Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-24T11:45:18.395Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Price System and Economic Change, A Commentary on Theory and History

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Eric E. Lampard
Affiliation:
University of Wisconsin

Extract

This paper is intended to provoke a general discussion of the nature and uses of historical sociology and its possible relevance to the work of economic historians. It is not an exhaustive treatment of the topic. Terms of reference merely call for a reconsideration of “the penetrative powers of the price system.”

Type
The Penetrative Power of the Price System
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1960

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

* The author wishes to acknowledge helpful suggestions received from Alfred Harris, anthropologist at Brandeis University, and Louis Cohn-Haft, ancient historian at Smith College. Neither of these scholars, of course, is responsible for applications made in this paper.

1 Innis, H. A., “The Penetrative Powers of the Price System,” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, IV (1938), 299319CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Meade, J. E., Planning and the Price Mechanism (London: Allen & Unwin, 1948), 89Google Scholar.

3 Robbins, Lionel, Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London: Macmillan, 1935), 72135Google Scholar.

4 Stigler, G. J., The Theory of Price (New York: Macmillan, 1946), 116Google Scholar.

5 Parsons, Talcott, “Some Reflections on “The Nature and Significance of Economics,'” Quarterly Journal of Economics, XLVIII (19341935), 511–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Mitchell, W. C., “The Role of Money in Economic History,” Journal of Economic History, IV (1944), Suppl., 61–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Ibid. Also, Mitchell, , “The Backward Art of Spending Money,” American Economic Review, II (1912), 269–81;Google Scholar“The Role of Money in Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, VI (1916), Suppl., 140–61;Google Scholar“Human Behavior and Economics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, XXIX (1914), 147Google Scholar.

8 Kuzets, Simon, “Notes on the Study of Economic Growth,” Social Science Research Council, Items, XIII (1959), 1317Google Scholar.

9 Croome, Honor, “The Dilemma of Development,” New Commonwealth, Nov. 9, 1953, 487Google Scholar.

10 Nurkse, Ragner, “International Investment To-day in the Light of Nineteenth-Century Experience,” Economic Journal. LXIV (1954), 744–758Google Scholar.

11 Stigler, op. cit., 11–12, 39–40.

12 Neale, W. C. in Karl Polanyi et al, Trade and Market in the Early Empires: Economies in History and Theory (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press & Falcon's Wing Press, 1957), 223228Google Scholar. This volume cited hereafter as: Polanyi, Trade and Market.

13 Heckscher, E. F., “A Plea for Theory in Economic History,” Economic History (Suppl. to Economic Journal), I (19261929), 525534;Google Scholar“Quantitative Measurement in Economic History,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, LIII (1939), 167Google Scholar. The present writer would, nevertheless, agree with Heckscher against Mitchell that “theory” does help in the choice and explanation of “facts.”

14 By “reciprocity” is meant a system in which tradition establishes the rights and obligations of individuals and groups in relation one to another, and status governs economic behavior. The symmetry of social organization insures provision for the needs of all, barring emergencies. By “redistribution” is meant a system in which a central agency, and not tradition or markets, determines production and disposition of goods. It is essentially authoritative. See, Polanyi, Trade and Market, passim. Readers interested in taxonomies, including those of Max Schmidt and Walter Eucken, should consult Wagner, P. L., “On Classifying Economies,” in Ginsburg, Norton, ed., Essays on Geography and Economic Development (Univ. of Chicago, Department of Geography, Research Paper No. 62, 1960), 4962Google Scholar.

15 These social and cultural phenomena influence “prices” and, in market economies, are sometimes influenced by them. For a recent critique of the “self-regulating market mechanism” in these regards, see Ayres, C. E., The Industrial Economy: Its Technological Basis and Institutional Destiny (Boston, Houghton Mifflin, 1952), 320373Google Scholar.

16 Kuznets, loc. cit., 13–17. This is not to suggest that we do not need more and better data of the kinds produced, for example, by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The point is that, apart from technical limitations of such data, the statistical analysis of economic change only goes so far. A sensible “incrementalist” realizes he can only explain a fraction of the data by macro-techniques. Also, Shannon, L. W., “Social Factors in Economic Growth: A Trend Report and Bibliography,” Cwrent Sociology, VI, No. 3 (Unesco, Paris, 1957)Google Scholar.

17 Parsons, Talcott, “Sociological Elements in Economic Thought: I. Historical, II. The Analytical Factor View,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, XLIX (1935), 414453, 646–667CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 W. W. Rostow, who currently is closest to finding the Holy Grail perhaps, is content to be an economic historian at an institute of technology.

