Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-cx56b Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-11T17:46:25.111Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Incentive-Based Solutions to Agricultural Environmental Problems: Recent Developments in Theory and Practice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Alan Randall
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural, Environmental, and Developmental Economics, The Ohio State University
Michael A. Taylor
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural, Environmental, and Developmental Economics, The Ohio State University

Abstract

Theory predicts that incentive-based regulatory instruments reduce compliance costs by encouraging efficient resource allocation and innovation in environmental technology. Cost reductions from pollution permit trading often have exceeded expectations, but the devil is in the details: the rules matter. In recent years, IB instruments of many kinds, from permit trading to various informal voluntary agreements, have been introduced in many countries. Point-nonpoint trading programs have been established in the U.S., but recorded trades have been rare. We speculate about prospects for performance-based monitoring of agricultural nonpoint pollution which, we believe, would encourage trading to the benefit of farmers and society.

Type
Invited Paper Sessions
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Atkinson, Scott E. and Lewis, Donald H.. “A Cost-Effectiveness Analysis of Alternative Air Quality Control Strategies.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 1, no. 3(November 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burtraw, Dallas. “The S02 Emissions Trading Program: Cost Savings Without Allowance Trades.” Contemporary Economic Policy Vol. 14, April 1996, pp. 7994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlson, Dale A., and Sholtz, Anne M.. “Designing Pollution Market Instruments: Cases of Uncertainty.” Contemporary Economic Policy Vol. 12, October 1994, pp. 114125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D.The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems.” in The Economics of Air Pollution, ed. Wolozin, Harold. 1966.Google Scholar
Dales, J.H.Pollution, Property, and Prices. University of Toronto Press. Toronto, Canada. 1968.Google Scholar
Davies, J. Clarence and Mazurek, Jan. Regulating Pollution. Does the U.S. System Work? Resources for the Future. Washington, DC 1997Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K., and Pindyck, Robert S.. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. 1994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Environment Australia (EA). “Environmental Incentives Australian Experience with Economic Instruments for Environmental Management.” Environmental Economics Research Paper No. 5 Canberra, Commonwealth of Australia (1997)Google Scholar
Environmental Law Institute. “Wetland Mitigation Banking: Fingertip Facts.” National Wetlands Newsletter. January-February p. 3 (1998)Google Scholar
European Environment Agency (EEA). “Environmental Agreements, Environmental Effectiveness.” Environmental Issues Series. Vol. 1 No. 3Copenhagen, Denmark. (1997)Google Scholar
Gannon, Rich. North Carolina Water Quality Commission. Personal Telephone Conversation. May 13, 1997Google Scholar
Govindasamay, Ramu, Herriges, Joseph A., and Shogren, Jason. “Nonpoint Tournaments.” in Non-point Source Pollution Regulation: Issues and Analysis. Kluwer Academic Publishers. Dordrecht, Netherlands, 1994.Google Scholar
Griffin, R., and Bromley, D.. “Agricultural Runoff as a Nonpoint Externality.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 64 pp. 547552(1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Robert W.A New Approach to the Design of Regulation in the Presence of Multiple ObjectivesJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 17, 195211(1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Robert W. and Noll, Roger G.. “Designing a Market for Tradable Emission Permits.” in Reform of Environmental Regulation, ed. Magat, Wesley A.. Ballinger Cambridge, MA 1982Google Scholar
Hall, John C, and Howett, Ciannat M.. “Guide to Establishing a Point/Nonpoint Source Pollution Reduction Trading System for Basinwide Water Quality Management: The Tar-Pamlico River Basin Experience” Report to North Carolina Department of Environment, Health, and Natural Resources, Division of Environmental Management, Water Quality Section. EPA-904-95-900(July 1995)Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., Schmalensee, Richard, and Bailey, Elizabeth M.. “The Market of Sulfur Dioxide Emissions.” The American Economic Review 88 No 4(1998):669685.Google Scholar
Keohane, Nathaniel O., Revesz, Richard L., and Stavins, Robert N.. “The Positive Political Economy of Instrument Choice in Environmental Policy.” Resources For the Future Discussion Paper 97-25. (1997)Google Scholar
Krupnick, Alan J., Oates, Wallace E., and Verg, Eric Van De. “On Marketable Air-Pollution Permits: The Case for a System of Pollution Offsets.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10, 233247 (1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Letson, David. “Point/Nonpoint Source Trading of Pollution Reduction Trading: An Interpretative Survey.” Natural Resources Journal 32 pp. 219232. (1992)Google Scholar
