguous. In particular, their relationships with the State need to be analysed with suitable precautions at the theoretical level. Different from all the other private or semi-private organizations, in fact, political parties hold the power to modify ‘the rules of the game’, that is to reform public institutions. Those parties that enter the representative institutions are legitimately entitled to change the structural settings and powers of the State: these parties regulate directly their own organizational field and their relationships with the State, by disciplining the requisites they must comply with to be admitted to the political and electoral competition, and to access environmental resources.

This peculiar nature of parties has been stressed by the theorists of the cartel party model.Footnote 4 In their well-known and contested article on the emergence of the cartel party, Katz and Mair (Reference Katz and Mair1995, Reference Katz and Mair2009) maintain the relationship between political parties, the civil society and the State developed dialectically, in time. This process has brought to parties' progressive penetration of the State, at least since the second half of the 20th Century, as the ties between the parties and the civil society were rapidly vanishing in terms of partisan identification, partisan alignment and party mobilization.Footnote 5 State penetration was interpreted as the by-product of a number of socio-economic, cultural as well as technological factors. The ‘statization’ of parties – a process epitomized by the introduction of public funding regimes – has supposedly transformed their very nature: from private associations into peculiar kinds of public utilities (van Biezen, Reference van Biezen2004; van Biezen and Kopecky, Reference van Biezen and Kopecky2014), heavily dependent on State direct and indirect resources.

Despite their institutional powers and pervasiveness, however, party organizational boundaries and functions do not coincide with those of the politico-administrative institutions: in theory therefore organizational changes experienced by public administration and parties, although they are intertwined, may be observed separately.

The evolution of the relationships between public administration and political parties

The relationship between politics and administration is at the heart of government (Dahlstrom, Reference Dahlstrom, Peters and Pierre2012). In political science, as well as in administrative law, this relationship has been framed as dichotomous, i.e. as the by-product of the doctrine about the separation of powers, of the legacies of some ancien régime features, and of the higher specialization of functions and technicality of the public offices (Rugge, Reference Rugge, Peters and Pierre2012). By following the principles formulated by Max Weber in his classical analysis of bureaucratic legitimacy in modern societies (Weber, Reference Weber1947), while politics shapes decisions, administration neutrally implements such decisions. However, although the division between administration and politics still remains a central organizing principle in all Western political systems (Rouban, Reference Rouban, Peters and Pierre2012), this separation has never been entirely enforced, especially after the growth of State intervention in the 20th Century. This makes it even more necessary to analyse in-depth the co-evolution of public administrations and party organizations, as ‘the scope of government determines the scope of administration’ (Fesler, Reference Fesler, Lynn and Wildavsky1990: 85).

In the literature, it is often argued that administrative reforms are the result of political struggles: however, as empirical research showed, the evolution of public administration follows also different patterns from those of the political processes (Dahlstrom, Reference Dahlstrom, Peters and Pierre2012). The role political parties play within public administration has been mainly analysed through the lenses of representation theory and that of patronage, i.e. the politicization of public administrationFootnote 6 (Peters and Pierre, Reference Peters and Pierre2004). In Western Europe, parties' colonization of the State – a phenomenon deeply connected to the building of the welfare state – has been observed by focusing on partisan control of recruitments and promotions of civil servants; and on the addition of layers of political appointees to the civil service (Dahlstrom, Reference Dahlstrom, Peters and Pierre2012). In a way, while parties' impact on public administration has been taken for granted by political scientists, a broader reflection on how public institutions and party organizations co-evolve, from an organizational point of view, has been set aside.

In the next paragraphs we highlight the main trajectories that characterized administrative and party evolution in most of the Western European countries, since the end of WW II. Our analysis is mainly based on the secondary literature in public administration and party studies.

The rise and fall of big government and big parties

After WWII, the consolidation and the expansion of the welfare state were functional to facilitate the post war reconstruction process in Western Europe (Flora, Reference Flora1986; Esping-Andersen, Reference Esping-Andersen1990). During the s.c. ‘Glorious Thirties’ (1945–1975), welfare statehood expanded ‘to limits’, bringing with it bureaucratization (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2018). The incidence of public spending for administration increased in parallel to the rapid and stable economic growth: the rationalized myth of a ‘scientific’ approach to State intervention became dominant during the 60s (Pollitt and Bouckaert, Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011).

At the same time, party organizations registered an unprecedented dimensional growth (Katz and Mair, Reference Katz and Mair1992). The extension of the social rights, State aid to national industry and firms, and the expansion of public administrations were power resources controlled by parties. Political primacy over public administration was fundamental for parties, as it granted them the possibility to provide goods (in terms of careers) and incentives (both material and symbolic) to their voters, as well as to gain loyal support for their preferred policies (Dahlstrom, Reference Dahlstrom, Peters and Pierre2012).

At the beginning of the 70s, during the ‘golden age’ of the European welfare state (Flora, Reference Flora1986), parties’ colonization of public administration was in its heydays as well as citizens' consensus toward party politics. However, in the middle of the decade, the recession and the slow-down of the economic growth weakened the widespread consensus reached in the post-war settlement. Moreover, ‘European welfare states had started to be afflicted by a number of internal, increasingly troublesome challenges and dynamics (such as demographic ageing or the post-industrial transition)’ (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2008: 85–86). The State, at least at an ideational level, became the problem (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2014). The rise of alternative views of the role of the State, based on neo-liberal theories and supported by the conservative parties in the UK and the USA, was centred on the downsizing of public administration; the privatization of public corporations and services; and on a regulative role assigned to the administration. It was the dawn of the New Public Management (NPM).

Despite the pervasive narrative of the NPM, institutional reluctance to change hindered in-depth modifications in public administration dimensions (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2008), with the partial exception of the Anglo-Saxon countries (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2014). During the 80s, although many countries launched reforms to downsize public administration, national peculiarities deeply influenced the degree to which each country ‘rationalized’ public intervention (Flora, Reference Flora1986).

Institutional persistence intertwined with party organizational stasis. Western European parties did not undergo significant organizational changes, even if the symptoms of widespread discontent, indifference and disinterest began to manifest in terms of electoral volatility and party membership decline (Mair, Reference Mair2005).

Public administration and party decline?

