Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-jbqgn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-27T22:50:33.590Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The future of new institutional economics: from early intuitions to a new paradigm?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 February 2014

CLAUDE MÉNARD*
Affiliation:
Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Paris, France
MARY M. SHIRLEY*
Affiliation:
Ronald Coase Institute, Chevy Chase, MD, USA

Abstract:

The trajectory of institutional economics changed in the 1970s when new institutional economics (NIE) began to take shape around some relative vague intuitions which eventually developed into powerful conceptual and analytical tools. The emergence of NIE is a success story by many measures: four Nobel laureates in less than 20 years, increasing penetration of mainstream journals, and significant impacts on major policy debates. This rapid acceptance is remarkable when we consider that it was divided from birth into distinct schools of thought. What will be the future of NIE? Will it be quietly absorbed by mainstream theory, or will it radically transform neoclassical economics into a new paradigm that includes institutions? To address these questions, we follow the sometimes-bumpy road to NIE's current successes and ponder the challenges that lie ahead.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A., (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, New York: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1965), ‘Some Economics of Property Rights’, Il Politico, 30 (4): 816819; reprinted in Economic Forces at Work (1977), Indianapolis: Liberty Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H. (1972), ‘Production, Information Costs and Economic Organizations’, American Economic Review, 62 (5): 777795.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001), Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M., Gustafsson, B., and Williamson, O. E. (1990), The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties, London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1974), The Limits of Organization, New York: Norton and Co.Google Scholar
Barnard, C. (1938), The Functions of the Executive, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1989/1997), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, R. H., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J., and Weingast, B. R. (1998), Analytic Narratives, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Glachant, J. (2008), New Institutional Economics: A Guidebook, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. (1975), ‘A Contractarian Paradigm for Applying Economic Theory’, American Economic Review, 65 (5): 225230.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. and Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of a Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. (1983), ‘The Contractual Nature of the Firm’, Journal of Law and Economics, 26 (1): 121.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937/2004), ‘The Nature of the Firm’ (originally published in 1937, Economia, 4 (16): 386405, in Ménard, C. (ed.), The Foundations of the New Institutional Economics, 2004, Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar, pp. 51–70.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1959), ‘The Federal Communications Commission’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 2 (October): 140.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 3 (October): 144.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1964), ‘The Regulated Industries: Discussion’, American Economic Review, 54 (May): 194197.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1994), Essays on Economics and Economists, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1998), ‘New Institutional Economics’, American Economic Review, 88 (2), 36.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1999), ‘The Task of the Society’, Opening Address to the Annual Conference of ISNIE, Newsletter of the International Society for New Institutional Economics, 2 (2): 36.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (2002), ‘Why Economics Will Change’, Newsletter of the International Society for New Institutional Economics, 4 (1): 47.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1934), Institutional Economics, New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. (1968), ‘Why Regulate Utilities?’, Journal of Law and Economics, 11 (April): 5566.Google Scholar
Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., LaPorta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2003), ‘The New Comparative Economics’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (4): 595619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, T. (1998), ‘A Note on the Economics of Institutions’, in Alston, L., Eggertsson, T. and North, D. C. (eds.), Empirical Studies in Institutional Change, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1991), The New Institutional Economics, College Station, TX: Texas A & M University Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1997), Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Goldberg, V. P. (1976), ‘Regulation and Administered Contracts’, Bell Journal of Economics, 7 (Autumn): 527543.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2005), ‘Commitment, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 727786.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (1988), Economics and Institutions, a Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics, Philadelphia, PA: University of Philadelphia Press.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. (1985), ‘Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning Electric Generating Plants’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1 (1): 3380.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. (2002), ‘Transaction Costs Economics, Antitrust Rules and Remedies’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organizations, 18 (1): 95116.Google Scholar
Judson, H. F. (1979), The Eight Day of Creation: Makers of the Revolution in Biology, New York, NY: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Klein, P. G. (2005), ‘The Make-or-Buy Decisions: Lessons from Empirical Studies’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 435464.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (2013), ‘The Institutional Approach to Economic History: Connecting the Two Strands’, University of Connecticut Department of Economics Working Paper No. 33, September 2013. www.econ.uconn.edu/workingpapers/?=2013-33. Accessed on January 9, 2014.Google Scholar
Levy, B. and Spiller, P. (1994), ‘The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 10 (2): 201246.Google Scholar
Llewelyn, K. N. (1931) ‘What Price Contract? An Essay in Perspective’, Yale Law Journal, 40: 704751.Google Scholar
Macaulay, S. (1963), ‘Non Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study’, American Sociological Review, 28 (1): 5567.Google Scholar
MacNeil, I. R. (1974), ‘The Many Futures of Contracts’, Southern California Law Review, 47 (May): 691816.Google Scholar
MacNeil, I. R. (1978), ‘Contracts: Adjustments of a Long Term Economic Relation Under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law’, Northwestern University Law Review, 72 (6): 854906.Google Scholar
Masten, S. (1984), ‘The Organization of Production: Evidence from the Aerospace Industry’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 27 (2): 403417.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (1995), ‘Markets as Institutions versus Organization as Markets? Disentangling some Fundamental Concepts’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28 (2): 161182.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2001), ‘Methodological Issues in New Institutional Economics’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 8 (1): 8592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, C. (2004), The International Library of New Institutional Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publisher.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2009), ‘Oliver Williamson and the Economics of Hybrid Organizations’ in Morroni, M. (ed.), Corporate Governance, Organization Design and the Firm: Cooperation and Outsourcing in the Global Economy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 87103.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2012), ‘Hybrid Modes of Organization: Alliances, Joint Ventures, Networks, and Other ‘Strange’ Animals’, in Gibbons, R. and Roberts, J. (eds.), The Handbook of Organizational Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Ghertman, M. (2009), Regulation, Deregulation and Reregulation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publisher.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (2005/2008), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M. (2014), ‘The Contribution of Douglass North to New Institutional Economics’, in Galiani, S. and Sened, I. (eds.), Economic Institutions, Rights, Growth, and Sustainability: The Legacy of Douglass North, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Merton, R. K. (1949; expanded 1957 and 1968), Social Theory and Social Structure, New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Monteverde, H. and Teece, D. (1982), ‘Suppliers Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry’, Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (1): 206213.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1968), ‘Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600–1850’, The Journal of Political Economy, 76 (5): 953970.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1993), ‘Douglass C. North, the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993: Autobiography’, The Nobel Foundation, vol. 2010.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1994), ‘Economic Performance through Time’, American Economic Review, 84 (3): 359368.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (2005), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C and Davis, L. (1971), Institutional Change and American Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P. (1973), The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Order: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, The Journal of Economic History, 49 (4): 803832.Google Scholar
Olson, M. and Kahkonen, S. (2000), A Not-So-Dismal Science: A Broader View of Economics and Societies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1973), Economic Analysis of Law, New York, NY: Little, Brown and Company.Google Scholar
Richter, R. (2005), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Its Start, its Meaning, and its Prospects’, European Business Organization Law Review, 6 (2): 161200.Google Scholar
Sala-I-Martin, X. (2002), ‘15 Years of New Growth Economics: What Have We Learnt?’, Columbia University, Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 0102-47.Google Scholar
Shelanski, H. and Klein, P. (1995), ‘Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Survey and Assessment’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11 (2): 335361.Google Scholar
Shirley, M. M. (2002), Thirsting for Efficiency: The Economics and Politics of Urban Water System Reform, Oxford: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Shirley, M. M. (2008), Institutions and Development, Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. (1966), The Theory of Price, 3rd ed., New York, NY: Macmillian.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. (1993), ‘Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149 (1): 286311.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1964), The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1971), ‘The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations’, American Economic Review, 61 (May): 112123.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1976), ‘Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies – in General and with Respect to CATV’, Bell Journal of Economics, 7 (1): 73104.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1979), ‘Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations’, Journal of Law and Economics, 22 (2): 361.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York, NY: The Free Press-Macmillan.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1986), Economic Organization: Firms, Markets, and Policy Control, New York, NY: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1996), The Mechanisms of Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock/Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37 (3): 595613.Google Scholar
Woolf, V. (1928), Mr. Bennett and Mrs. Brown, London: Hogarth Press.Google Scholar