Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-x5cpj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-31T07:14:10.093Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

“A Just and Profitable Commerce”: Moral Economy and the Middle Classes in Eighteenth-Century London

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 January 2014

Extract

It has been twenty years since E. P. Thompson introduced the term “moral economy” into the historian's vocabulary. Since then it has exerted a paradigmatic force in explanations of the motivations for, and responses to, various forms of popular action. Pitted against this has been the notion of political economy, most often presented as a subsequent (and eventually triumphant) ideological development that was necessarily antithetical to a moral economy. Together these two models have served as fundamental reference points around which accounts of popular protest and public policy have been constructed. Recent explorations into past assumptions regarding the proper functioning of the marketplace have served to open this conventional schematization to debate. Thompson himself has once again entered the fray with a further refinement and restatement of his original arguments and a spirited riposte to his critics. The purpose of the following essay is to focus and further develop this debate in light of the author's ongoing research into the City of London in the late eighteenth century.

In seeking to loosen the constructs through which past economic relations and ideologies have been characterized, this essay will concentrate on two main areas of enquiry. The first follows the work of other historians in attempting to probe more deeply into the diverse and often conflicting understandings of the marketplace articulated in this period, thus revealing alternate possibilities in the interstices of moral economy and political economy. The second as yet remains relatively unexplored and concerns a series of assumptions as to who might be expected to advocate these various conceptions of market relations and why.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © North American Conference of British Studies 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Thompson, E. P., “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Century,” Past and Present, no. 50 (1971), pp. 76136Google Scholar.

2 Bohstedt, John, Riots and Community Politics in England and Wales, 1790–1810 (Cambridge, Mass., 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Claeys, Greg, Machinery, Money and the Millennium (Cambridge, 1987)Google Scholar; Reddy, William, The Rise of Market Culture (Cambridge, Mass., 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thompson, E. P., “The Moral Economy Reviewed,” in his Customs in Common (London, 1991), 259351Google Scholar.

3 Thompson cautions against this in “The Moral Economy Reviewed,” p. 288.

4 By using the phrase “middling sort,” I am deliberately adopting a loose terminology in order to leave room for an exploration of the various identities subscribed to by those who might be included under this broad category—anyone from the skilled artisan to the financier.

5 Wells, Roger, Wretched Faces: Famine in Wartime England, 1793–1801 (Gloucester, 1988)Google Scholar.

6 Stevenson, John, Popular Disturbances in England, 1700–1870 (London, 1979), p. 92Google Scholar; Stern, Walter M., “The Bread Crisis in Britain, 1795–96,” Economica 31 (1964): 168–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gourvish, T. R., “A Note on Bread Prices in London and Glasgow, 1788–1815,” Journal of Economic History 30 (1970): 854–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Wells, , Wretched Faces, p. 60Google Scholar; Schwarz, L. D., “The Standard of Living in the Long Run: London, 1700–1860,” Economic History Review, 2d ser., 38 (1985): 3941Google Scholar.

8 41 Geo. III, c. 16.

9 Poynter, J. R., Society and Pauperism: English Ideas on Poor Relief (London, 1969)Google Scholar; Andrew, D. T., Philanthropy and Police: London Charity in the Eighteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Reports of the Society for Bettering the Condition of the Poor (London, 17981808)Google Scholar.

10 Girdler, J. S., Observations on the Pernicious Consequences of Forestalling, Regrating and Ingrossing (London, 1800)Google Scholar.

11 On marketing offenses, see Westerfield, R. B., Middlemen in English Business (1915; reprint, New York, 1968)Google Scholar; Fay, C. R., The Corn Laws and Social England (Cambridge, 1932)Google Scholar; Barnes, D. G., History of the English Corn Laws (London, 1930)Google Scholar.

12 Girdler; The Times (February 27, March 10, July 28, December 27, 1800); Wells, p. 84. Douglas Hay, in a forthcoming Past and Present article, considers the course of arguments in the courts during this period regarding market regulation.

13 See [Jones, P. E.], The Corporation of London: Its Origins, Constitution, Powers and Duties (London, 1950), pp. 135–48Google Scholar; Pulling, Alexander, A Practical Treatise on the Laws, Customs and Regulations of the City of London (London, 1842), p. 403Google Scholar; notes relating to city markets, Corporation of London Record Office (CLRO) Misc. MSS 90.8; Alchin's Market Collection, CLRO 113A.

14 Resolutions of master butchers at a meeting at the Nag's Head Tavern, August 1, 1786, CLRO MSS 353.2.

15 Minutes and papers of the Committee regarding the High Price of Provisions and the Control of Markets, 1786–88, CLRO MSS 118.2.

16 Pulling, p. 405; Chartres, J., “The Marketing of Agricultural Produce,” in Agrarian Change, ed. Thirsk, J., vol. 5Google Scholar, pt. 2., of The Agrarian History of England and Wales, ed. Finberg, H. P. R. (Cambridge, 1985), pp. 406502Google Scholar; Parliamentary Papers, 1801, vol. 2, Seventh Report of House of Commons Select Committee on the Corn Trade.

17 Webb, S. and Webb, B., “The Assize of Bread,” Economic Journal 54 (1904): 196208CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thrupp, Sylvia, The Worshipful Company of Bakers: A Short History (London, 1933)Google Scholar; Ross, A. S. C., “The Assize of Bread,” Economic History Review 2 (1956/1957): 332–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Morning Chronicle, January 24, 1795; Common Hall Book, vol. 9, fol. 50.

19 Minutes of the Committee to Consider the Best Means of Reducing the High Price of Provisions, 1795, CLRO Misc. MSS 113.3.

20 Minutes of Evidence taken before the Lords of His Majesty's Most Honourable Privy Council respecting the Stock of Grain in this Country” (1795), in House of Commons Sessional Papers of the Eighteenth Century, ed. Lambert, S. (Wilmington, Del., 1975), 99:46Google Scholar; Common Council Journal (CCJ), vol. 75, fols. 238, 239.

21 CCJ, vol. 75, fols. 244–46.

22 Journals of the House of Commons, vol. 51, pp. 19, 92, 197, 206–13Google Scholar.

23 Minutes of the Court of Aldermen Committee to Consider the Assize of Bread, 1795, CLRO Sm. MS box 4, no. 7.

24 Tann, J., “Co-operative Corn Milling,” Agricultural History Review 28 (1980): 4557Google Scholar; Westworth, O. A., “Albion Steam Flour Mills,” Economic History (1932): 380–95Google Scholar.

25 CLRO Misc. MSS 113.3.

26 Minutes of the Committee for Erecting Public Mills, 1798–1803, CLRO Misc. MSS 119.2.

27 Representation of the millers in the vicinity of London (London, 1800)Google Scholar.

28 CLRO Misc. MSS 119.2; Parliamentary History, vol. 35, col. 455; Parliamentary Papers, 1801, vol. 1, pt. 1, “Account presented to the House of Commons from the London Company for the Manufacture of Flour, Meal and Bread.”

29 CCJ, vol. 79, fol. 60.

30 Minutes and papers of the Committee to Enquire into the High Price of Provisions, 1800–1802, CLRO MSS 94.24.

31 Report of the committee on the High Price of Provisions, 1801, CLRO, Papers, Accounts, Reports, bk. 2, fol. 295.

32 Wells (n. 5 above), p. 86; Girdler (n. 10 above).

33 Court of Aldermen Repertory (CA Rep) 204, CLRO, fol. 412.

34 CCJ, vol. 79, fols. 197–99; CA Rep 204, fols. 414–33; Wells, pp. 120–32.

35 CCJ, vol. 79, fols. 215–16.

36 Wells, p. 243; Sixth Report from the Committee to Consider the High Price of Provisions” (1800), in House of Commons Sessional Papers, 131:438Google Scholar.

37 Parliamentary History, vol. 35, cols. 789, 793.

38 CLRO PAR bk. 2, 295.

39 The Times (December 27, 1800).

40 In “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd” (n. 1 above), p. 91, Thompson himself suggests that in practice the eighteenth-century corn trade offered empirical verification for neither “pure” model of market relations.

41 Hont, I. and Ignatieff, M., “Needs and Justice in the Wealth of Nations,” in their Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment (Cambridge, 1983), p. 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wells (n. 5 above), p. 80.

42 The Times (August 1, 1800).

43 The Times (December 27, 1800). While most “interventionist” commentators agreed that the state had the right to ensure a fair price for articles of sustenance, the communitarian emphasis of this letter is unusual.

44 Bohstedt (n. 2 above), pp. 208–9, 99; Wells, p. 178; Thompson, , “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd,” p. 129Google Scholar.

45 Bohstedt, p. 209, following on from Rudé, George, “The Growth of Cities and Popular Revolt, 1750–1850,” in French Government and Society, 1500–1850, ed. Bosher, J. F. (London, 1973), pp. 172, 190Google Scholar, acknowledges that the City of London may have been an exception to this typology of urban social relations.

46 Rose, R. B., in his pioneering article “Eighteenth Century Price Riots and Public Policy in England,” International Review of Social History 6 (1961): 291CrossRefGoogle Scholar, suggests that burgess magistrates were primarily concerned with the maintenance of public order; Bohstedt, p. 48.

47 Bohstedt, p. 94.

48 Guildhall Library, London, Noble Collection, “Combe.”

49 Seed, John, “Unitarianism, Political Economy and the Antinomies of Liberal Culture in Manchester, 1830–1850,” Social History 7 (1982): 25CrossRefGoogle Scholar, argues that paternalist elements were not alien to middle-class culture. For an insightful discussion of the varieties of paternalism in early nineteenth-century thought, see Eastwood, David, “Robert Southey and the Intellectual Origins of Romantic Conservatism,” English Historical Review 104 (1989): 308–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 See Hilton, Boyd, The Age of Atonement (Oxford, 1988), 87, 91–92, 98Google Scholar.

51 Coats, A. W., “Contrary Moralities: Plebs, Paternalists and Political Economists,” Past and Present, no. 54 (1972), pp. 130–33Google Scholar; Fox-Genovese, E., “The Many Faces of Moral Economy: A Contribution to a Debate,” Past and Present, no. 58 (1973), pp. 161–68Google Scholar.

52 Hilton; Thompson, , “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd” (n. 1 above), p. 90Google Scholar.

53 Girdler (n. 10 above), p. 255.

54 Thomas Dornford, an activist on the committee for public mills, came from a strong Methodist background; Alderman Paul Lemesurier, who chaired the 1786 committee on abuses at Smithfield market, was a member of both the Society for Propagating the Gospel and the Society for Bettering the Condition of the Poor (SBCP; though the SBCP fits into Hilton's laissez-faire school of evangelicalism); and Alderman Thomas Cadell, who led the inquiry into the exorbitant profits of metropolitan millers, was a director of the Foundling Hospital. See Dornford, Josiah, Some Memoirs of the Life and Death of Mrs Eleanor Dornford, 2d ed. (London, 1805)Google Scholar; Andrew (n. 9 above), app. s.v. “Major Donors.”

55 Thompson, “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd”; Williams, D., “Morals, Markets and the English Crowd in 1766,” Past and Present, no. 104 (1984), pp. 5673Google Scholar.

56 Wells (n. 5 above), p. 328.

57 Going through the lists of the more active members of the Corporation's provisions committees, one finds a stationer, haberdasher, laceman, wax chandler, and attorney. Few committee members had any direct interest in the provisions trade themselves though a tea broker, a grocer, and two seedsmen can be identified among the activists. See CLRO Misc. MSS 118.2, 113.3, 119.2, 94.24, and the following London trade directories: Kent's (London, 17821800)Google Scholar, Lowndes's (London, 1784, 1796)Google Scholar, Universal British (London, 1791)Google Scholar.

58 Waithman, Robert, War Proved to be the Real Cause of the Present Scarcity (London, 1800)Google Scholar.

59 CLRO PAR bk. 2, 295.

60 Journals of the House of Commons, vol. 55, 798.

61 See Wahrman, Dror, “Virtual Representation: Parliamentary Reporting and Languages of Class in the 1790s,” Past and Present, no. 136 (1992), pp. 83113Google Scholar, who argues that a middle-class idiom in the late eighteenth century was a highly contested assertion.

62 Hilton (n. 50 above); Claeys (n. 2 above), chap. 1.

63 The Times (November 10, 1800).