It was only in the aftermath of a series of international political events (the collapse of the Soviet Union), economic dynamics (the increase of the globalization process and international trade, and the intensifying of the EU integration), as well as changes in domestic socio-economic structures (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2008) that the role and competences of the Nation State had to face in-depth modifications. Within the framework of the EU integration process, the neo-liberal discourse was losing ground, while a new ideological consensus emerged, which Ferrera (Reference Ferrera2014) proposes to call ‘liberal neo-welfarism’. Since the mid-90s, new administrative recipes based on concepts such as governance, partnership, network, transparency and e-government entered within the institutional agendas of EU member states (Pollitt and Bouckaert, Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011).

While public administration was undergoing in-depth modifications, the crisis of the traditional party organizational models became irreversible, as empirically shown by the specialized literature (van Biezen et al., Reference van Biezen, Mair and Poguntke2011). Although to a different extent from country to country, political parties began (confusedly) to promote changes based on the rationalized myths derived from the NPM rhetoric and its further evolution.

The present era of continuous administrative reforms corresponds to parties’ restless struggle to find effective organizational arrangements (Ignazi, Reference Ignazi2012). However, some common tendencies have been identified by the literature, such as party de-territorialization; the decrease of paid staff at the central level (Webb, Reference Webb2000; Bardi et al., Reference Bardi, Calossi, Pizzimenti, Scarrow, Webb and Poguntke2017); organizational decentralization; party presidentialization (Poguntke and Webb, Reference Poguntke and Webb2007); the further autonomization and empowerment of the party in public office (Katz and Mair, Reference Katz and Mair2009) and party opening to civil society in selecting candidates to internal posts, as well as to elections.

Comparative empirical analysis: UK and Italy (1950–2010)

Case selection and method

The aim of the following paragraphs is to investigate the relationships between public administration evolution and party organizational change, in the UK and Italy, from 1950 to 2010. In order to address our main research question, we adopt a most different systems design, by investigating two countries that differ in many salient aspects of the domestic politico-administrative sphere, as reported in Table 1.Footnote 7 In particular, after WWII, the two countries stood on the opposite sides of two hypothetical continua: the consolidation of the State as well as that of the party system. In fact, the Italian institutional and party systems had recently emerged from a semi-totalitarian regime, while the UK was a centuries-old constitutional monarchy and had a consolidated two-party system.

Table 1. The politico-administrative system in Italy and the UK

Public administration and party changes will be observed by analysing the values of a set of indicators. More in detail, for both public administration and parties we will focus on their relative size. While organization theorists have always considered ‘size’ as a characterizing organizational construct (Palmer et al., Reference Palmer, Biggart, Dick, Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin and Suddaby2013), this concept has never been precisely defined in operational terms in party studies. While Tan (Reference Tan1998) argued that party size impacts on intraparty participation and distribution of power, other scholars have stressed the systemic quality of this attribute (Smith, Reference Smith, Müller-Rommel and Pridham1991), which is inherently related to the average dimensions of all the parties within a party system. In all these cases, the party size is considered an independent variable. Another body of the literature, focused on parties' policy preferences, looks at public spending as an indicator of the size of government (Blais et al., Reference Blais, Blake and Dion1993): here the size of the aggregate or sectoral State spending is considered a dependent variable, whose values vary according to the colour of the parties in government.

We concentrate on State spending devoted to public administration as a percentage of the gross domestic product (GDP), an indicator that will be combined with others concerning the size of the civil service and the size of the persons in employment. In particular, changes in the SPA will be measured through the following indicators:

  1. (1) The number of public administration employees (PAE);

  2. (2) The number of total employees (TE);

  3. (3) The PAE/TE ratio;

  4. (4) The Total Public Spending (TPS)/GDP ratio;

Party organizational change will be analysed by focusing on a significant sample of parties – corresponding to the relevant ones for each country. We distinguish two different faces of party organizations: an internal organizational face (related to the size of party membership) and an external organizational face (related to the size of party electoral support). The size of the internal and external organizational faces will be analysed through the following indicators:

  1. (1) the aggregate number of party members (PM);

  2. (2) the aggregate number of party voters raised by the analysed parties (PVPM);

  3. (3) the PM/PVPM ratio;

  4. (4) the total number of party voters (PVT) at the national elections;

As our main goal is to observe patterns of possible co-evolution between the size of public administration and that of party organizations we do not formulate any specific assumption of causality between the two variables. The possibility that this relationship could be a positive one, a negative one or that no relationship exists is left open (Nardi, Reference Nardi2018). In general, we may expect that the expansion/contraction in the size of public administration runs in parallel to the expansion/contraction in the size of both party internal and external faces. On the one hand, parties that have access to State resources may distribute such assets amongst their affiliates in the form of goods (e.g. recruitment and careers of the civil servants), organizational innovations (by adding layers of political appointees to the civil service) and selective incentives: in all these cases, the attractiveness to become PM supposedly increases (Scarrow et al., Reference Scarrow, Archury, Kosiara-Pedersen and van Haute2018). On the other hand, the expansion of public administration is generally supported by the citizens when it intertwines with an extension of public services (Steinmo, Reference Steinmo1993; Ferrera, Reference Ferrera2014), so that the number of voters is also expected to increase.

The selected indicators will be discussed throughout a qualitative description of public administration reforms and the significant political changes that occurred in the two countries, by primarily resorting to the specialized secondary literature.

The British case

A peculiar feature of the British public administration has always been the autonomy of the civil service from politics (Webb, Reference Webb, Katz and Mair1992): civil servants are primarily regarded as trustees of the public interest, guardians and representatives of the state (Pollitt and Bouckaert, Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011). In the aftermath of WWII, the British elitist and pragmatic model of welfare state (Crouch, Reference Crouch, Ebbinghaus and Manow2001) ‘marked a continuation of wartime policies and of progressive and consensual policy developments’ (Parry, Reference Parry and Flora1986: 160), and it was not subjected to significant administrative reforms. Until the 70s, the most relevant reform of public administration followed the publication of the Fulton Report, in 1968, which aimed at improving management at the governmental level and democratizing the administrative culture: however, the service maintained a rigid hierarchical organization (Norton, Reference Norton, Jones, Norton and Daddow2018).

