Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-g5fl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-04T06:37:16.172Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

PUSH, PULL, AND POPULATION SIZE EFFECTS IN STRUCTURAL DEVELOPMENT: LONG-RUN TRADE-OFFS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 November 2016

Oksana M. Leukhina*
Affiliation:
University of Washington
Stephen J. Turnovsky
Affiliation:
University of Washington
*
Address correspondence to: Oksana M. Leukhina, Department of Economics, University of Washington, Box 353330, 305 Savery Hall, Seattle, WA 98195; e-mail: oml@u.washington.edu
Get access

Abstract:

The process of structural transformation from the farm to a nonfarm sector is accompanied by technological change in both sectors and massive population growth. We investigate the effects of increasing population size (the population effect) and sector-specific productivity (the push and pull effects), both factor-neutral and factor-biased, in a parsimonious general equilibrium model under general forms of utility and production functions. All three effects may co-exist and interact in important ways. Generalizing the agricultural sector production function to CES is crucial for the population growth effect. Our analysis highlights how the relative importance of the three effects changes as the country develops and production and consumption conditions become more flexible.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron and Guerrieri, Veronica (2008) Capital deepening and non-balanced economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 116 (3), 467498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Robert C. (2009) Engels’ pause: Technical change, capital accumulation, and inequality in the British industrial revolution. Explorations in Economic History 46 (4), 418435.Google Scholar
Alvarez-Cuadrado, Francisco and Poschke, Markus (2011) Structural change out of agriculture: Labor push versus labor pull. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (3), 127158.Google Scholar
Antras, Pol (2004) Is the U.S. aggregate production function Cobb-Douglas? New estimates of the elasticity of substitution. Contributions to Macroeconomics 4 (1), ISSN (Online) 1534–6005, DOI: 10.2202/1534-6005.1161.Google Scholar
Bar, Michael and Leukhina, Oksana (2010) Demographic transition and industrial revolution: A macroeconomic investigation. Review of Economic Dynamics 13 (2), 424451.Google Scholar
Baumol, William (1967) Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: The anatomy of urban crisis. American Economic Review 57 (3), 415426.Google Scholar
Behrman, Jere R. (1972) Sectoral elasticities of substitution between capital and labor in a developing economy: Time series analysis in the case of Postwar Chile. Econometrica 40 (2), 311326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buera, Francisco J. and Kaboski, Joseph P. (2008) Can traditional theories of structural change fit the data? Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (2–3), 469477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caselli, Francesco and Coleman II, Wilbur J. (2001) The U.S. structural transformation and regional convergence: A reinterpretation. Journal of Political Economy 109 (3), 584616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Gregory (2001) The secret history of the industrial revolution. Unpublished Ms.Google Scholar
Crafts, Nicholas Francis Robert (1980) Income elasticities of demand and the release of labor by agriculture during the British industrial revolution: A further appraisal. Journal of European Economic History 9 (1), 153168.Google Scholar
Deane, Phyllis (1969) The First Industrial Revolution. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dennis, Benjamin N. and Iscan, Talan B. (2009) Engel versus Baumol: Accounting for structural change using two centuries of U.S. data. Explorations in Economics History 46 (2), 186202.Google Scholar
Doepke, Matthias (2004) Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of Economic Growth 9 (3), 347383.Google Scholar
Duffy, John and Papageorgiou, Chris (2000) A cross-country empirical investigation of the aggregate production function specification. Journal of Economic Growth 5 (1), 87120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Echevarria, Cristina (1997) Changes in sectoral composition associated with economic growth. International Economic Review 38 (2), 431452.Google Scholar
Galor, O. (2011) Unified Growth Theory. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded and Weil, David N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90 (4), 806828.Google Scholar
Gollin, Douglas and Rogerson, Richard (2014) Productivity, transport costs and subsistence agriculture. Journal of Development Economics 107 (1), 3848.Google Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Jedwab, Remi and Vollrath, Dietrich (2016) Urbanization with and without industrialization. Journal of Economic Growth 21 (1), 3570.Google Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Parente, Stephen and Rogerson, Richard (2007) The food problem and the evolution of international income levels. Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (4), 12301255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollin, Douglas, Parente, Stephen and Rogerson, Richard (2002) The role of agriculture in development. American Economic Review 92 (2), 160164.Google Scholar
Goodfriend, Marvin and McDermott, John (1995) Early development. American Economic Review 85 (1), 116133.Google Scholar