Malik, Aran S., Letson, David, and Crutchfield, Stephen R.. “Point/Nonpoint Source Trading of Pollution Abatement: Choosing the Right Trading Ratio.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75 (November 1993):959967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsh, Lindeil L., Porter, Douglas R., and Salvesen, David A.. “Introduction and Overview.” in Mitigation Banking—Theory and Practice. The Island Press, Washington, DC 1996.Google Scholar
Mendelsohn, Robert. “Regulating Heterogeneous Emissions.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 13 (December 1986):301312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGartland, Albert. “A Comparison of Two Marketable Discharge Permit Systems.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15, 3544 (1988).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGartland, Albert M., and Oates, Wallace E.. “Marketable Permits for the Prevention of Environmental Deterioration.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 12, 207228 (1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, David W.Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs.” Journal of Economic Theory 5, 395418 (1972).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The National Action Plan to Implement the Hydrogeomorphic Approach to Assessing Wetland Functions.” Federal Register, June 20, 1997, 62:119Google Scholar
Netusil, N.R., and Braden, J.B.. “Market and bargaining approaches to nonpoint source pollution abatement problems.” Water Science Technology 28 (June, 1995): pp. 3545CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Economic Instruments for Pollution Control and Natural Resources Management in OECD Countries: A Survey. ENV7 EPOC/GEEI(98)35/REVl/FINAL Paris. 1999.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C.The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan. 1920.Google Scholar
Porter, Michael E., and Linde, Claas van der. “Toward a New Conception of the Environment-Competitiveness Relationship.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, No. 4 Fall 1995. pp. 97118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Purvis, A.Boggess, W.G., Moss, C.B., and Holt, J.. “Technology Adoption Decisions Under Irreversibility and Uncertainty: An Ex Ante Approach.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 No. 3 pp. 541551 August 1995CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randall, Alan. “Whose Losses Count? Examining Some Claims About Aggregation Rules for Natural Resources Damages.” Contemporary Economic Policy 15(4), 1997. pp.8897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randall, Alan. “A New Look at the Old Problem of Externalities.” Choices (1st quarter), 1999. pp. 2932.Google Scholar
Rasmusen, Eric. “Moral Hazard in Risk-Averse Teams.” Rand Journal of Economics, 18, 1987. pp. 428–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roach, Fred, Kolstad, Charles, Knesse, Allen V., Tobin, Richard, and Williams, Michael. “Alternative Air Quality Policy Options in the Four Corners Region.” Southwest Review 1, no. 2 (Summer 1981)Google Scholar
Segerson, Kathleen. “Uncertainty and Incentives for Nonpoint Pollution Control.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15, pp. 8798. (1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segerson, Kathleen. “Liability for groundwater contamination from pesticides.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 19 No. 3 pp. 227243. (1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segerson, Kathleen, and Miceli, Thomas J.. “Voluntary Environmental Agreements: Good or Bad News for Environmental Protection?Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 36 No. 2 pp. 109130. (1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seskin, Eugene P., Anderson, Robert J. Jr., and Reid, Robert O.. “An Empirical Analysis of Economic Strategies for Controlling Air Pollution.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10, no. 2 (June 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singleton Shire Council (SSC). State of the Environment Report 1999. (Online Document) http://www.singleton.nsw.gov.au/environ/SE099/aqul2.htmGoogle Scholar
Smith, David. US Environmental Protection Agency, Region 9. Personal Telephone Conversation. August 5, 1997Google Scholar
Stavins, Robert N., and Whitehead, Bradley W.. “The Next Generation of Market-Based Environmental Policies.” Resources For the Future Discussion Paper 97-10. (1997)Google Scholar
Sutliff, Jim. Ohio Wetlands Foundation. Personal Phone Conversation. August 12, 1997Google Scholar
Tietenberg, T.H.Emissions Trading: an exercise in reforming pollution policy. Resources for the Future, Inc. Washington, D.C. 1985CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomasi, Theodore, Segerson, Kathleen, and Braden, John. “Issues in the Design of Incentive Schemes for Nonpoint Source Pollution Control” in Nonpoint Source Pollution Regulation: Issues and Analysis Kluwer Academic Publishers Dordrecht, Netherlands. 1994. pp. 137Google Scholar
United States Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Draft Framework for Watershed-Based Trading. EPA 800-R-96-001, Government Publications Office Washington, DC 1996Google Scholar
United States General Accounting Office (US-GAO). Water Pollution: Pollutant Trading Could Reduce Compliance Costs If Uncertainties Are Resolved. Report to the Chairman, Committee on Public Works and Transportation, House of Representatives. Washington, DC 1992.Google Scholar