This period was also marked by a minimal ideological distance between the Conservatives and the Labour (Clark, Reference Clark2012). The consensus politics pursued by both parties characterized British politics until the late 1970s (Bale, Reference Bale2012), by primarily relying on Keynesian macroeconomic policies and the expansion of public services (Farnham and Horton, Reference Farnham and Horton1996; Hassel, Reference Hassel, Ebbinghaus and Manow2001). As confirmed by Parry (Reference Parry and Flora1986: 224) ‘[…] party ideology has been expressed more in terms of symbols and rhetoric than in substantive policy change […]’. Two factors made it possible to achieve such a policy consensus. The first was the Coalition government during WWII, when the Labour became accustomed to finding pragmatic agreements with the Conservatives and gained credibility in office. The second was the importance, within the Conservatives, of the ‘One Nation Group’, which was used to advocate for ‘a full review of social security arrangements’ (Bale, Reference Bale2012: 99), over the other internal tendencies. The main differences could be identified in parties' organizations, which reflected their different genetic models. One of the structural features of the Conservative Party was the formalized differentiation between the party in public office (the most powerful organizational face) and the party in central office (Kelly, Reference Kelly, Garnett and Lynch2003): the party was based on three separate organizations (the National Union of Conservative and Unionist Associations, the Conservative Central Office and the Parliamentary Group), scarcely coordinated. In the Labour, the coalition between parliamentary and Unions' elites dominated the party (Webb, Reference Webb2000). The National Executive Committee has always represented party's organizational core, within which exponents of both the affiliated trade unions and the parliamentary group were predominant. Despite these differences, a common element of the two parties was the low value attributed to ordinary members in having a voice in national party's affairs.

The relationship between the evolution in the size of public administration and that of party internal organization can be observed in more detail in Tables 2 and 3. A common trend in the growth of both the PAE and PM size is observable, at least until the 60s: however, while the expansion of public administration continued throughout the 70s – as well documented also by the PAE/TE and the TPS/GDP ratios – the decline of PM has been a rapid and continuous process (Webb, Reference Webb, Webb, Farrell and Holliday2002). Unfortunately, data are not particularly reliable (Seyd and Whiteley, Reference Seyd and Whiteley1992, Reference Seyd and Whiteley2004), as parties did not have any formal duty to release membership figures (Keen and Audickas, Reference Keen and Audickas2017). The Conservative Party did not maintain a consistent party register: this reluctance was due to the three-face structure of the party and the process by which individuals became full members; as well as to the fact that, until 1965, no role was played by ordinary members in selecting the leadership (Bale, Reference Bale2012). Similarly, pre-1980 figures in Labour were inflated, as from 1956 until that year party's local units were obliged to have at least 800 registered members. While party internal organizations weakened, however, their external support (PVT) followed different trends, in line with the expansionary trends of public spending.

Table 2. UK: the evolution of public administration (1950–2010)

Source: authors’ elaboration on official data published at www.ons.gov.uk/employmentandlabourmarket/peopleinwork/publicsectorpersonnel, and Apostolova and Allen 2017).

Table 3. UK: the evolution of party internal and external organizations (1950–2010)

Source: authors’ elaboration on data published by Katz and Mair (Reference Katz and Mair1992); Clark (Reference Clark2012); and Keen and Audickas, Reference Keen and Audickas2017.

The turning point in the evolution of the British public administration was represented by the success of the Conservative Party led by M. Thatcher, at the 1979 national elections (Hoggett, Reference Hoggett1996; Skelcher, Reference Skelcher2000). From that moment, public administration has been subjected to unprecedented demands for change (Ackroyd et al., Reference Ackroyd, Kirkpatrick and Walker2007). However, the tangible outputs of Thatcher's administrative revolution – inspired by neo-liberal economic theories and by the NPM paradigm (Lawler and Hearn, Reference Lawler and Hearn1995) – were limited, at least until the 90s. In the mid-80s, Parry (Reference Parry and Flora1986: 163) maintained that ‘in the long time perspective, the forces of persistence and continuity remain stronger than those of change and disruption’.

As suggested by Pollitt and Bouckaert (Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011), during the first phase (1979–1982) the re-organization of public administration was mainly centred on cost reduction and cuts; the second phase of reforms (1982–1989) was characterized by the adoption of private sector management doctrines. State dimensions were downsized as far as privatizations and contracting-out policies were pursued. The third phase (1989–1996) registered increased attention toward the use of market-oriented strategies by the public services. The orientations impressed by Thatcher's governments were adopted also by her successor, J. Major: most important, at the organizational level the classic hierarchical structure was progressively replaced by more flexible arrangements (Norton, Reference Norton, Jones, Norton and Daddow2018).

The narrative of administrative change is only partially confirmed by the data.Footnote 8 During the first decade of Thatcher-led governments the TPS/GDP began to decrease significantly only from 1989 (Table 2). Even by considering the increased size of the labour force, however, at the beginning of the 90s the PAE/TE ratio decreased to 22.6%, while the absolute number of PAE diminished of 1.300.000 units from 1980 to 1990.

The (substantial) institutional stability was accompanied by parties' organizational stasis. While significant changes characterized the ideological profile of the major parties, organizational reforms were pursued only at a symbolic level. When Thatcher became the party's leader in 1975, she pushed away from the One Nation Conservatism. Thatcher's leadership was characterized by ‘some limited organisational changes and more substantial policy shifts’ (Bale, Reference Bale2012: 214), thus the predominance of the party in public office was not seriously threatened (Kelly, Reference Kelly, Garnett and Lynch2003). In parallel, Labour's platforms turn into ‘left-wing documents’ (Clark, Reference Clark2012: 63), at least until the first half of the 80s: party organization was initially re-designed to strengthen the extra-parliamentary party at the expense of the party in public office; however, as soon as party electoral support decreased, the Labour turned toward a more leader-oriented organization. More in general, similarly to what was happening in most Western European democracies, also the UK experienced a huge decline of party membership; a progressive disarticulation of party social identity; and the deterioration of citizens trust in politics. These intertwined phenomena brought to a dramatic and relentless party organizational collapse. While intra-party democracy only slightly increased (Rye, Reference Rye, Jones, Norton and Daddow2018), the haemorrhage of PM continued incessantly from 1980 onwards.

After Labour's electoral victory, in 1997, the evolution of the British public administration turned off the pathways of NPM, although the persistence of managerial logics influenced also T. Blair's executives. A complicated mix of public and private relationships represented the new recipe to frame administrative reforms, based on the concepts of governance, partnership, modernization; and an emphasis on more networked forms of governing arrangements. The Blairian ‘Third Way’ led to State congestion, as far as the management and the control over such new public-private arrangements were retained by the State. Unsurprisingly, then, public spending began to increase in parallel to the good economic performance of the country (Pollitt and Boukaert, Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011). In the aftermath of Labour's electoral victory, between 1998 and 2010 the PAE began to increase, by reaching similar figures if compared to 1990. A more gradual rise of the PAE as a proportion of total employment was registered in the same period. The effects of the 2008 economic crisis brought to a significant increase also in the TPS/GDP ratio (51.5% in 2009), whose levels were similar to those observed in 1980.

During the same period, party traditional organizational arrangements were definitively dismissed. Since the end of the 80s, the Labour had promoted internal party reforms aimed at enhancing leadership autonomy, at the expense of the Trade Unions and the parliamentary party (Webb, Reference Webb, Broughton, Farrell, Denver and Railings1995): these changes paved the way for Blair's ascendancy, by opening a new era of plebiscitary intra-party democracy (Webb, Reference Webb2000; Minkin, Reference Minkin2014). After the 1997 electoral collapse, the Conservatives were somewhat forced to modify party internal organization toward more coordinated arrangements, in line with Labours’ successful model. In particular, under Hague's leadership six principles of organizational change were promoted: ‘unity, decentralisation, democracy, involvement, integrity, openness’ (Kelly, Reference Kelly, Garnett and Lynch2003: 87). These were contained in the reform program named ‘The Fresh Future’, whose final result was a further diminishing of local party autonomy and the empowerment of party central office (Webb, Reference Webb2000): the top-down leader-dominated structure of the party persisted (Bale, Reference Bale2016). From an organizational point of view, the data concerning the absolute number of PM and the PM/PVPM ratio depict the irreversible decline of party internal organizations. In contrast, in line with the already observed trend, both the values of PVT and PVPM increased, in parallel to the (re)expansion of public administration.

The Italian case

Antifascist parties were the main protagonists of the war of Liberation from Nazi-Fascism. This early role and their capacity to mobilize citizens (compared to other institutional players) gave these actors the possibility to monopolize the work of the 1946 Constituent Assembly. As a consequence, the constitution was the by-product of parties’ elaborations, values and strategic interests (Scoppola, Reference Scoppola1996). As the legacies of the fascist regime were still too vivid to formally regulate the relationships between the political parties and the State (Pizzimenti, Reference Pizzimenti2017), during the post-war period the political class paid little attention to the organization of public administration (Cassese, Reference Cassese1974; Capano and Gualmini, Reference Capano and Gualmini2006; Melis, Reference Melis2014).

Until the beginning of the 60s, institutional continuity with the past prevailed, despite expenditure for the promotion of the economic expansion grew rapidly (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera and Flora1986). It was in the outcome of a country's ‘economic miracle’ that new reflections on the role of the State brought to the ascendancy of the interventionist paradigm and to the consequent expansion of public administration and public spending (Melis Reference Melis1996).

From an organizational point of view, the rationalized myth of the mass party – a hierarchical and structured extra-parliamentary organization; a high number of PM and local units; voluntary activism and the capacity to raise funds from the affiliates – was the main reference model for all the major parties (Bardi and Morlino, Reference Bardi, Morlino, Katz and Mair1992; Ignazi, Reference Ignazi2002). Parties’ strategies to reinforce their organizations and their electoral strength were centred on the occupation and the exploitation of public institutions (Scoppola, Reference Scoppola1996; Pasquino, Reference Pasquino2002). This strategy was allowed by the total permeability of the bureaucratic personnel to the influences of politics (Melis, Reference Melis and Romanelli1995; Rugge, Reference Rugge, Peters and Pierre2012; Di Mascio, Reference Di Mascio2013), which was favoured by the wide use of patronage made by the predominant Christian Democrats and their minor allies (PLI, PRI and PSDI). These parties were the main beneficiaries of State indirect resources. From 1963 the Socialists (PSI) also entered the area of governmental parties, which did not include the Communists (PCI) and the neo-Fascists (MSI). The launch of the regionalization process, in 1970, allowed also the PCI to control relevant administrative institutions and their related resources.

The parallel co-evolution of public administration and party organizations can be observed more in detail in Tables 4 and 5. State intervention in a high number of policy fields turned into an impressive growth in the number of PAE, from 1950 to 1990: at the beginning of the 90s, the number of PAE was tripled compared to the post-war period, and also the PAE/TE ratio followed similar patterns. The constant growth of public administration is well documented also by the TPS/GDP ratio, which was boosted by the launch of the ordinary Regions and their bureaucratic structures, from 1970 onwards (Istituto Centrale di Statistica, Reference Istituto Centrale di Statistica1976; MEF, 2011). In parallel, more than 4 million Italian citizens were members of a party, yearly, on average.

Table 4. Italy: the evolution of public administration (1950–2010)

Source: authors’ elaboration on official data published by Istituto Centrale di Statistica (Reference Istituto Centrale di Statistica1976), ISTAT (http://www.istat.it) and MEF (2011).

Table 5. Italy: the evolution of party internal and external organizations (1950–2010)

Source: authors’ elaboration on data published by Katz and Mair (Reference Katz and Mair1992); Bardi, Ignazi, and Massari (Reference Bardi, Ignazi and Massari2007); party websites.

It is interesting to note that while the PM/ PVPM ratio fell by 5 percentage points, from 1950 to 1990 – also as a consequence of the extension, in 1975, of the right to vote to citizens aged between 18 and 21 – the external face of the analysed parties constantly increased, at least until 1980. In this respect, the extensive use of clientelistic practices by the Democrazia Cristiana  and its minor allies (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera and Flora1986), especially in Southern regions, still represented a powerful explanation for understanding Italian parties' electoral strength.

The public debate on the ineffectiveness of the Interventionist State began during the 70s, in parallel with the slowdown of economic growth. However, Italian state-centred parties could not loosen their pervasive control over public administration, which constituted the primary source of indirect revenues for the Italian particracy. The resort to public debt was the strategy followed by the Italian governments (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera and Flora1986; Cotta and Isernia, Reference Cotta and Isernia1996). Public administration continued its dimensional growth (Melis, Reference Melis2014): the TPS/GDP was 52.9% in 1990, 20 percentage points higher than in 1970.

Public spending represented a crucial source for the maintenance of large sectors of Italians: thus, structural reforms were left aside by parties, which were slowly undergoing transformations towards less ideological and class-based organizations. However, during this period, despite a rising public discontent and the spread of new mass political attitudes and behaviour activated by the debate on the containment of public spending (Ferrera, Reference Ferrera and Flora1986), the issue of organizational change was not seriously addressed by any of the major parties: only minor concerns about the need to open the parties to civil society emerged.

In the first half of the 1990s, Italy experienced the collapse of its party system. This unexpected process has been interpreted as the byproduct of a number of factors, both external and internal: the collapse of International Communism; Italy's fiscal crisis during the process that eventually gave birth to the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU); the exposure of Italy's widespread system of political corruption; and the referenda that forced radical changes in political competition (Ignazi, Reference Ignazi2002).

In particular, Italy's fiscal malaise culminated in a serious crisis, which forced a departure from the country's irresponsible financial conduct. The constraints imposed by Italy's membership in the EMU forced governments to privilege financial stabilization, deficit containment and austerity (Ferrera and Gualmini, Reference Ferrera and Gualmini2004). In this context, administrative reforms gained prominence within the institutional agenda (Capano and Gualmini, Reference Capano and Gualmini2006). Consequently, after decades of stagnation, public administration entered a period of permanent reform (Capano, Reference Capano, Di Palma, Fabbrini and Freddi2000), which included: the privatization of State firms and public services; the administrative decentralization and simplification; the reorganization of central apparatuses (Pollitt and Bouckaert, Reference Pollitt and Bouckaert2011). But ultimately, none of these reforms had the quality needed to completely remove the legacy of the past. The implementation of these measures has been hindered by the persistence of political, cultural and institutional obstacles (Capano, Reference Capano2003): what happened has been described as ‘institutional layering’ (Bull and Rhodes, Reference Bull and Rhodes2007). Not surprisingly, a slow decrease in the absolute number of PAE, as well as in the TPS/GDP ratio may be observed.

Institutional stability goes hand in hand with the steadiness of voters (PVT), even though the collapse of all the traditional parties brought to an almost completely renewed electoral supply, since 1994. In parallel, parties' internal organizational decline became evident. In 2000, the number of PM had shrunk almost 2.5 Million compared to 1990, and the PM/PVPM ratio more than halved. The rapid and victorious ascendancy of Forza Italia (founded in 1993 by S. Berlusconi) has been considered as a crucial driver for the promotion of party organizational change. In a context of widespread hostility against particracy, the traditional organizational models were seen as inefficient and antiquated. The new predominant rationalized myths were coherent with the spirit of the reforms of public administration. The ‘thin party’ should be founded on the role and personal capacities of its top leaders; on the active participation of citizens, not necessarily enrolled in the party; on a variable network of party clubs and limited membership; on the empowerment of party sub-national organizational tiers; on the contracting out of strategic activities (electoral campaigning, political marketing) to professional paid staff. These organizational changes were promoted, at least at the symbolic level, by all the major parties of the so called Second Republic (Bardi et al., Reference Bardi, Ignazi and Massari2007).

But, as with State reforms (Bull and Pasquino, Reference Bull and Pasquino2007), the legacies of the past limited parties’ actual capacity to find effective and stable organizational arrangements (Ignazi and Pizzimenti, Reference Ignazi and Pizzimenti2014). The transition towards a majoritarian democracy was not completed, while the efforts to create a fictional two-party system – based on supposed new ‘open parties’ (Vassallo and Passarelli, Reference Vassallo and Passarelli2016) – failed spectacularly, by colliding with the well-established proportional functioning of the political system. However, for our purposes, it is interesting to notice that while PM slightly increased from 2000 to 2010, the size of parties’ external face declined, in line with the general trajectories followed by the electoral turnout in most European countries in the aftermath of the 2008 economic crisis; but, also, with the (albeit limited) reduction of the PAE.

Results and discussion

For both the UK and Italy it is possible to resort to a periodization of the time span covered by the research (Table 6). Phases are identified according to the major politico-administrative junctures that occurred in the two countries: the electoral success of M. Thatcher in the UK (1979) and the collapse of the s.c. First Republic in Italy (1992–93).

Table 6. Administrative and party change in the UK and Italy (1950–2010)

By analysing the trends followed by the number of PAE and the number of PM in the UK, from 1950 to 1980, the former constantly increased, while the latter declined heavily: the same holds true by considering the relations between PM, PAE/TE and TPS/GDP ratios (Table 7). The most intuitive explanation of these results may refer to the traditional mutual autonomy between the British public administration and party politics. However, this interpretation risks overlooking the scarce reliability of data on British parties. In fact, public support to the expansion of public administration is confirmed by data, as positive results are observed if we move from internal party organizations to their external ones (the PAE:PVPM is r = 0.77, the PAE/TE:PVPM is r = 0.73 and the TPS/GDP:PVPM is r = 0.82). The same holds true by focusing on the total number of voters at the national elections – an indicator that may somewhat register the level of citizens’ consensus towards party politics. The second phase (1980–2010) was characterized by a hollowing out process of both public administration and party organizations, although the changes in the former were launched in the early 80s (under Thatcher's government), while party change was more pronounced after Blair's victory, in 1997. The co-evolution is confirmed by the linear relation PAE:PM (r = 0.71) as well as by the relation between PAE/TE:PM (r = 0.94). The number of PVT decreased dramatically from 1990 to 2000 in parallel with diminishing of TPS/GDP, while it started to grow again in the aftermath of the 2008 economic crisis, which brought a significant increase in both PAE and TPS/GDP – whose levels, in 2010, were similar to those registered in 1980.

Table 7. Linear relations between the size of public administration and party change (r – values) in the UK and Italy

The results registered for the Italian case are less controversial. During the first phase (1950–1990) – characterized by the constant expansion of public administration and the high politicization of public service – data confirm the parallel dimensional increase in the size of both public administration and party organizations (PAE:PM r = 0.72; PAE/TE:PM r = 0.73 and TPS/GDP:PM r = 0.84). In the heydays of particracy, the widespread consensus towards public administration expansion is confirmed by the linear relations PAE:PVT (r = 0.97), PAE/TE:PVT (r = 0.98) and TPS/GDP:PVT (r = 0.97). These results are also supported when we focus our observations on the aggregate number of PVT raised by the analysed parties. In contrast, while the ratio of PAE/TE has been increasing, the ratios of PM/PVT and PM/PVPM have been declining during the whole period, due to the progressive contraction of parties' internal face.

During the second phase (1990–2010), both the political and the institutional spheres shared a similar rhetoric: public administration and parties were both urged to be reformed towards more ‘thin’ and ‘effective’ models. Despite changes in the party system, they were more blatant than those experienced by public administration, data on PM and PV followed a similar trajectory as those of PAE/TE. In fact, both the internal and external faces of the Italian parties reduced their dimensions, in parallel with the downturn of public administration.

Conclusions

The aim of this article was to investigate to what extent the evolution in the size of party organizations and in the size of public administration has followed similar trajectories in the United Kingdom and Italy, from 1950 to 2010. By relying on a new-institutional approach to organization theory, the research adopted a most different systems design, by combining qualitative analysis and descriptive statistics. We expected that the expansion/contraction in the size of public administration ran in parallel to the expansion/contraction in the size of parties' internal (PM) and external (voters) faces.

Our findings confirm that parties' external face expands when public spending and the number of public employees increase, and vice-versa. The same holds for parties' internal face, in the Italian case. However, changes in the size of public administration and in the size of parties' internal organization follow less predictable patterns in the British case, as the number of PM decreased even during the expansionary phase of public administration.

In conclusion, evidence from the two cases suggests that some kind of co-evolution between changes in party organization and public administration is observable. Further theoretical refinements and comparative empirical research based on other cases (whether most different or most similar) could help to verify or falsify the validity of this preliminary assumption.

Author ORCIDs

Eugenio Pizzimenti, 0000-0003-1854-2265

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank the two anonymous reviewers for their precious comments.

Financial support

The research received no grants from public, commercial or non-profit funding agency.

Data

The replication dataset is available at http://thedata.harvard.edu/dvn/dv/ipsr-risp

Footnotes

1 See Hopkin and Paolucci (Reference Hopkin and Paolucci1999); Calise (Reference Calise2000); Webb and Poguntke (Reference Webb and Poguntke2005); Passarelli (Reference Passarelli2015).

2 See Dalton and Wattenberg (Reference Dalton and Wattenberg2002); Mair and van Biezen (Reference Mair and van Biezen2001); Hazan and Rahat (Reference Hazan and Rahat2010); Cross and Pilet (Reference Cross and Pilet2015); Scarrow et al. (Reference Scarrow, Poguntke and Webb2017).

3 See Lanzalaco (Reference Lanzalaco1995); Scott (Reference Scott1995); Hall and Taylor (Reference Hall and Taylor1996).

4 See Katz and Mair (Reference Katz and Mair1994); (Reference Katz and Mair1995); (Reference Katz and Mair2009). For a criticism of the cartel party model see Koole (Reference Koole1996); Poguntke (Reference Poguntke and Bardi2006).

5 See Dalton and Wattenberg (Reference Dalton and Wattenberg2002); Scarrow (Reference Scarrow2006); Scarrow and Burcu (Reference Scarrow and Burcu2010); van Biezen et al. (Reference van Biezen, Mair and Poguntke2011).

6 For a classification see Rouban (Reference Rouban, Peters and Pierre2012).

7 See also Baldini (Reference Baldini2013).

References

Ackroyd, S, Kirkpatrick, I and Walker, RM (2007) Public management reform in the UK and its consequences for professional organization: a comparative analysis. Public Administration 85, 926. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9299.2007.00631.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldini, G (2013) Le riforme istituzionali: tra attori e veti, tradizioni e cultura politica. Polis (bologna, Italy) 27, 205230. https://doi.org/10.1424/74448Google Scholar
Bale, T (2012) The Conservatives Since 1945: The Drivers of Party Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bale, T (2016) The Conservative Party: From Thatcher to Cameron. Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Bardi, L and Morlino, L (1992) Italia. In Katz, R and Mair, P (eds), Party Organizations. London: Sage, pp. 458618.Google Scholar
Bardi, L, Ignazi, P and Massari, O (eds) (2007) I partiti italiani. Iscritti, dirigenti, letti. Milano: Egea.Google Scholar
Bardi, L, Calossi, E and Pizzimenti, E (2017) Which face comes first? The ascendancy of the party in public office. In Scarrow, SE, Webb, PD and Poguntke, T (eds), Organizing Political Parties Representation, Participation, and Power. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 6283.Google Scholar
Blais, A, Blake, D and Dion, S (1993) Do parties make a difference? Parties and the size of government in liberal democracies. American Journal of Political Science 37, 4062. https://doi.org/10.2307/2111523CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, M and Pasquino, G (2007) A long quest in vain: institutional reforms in Italy. West European Politics 30, 670691. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402380701500223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, M and Rhodes, M (1997) Crisis and transition in Italian Politics in the 1990s. West European Politics 20, 113. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402389708425172CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calise, M (2000) Il partito personale. Roma-Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Capano, G (2000) Le politiche amministrative. Dall'improbabile riforma alla riforma permanente? In Di Palma, G, Fabbrini, S and Freddi, G (eds), Condannata al successo? Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 153198.Google Scholar
Capano, G (2003) Administrative traditions and policy change: when policy paradigms matter. The case of Italian administrative reform during the 1990s. Public Administration 81, 781801. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0033-3298.2003.00371.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capano, G and Gualmini, E (2006) La pubblica amministrazione in Italia. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Cassese, S (1974) La formazione dello stato amministrativo. Milano: Giuffrè.Google Scholar
Clark, A (2012) Political Parties in the UK. Basingstoke: Palgrave-McMillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cotta, M and Isernia, P (eds) (1996) Il gigante dai piedi di argilla. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Cross, WP and Pilet, JB (2015) (eds) The Politics of Party Leadership Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crouch, C (2001) Welfare state regimes and industrial relations: The questionable role of path dependency theory. In Ebbinghaus, B and Manow, P (eds) Comparing Welfare Capitalism. London: Routledge, pp. 105124.Google Scholar
Dahlstrom, C (2012) Politics and administration. In Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds), The Sage Handbook of Public Administration. London: Sage, pp. 361367.Google Scholar
Dalton, RJ and Wattenberg, MP (eds) (2002) Parties Without Partisans: Political Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Maggio, PJ and Powell, WW (1983) The iron cage revisited: collective rationality and institutional isomorphism in organizational fields. American Sociological Review 2, 147160. https://doi.org/10.2307/2095101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Mascio, F (2013) Partiti e Stato in Italia. Le nomine pubbliche tra clientelismo e spoils system. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Esping-Andersen, G (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Farnham, D and Horton, S (1996) Managing the New Public Services. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrera, M (1986) Italy. In Flora, P (ed.), Growth to Limits: The Western European Welfare States Since World War II. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 388482.Google Scholar
Ferrera, M (2008) The european welfare state: golden achievements, silver prospects. West European Politics 31, 82107. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402380701833731CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrera, M (2014) Ideology, parties and social politics in Europe. West European Politics 37, 420438. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2014.887872CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrera, M (2018) Mass democracy, the welfare state and European integration: a neo-Weberian analysis. European Journal of Social Theory 37, 118. https://doi.org/10.1177/1368431018779176Google Scholar
Ferrera, M and Gualmini, E (2004) Rescued by Europe?, Social and Labour Market Reforms in Italy From the First Republic to Berlusconi. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.Google Scholar
Fesler, JW (1990) The state and its study: The whole and the parts. In Lynn, NB and Wildavsky, A (eds). Public Administration: The State of the Discipline. Chatam, NJ: Chatam House Publishers, pp. 8486.Google Scholar
Flora, P (ed) (1986) Growth to Limits: The Western European Welfare States Since World War II. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Greenwood, R, Oliver, C, Sahlin, K and Suddaby, R (2013) Introduction. In Greenwood, R, Oliver, C, Sahlin, K and Suddaby, R (eds), The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. London: Sage, pp. 146.Google Scholar
Hall, PA and Taylor, RC (1996) Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Political Studies 44, 936957. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9248.1996.tb00343.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harmel, R (2006) Spiegazioni concorrenti (o complementari) del mutamento organizzativo. In Bardi, L (ed.), Partiti e sistemi di partito. Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 123141.Google Scholar
Hassel, A (2001) The governance of the employment-welfare relationship in Britain and Germany. In Ebbinghaus, B and Manow, P (eds) Comparing Welfare Capitalism. London: Routledge, pp. 146168.Google Scholar
Hazan, RY and Rahat, G (2010) Democracy Within Parties: Candidate Selection Methods and Their Political Consequences. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellmann, O (2011) Political Parties and Electoral Strategy: The Development of Party Organization in East Asia. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoggett, P (1996) New modes of control in the public services. Public Administration 74, 932. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9299.1996.tb00855.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkin, J and Paolucci, C (1999) The business firm model of party organisation: Cases from Spain and Italy. European Journal of Political Research 35, 307339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hult, KM (2012) Environmental perspective on public institutions. In Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds), The Sage Handbook of Public Administration. London: Sage, pp. 193205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Husted, E (2018) Some have ideologies, we have values’: the relationship between organizational values and commitment in a political party. Culture and Organization. https://doi.org/10.1080/14759551.2018.1518325Google Scholar
Ignazi, P (2002) Il potere dei partiti. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Ignazi, P (2012) Forza senza legittimità. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Ignazi, P (2017) Parties and democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ignazi, P and Pizzimenti, E (2014) Finanziamento pubblico e mutamenti organizzativi nei partiti italiani. Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica 2, 199235. https://doi.org/10.1426/34966.Google Scholar
Istituto Centrale di Statistica, (1976) Sommario di statistiche storiche dell'Italia 1861-1975. https://ebiblio.istat.it/digibib/Sommario%20Statistiche20Storiche/TO00159260Sommario_statistiche_storiche_Italia_1861_1975.pdf.Google Scholar
Karthikeyan, S, Jonsson, S and Wezel, FC (2016) The travails of identity change: competitor claims and distinctiveness of British Political Parties, 1970–1992. Organization Science 27, 106122. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2015.1013Google Scholar
Katz, R (1986) Party government: A rationalistic conception. In Castels, FG and Wildenmann, R (eds), Visions and Reality of Party Government. Berlin: de Gruyter, pp. 3171.Google Scholar
Katz, R (2006) Agenti di chi? Princìpi, committenti e politica dei partiti. In Bardi, L (ed.), Partiti e sistemi di partito. Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 5979.Google Scholar
Katz, R and Mair, P (eds) (1992) Party Organizations. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Katz, R and Mair, P (1994) How Parties Organize. Change and Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democracies. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Katz, R and Mair, P (1995) Changing models of party organisation and party democracy: the emergence of the cartel party. Party Politics 1, 528. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068895001001001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, R and Mair, P (2009) The cartel party thesis revisited. Perspective on Politics 7, 753766. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592709991782CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keen, R and Audickas, L (2017) Membership of UK political parties. House of Commons Library Briefing, Paper SN05125. Available at file:///C:/Users/Utente/Downloads/SN05125.pdfGoogle Scholar
Kelly, R (2003) Organizational reform and the extra-parliamentary party. In Garnett, M and Lynch, P (eds), Conservatives in Crisis. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 82106.Google Scholar
Koole, R (1996) Cadre, catch-all or cartel? A comment on the notion of the cartel party. Party Politics 2, 507523. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068896002004004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lanzalaco, L (1995) Istituzioni, organizzazioni, potere. Introduzione all'analisi istituzionale della politica. Roma: NIS.Google Scholar
Lawler, J and Hearn, J (1995) UK public sector organizations: the rise of managerialism and the impact of change on social services departments. International Journal of Public Sector Management 8, 716. https://doi.org/10.1108/09513559510096237CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, C (1977) Politics and Markets. NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Mair, P (2005) Democracy Beyond Parties. Centre for the Study of Democracy, Paper 05'06. Available at http://cadmus.eui.eu/bitstream/handle/1814/3291/viewcontent.pdfGoogle Scholar
Mair, P and van Biezen, I (2001) Party Membership in Twenty European Democracies, 1980-2000. Party Politics 7, 521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, JG and Olsen, JP (1983) The new institutionalism: organizational factors in political life. American Political Science Review 78, 734749. https://doi.org/10.2307/1961840CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, JG and Olsen, JP (1989) Rediscovering Institutions. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Melis, G (1995) L'amministrazione. In Romanelli, R (ed.) Storia Dello Stato Italiano. Roma: Donzelli, pp. 187251.Google Scholar
Melis, G (1996) Storia dell'amministrazione italiana: 1861–1993. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Melis, G (2014) Fare lo Stato per fare gli italiani. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Meyer, JW and Rowan, B (1977) Institutionalized organizations: formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology 83, 340363. https://doi.org/10.2307/2778293CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, JW and Scott, WR (1983) Organizational Environment: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills: Sage.Google Scholar
Ministero dell'Economia e delle Finanze (2011) La spesa dello Stato dall'Unità d'Italia. Studi e pubblicazioni. Available at http://www.rgs.mef.gov.it/_Documenti/VERSIONE-I/Pubblicazioni/Studi-e-do/La-spesa-dello-stato/La_spesa_dello_Stato_dall_unit_d_Italia.pdfGoogle Scholar
Minkin, L (2014) The Blair Supremacy: A Study in the Politics of Labour's Party Management. Manchester: MUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nardi, PM (2018) Doing Survey Research. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, P (2018) Ministers, departments and civil servants. In Jones, B, Norton, P and Daddow, O (eds), Politics UK. London: Routledge, pp. 462483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palmer, D, Biggart, N and Dick, B (2013) Is the new institutionalism a theory? In Greenwood, R, Oliver, C, Sahlin, K and Suddaby, R (eds), The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. London: Sage, pp. 739768.Google Scholar
Panebianco, A (1982) Modelli di partito. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Parry, R (1986) United Kingdom. In Flora, P (ed) (1986) Growth to Limits: The Western European Welfare States Since World War II. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 156240.Google Scholar
Pasquino, G (2002) Il sistema politico italiano. Bologna: Bononia University Press.Google Scholar
Passarelli, G (ed) (2015) The Presidentialization of Political Parties. London: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds) (2004) The Politicization of the Civil Service in Comparative Perspective: The Quest for Control. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfeffer, J and Salancik, GR (1978) The External Control of Organizations. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Pizzimenti, E (2017) The evolution of party funding in Italy: a case of inclusive cartelisation? Modern Italy 22, 7185. https://doi.org/10.1017/mit.2016.40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poggi, G (1978) La vicenda dello stato moderno: profilo sociologico. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Poguntke, T (2006) Ci sono prove empiriche a sostegno della tesi del cartel party? Partiti e società nell'Europa occidentale. In Bardi, L (ed.), Partiti e sistemi di partito. Bologna: Il Mulino, pp. 103121.Google Scholar
Poguntke, T and Webb, P (eds) (2007) The presidentialization of politics: A comparative study of modern democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pollitt, C and Bouckaert, G (2011) Public Management Reform. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, WW and Di Maggio, PJ (eds) (1991) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rouban, L (2012) Politicization of the civil service. In Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds) The Sage Handbook of Public Administration. London: Sage, pp. 380391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rugge, F (2012) Administrative legacies in Western Europe. In Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds), The Sage Handbook of Public Administration. London: Sage, pp. 228240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rye, D (2018) Political parties. In Jones, B, Norton, P and Daddow, O (eds), Politics UK. London: Routledge, pp. 254278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarrow, S (2006) Beyond Party Members: Changing Approaches to Partisan Mobilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scarrow, S and Burcu, G (2010) Declining members, changing members. European political party members in a New Era. Party Politics 16, 832–43. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068809346078CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarrow, S, Poguntke, T and Webb, P (eds) (2017) Organizing Political Parties. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarrow, S, Archury, S, Kosiara-Pedersen, K and van Haute, E (2018) The consequences of membership incentives: do greater political benefits attract different kinds of members? Party Politics 20, 113. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068818754603Google Scholar
Scoppola, P (1996) La repubblica dei partiti: evoluzione e crisi di un sistema politico: 1945–1996. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Scott, WR (1995) Istituzioni e organizzazioni. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Scott, WR (2008) Le organizzazioni. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Seyd, Ñ and Whiteley, N (1992) Labour's Grassroots: The Politics of Party Membership. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Seyd, Ñ and Whiteley, N (2004) British party members: an overview. Party Politics 10, 355366. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068804043903CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skelcher, C (2000) Changing images of the state: overloaded, hollowed-out, congested. Public Policy and Administration 15, 319. https://doi.org/10.1177/095207670001500302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, G (1991) In search of small parties: Problems of definition, classification and significance. In Müller-Rommel, F and Pridham, G (eds), Small Parties in Western Europe: Comparative and National Perspective. London: Sage, pp. 2340.Google Scholar
Steinmo, S (1993) Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tan, AC (1998) The impacts of party membership size: a cross-national analysis. The Journal of Politics 60, 188198. https://doi.org/10.2307/2648007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thoenig, JC (2012) Intitutional Theories and Public Institutions: New Agendas and Appropriateness. In Peters, BG and Pierre, J (eds). The Sage Handbook of Public Administration. London: Sage, pp. 169179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Biezen, I (2004) Political parties as public utilities. Party Politics 10, 701722. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068804046914CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Biezen, I and Kopecky, P (2014) The cartel party and the state: party-state linkages in European Democracies. Party Politics 20, 170182. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068813519961CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Biezen, I, Mair, P and Poguntke, T (2011) Going, going,…gone? The decline of party membership in Contemporary Europe. European Journal of Political Research 51, 2456. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2011.01995.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vassallo, S and Passarelli, G (2016) Centre-left Prime Ministerial Primaries in Italy: the laboratory of the ‘open party’ model. Contemporary Italian Politics 8, 1223. https://doi.org/10.1080/23248823.2016.1152005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Beyme, K (1987) I partiti nelle democrazie occidentali. Bologna: Zanichelli.Google Scholar
Webb, P (1992) United Kingdom. In Katz, R and Mair, P (eds), Party Organizations. London: Sage. pp. 837870.Google Scholar
Webb, P (1995) Reforming the party-union link: An assessment. In Broughton, D, Farrell, D, Denver, D and Railings, C (eds), British Parties and Elections Yearbook 1994. London: Frank Cass, pp. 114.Google Scholar
Webb, P (2000) The Modern British Party System. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Webb, P (2002) Political parties in Britain. In Webb, P, Farrell, D and Holliday, I (eds), Political Parties in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 1644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Webb, P and Poguntke, T (eds) (2005) The Presidentialization of Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, M (1947) The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. The politico-administrative system in Italy and the UK

Figure 1

Table 2. UK: the evolution of public administration (1950–2010)

Figure 2

Table 3. UK: the evolution of party internal and external organizations (1950–2010)

Figure 3

Table 4. Italy: the evolution of public administration (1950–2010)

Figure 4

Table 5. Italy: the evolution of party internal and external organizations (1950–2010)

Figure 5

Table 6. Administrative and party change in the UK and Italy (1950–2010)

Figure 6

Table 7. Linear relations between the size of public administration and party change (r – values) in the UK and Italy