19 Parsons, Talcott, The Structure of Social Action (2nd ed., Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1949);Google ScholarParsons, T. and Shils, E. A., eds., Toward a General Theory of Action (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press, 1951);CrossRefGoogle ScholarParsons, T. and Smelser, N. J., Economy and Society: A Study in the Integration of Economic and Social Theory (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1956);Google Scholar Polanyi, Trade and Market. These studies do not, of course, exhaust the literature of sociology relevant to economic history, let alone history in general. See, for example, Moore, W. E., Industrialization and Labor: Social Aspects of Economic Development (Ithaca: Cornell Univ. Press, 1951);Google ScholarHawley, A. H., Human Ecology: A Theory of Community Structure (New York: Ronald, 1950);Google ScholarLipset, S. M. and Bendix, Reinhard, Social Mobility in Industrial Society (Berkeley and Los Angeles: Univ. of California Press, 1958);Google ScholarDuncan, O. D. and Schnore, L. F., “Cultural, Behavioral, and Ecological Perspectives in the Study of Social Organization,” American Journal of Sociology, LXV (1959), 132153CrossRefGoogle Scholar, including a comment by P. H. Rossi. The present writer does not presume to assess the relative merits of these different approaches. He would only caution that every band wagon is potentially a hearse.

20 A. L. Oppenheim, “A Bird's-Eye View of Mesopotamian Economic History,” and R. B. Revere, “‘No Man's Coast’: Ports of Trade in the Eastern Mediterranean,” in Polanyi, Trade and Market, 27–37, 38–63.

21 Lyon, Bryce, From Fief to Indenture; The Transition from Feudal to Nonfeudal Contract in Western Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press, 1957);CrossRefGoogle ScholarBaldwin, J. W., The Medieval Theories of the Just Price; Romanists, Canonists, and Theologians in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries (Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society, 1959)Google Scholar.

22 Bailey, F. G., Caste and the Economic Frontier (Manchester: Manchester Univ. Press, 1957), 236240Google Scholar. The Orissa case is not cited as the prototype of Indian economy. Some sectors and localities have been subject to industrialization since the latter part of the 19th century. One wonders, however, if some of the recent Indian developments are not as much a consequence of “mobilization” by governments as of the penetrative powers of the price system. A major factor in the industrialization of some backward areas is “cold war” competitive co-existence.

23 The fact that prices are quoted, contracts made, and accounts reckoned in money terms does not detract from the point that decisions of authority rather than market bargaining determine many of the actual quantities involved. They did this long before the introduction of a general-purpose medium and the institutions of market economy: see, Quiggin, A. H., A Survey of Primitive Money: The Beginnings of Currency (London: Methuen, 1949), 514, 321–323Google Scholar.

24 Jerome, Harry, “The Relation of Custom to Price,” unpublished Ph.D, thesis, Univ. of Wisconsin, 1918.Google Scholar Also, Cooley, C. H., “The Institutional Character of Pecuniary Valuation,” American Journal of Sociology, XVIII (19121913), 543544;Google ScholarEllis, A., “Influence of Opinion on Markets,” Economic Journal, II (1892), 109116CrossRefGoogle Scholar, suggests that of eight conditions listed by Bagehot for striking a bargain, six are “based upon opinion.”

25 Lampard, E. E., “History of Cities in the Economically Advanced Areas,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, III (1955), 8792.Google Scholar Also, Schnore, L. F., “Social Morphology and Human Ecology,” American Journal of Sociology, LXIII (1958), 620634CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 T. K. Hopkins, “Sociology and the Substantive View of the Economy,” in Polanyi, Trade and Market, 271–306.

27 Dalton, George, “A Note of Clarification on Economic Surplus,” American Anthropologist, LXII (1960), 483490CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and D. B. Fusfeld in Polanyi, Trade and Market.

28 Smelser, N. J., Social Change in the Industrial Revolution: An Application of Theory to the British Cotton Industry (Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1959)Google Scholar. Quite apart from sociology, Smelser's study involved a first-class job of historical research.

29 See the comments of H. W. Pearson on Parsons and Smelser in Polanyi, Trade and Market, 307–318, and something of a rejoinder by Smelser, N. J., “A Comparative View of Exchange Systems,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, VII (1959), 173182CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Smelser criticizes the “substantive economics” model and attempts a translation of some of its forms into Parsonsian.

30 C. M. Arensberg, “Anthropology as History,” in Polanyi, Trade and Market, 97–113.

31 Usher, A. P., A History of Mechanical Inventions (Boston: Beacon Paperback, ed., 1959), 183Google Scholar, for an economic historian's view of the analysis of social change. Usher's analytical framework rests upon “the sociology of Gabriel Tarde, the gestalt psychology, and the concept of emergent evolution developed notably by C. Lloyd Morgan and other biologists,” (p. viii).

32 The difficulty, from the theorist's standpoint, is that historical writings provide “very few facts of history in the relevant senses”: Lewis, W. A., The Theory of Economic Growth (Homewood, Ill., 1955), p. 15.Google Scholar But see also, Bock, K. E., “The Acceptance of Histories: Toward a Perspective for Social Science,” University of California Publications in Sociology and Social Institutions, III, No. 1 (Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1956)Google Scholar.