Griliches, Zvi (1963) Estimation of the aggregate agricultural production function from cross-sectional data. Journal of Farm Economics 45 (2), 419428.Google Scholar
Guillo, María Dolores, Papageorgiou, Chris and Perez-Sebastian, Fidel (2011) A unified theory of structural change. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35 (9), 13931404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Gary D. and Prescott, Edward C. (2002) Malthus to solow. American Economic Review 92 (4), 12051217.Google Scholar
Heady, Earl O. and Dillon, John L., (1961) Agricultural Production Functions. Ames, IA: Iowa State University Press.Google Scholar
Herrendorf, Berthold, Schmitz, James A. and Teixeira, Arilton (2012) The role of transportation in US economic development: 1840–1860. International Economic Review 53 (3), 693715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrendorf, Berthold, Herrington, Christopher and Valentinyi, Ákos (2015) Sectoral technology and structural transformation. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7 (4), 104133.Google Scholar
Herrendorf, Berthold, Rogerson, Richard and Valentinyi, Ákos (2014) Growth and structural transformation, In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, Steven N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth vol. 2, pp. 855–941. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Herrendorf, Berthold, Rogerson, Richard and Valentinyi, Ákos (2013) Two perspectives on preferences and structural transformation. American Economic Review, 103 (7), 27522789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klump, Rainer, McAdam, Peter and Willman, Alpo (2007) Factor substitution and factor-augmenting technical progress in the United States: A normalized supply-side system approach. Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1), 183192.Google Scholar
Kongsamut, Piyabha, Rebelo, Sergio and Xie, Danyang (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Review of Economic Studies 68 (4), 849868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kremer, Michael (1993) Population growth and technological change: One million BC to 1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3), 551575.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon (1957) Quantitative aspects of the economic growth of nations: II. Economic Development and Cultural Change 5 (4), 3111.Google Scholar
Laitner, John P. (2000) Structural change and economic growth. Review of Economic Studies 67 (3), 545561.Google Scholar
Leon-Ledesma, Miguel, McAdam, Peter and Willman, Alpo (2010) Identifying the elasticity of substitution with biased technical change. American Economic Review 100 (4), 13301357.Google Scholar
Leukhina, Oksana M. and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2016) Population size effects in the structural development of England. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 8 (3), 195229.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. Arthur (1954) Economic development with unlimited supply of labor. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 22 (2), 139191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoring the World Economy: 1820/1992. Washington: OECD Development Center.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (1992) Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory 58 (2), 317334.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Brian R. (2003a) International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750–2000. 5th ed. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Brian R. (2003b) International Historical Statistics: The Americas, 1750–2000. 5th ed. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1977) Demand vs. supply in the industrial revolution. Journal of Economic History 37 (4), 9811008.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1985) The Economics of the Industrial Revolution. Washington DC: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1993) The British Industrial Revolution. Boulder CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Murphy, Kevin M., Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. (1989) Income distribution, market size, and industrialization. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (3), 537564.Google Scholar
Ngai, L. Rachel and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2007) Structural change in a multisector model of growth. American Economic Review 97 (1), 429443.Google Scholar
Restuccia, Diego, Yang, Dennis Tao and Zhu, Xiaodong (2008) Agriculture and aggregate productivity: A quantitative cross-country analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (2), 234250.Google Scholar
Salhofer, Klaus (2000) Elasticities of substitution and factor supply elasticities in European agriculture: A review of past studies. Instituts für Wirtschaft, Politik und Recht (WPR) Diskussionspapiere 83-W-2000.Google Scholar
Stokey, Nancy (2001) A quantitative model of the British industrial revolution, 1780–1850. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55 (1), 55109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamura, Robert (2002) Human capital and the switch from agriculture to industry. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (2), 207242.Google Scholar
Uzawa, Hirofumi (1962) Production functions with constant elasticities of substitution. Review of Economic Studies 29 (4), 291299.Google Scholar
Von Tunzelmann, Gustav N. (1985) The standard of living debate and optimal economic growth. In Mokyr, J. (ed.), The Economics of the Industrial Revolution, pp. 207226. Washington DC: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar