Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T14:41:17.088Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Intragenerational externalities and intergenerational transfers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2012

MARTIN KOLMAR*
Affiliation:
University of St. Gallen and CESifo (Kolmar), University of Munich, Ifo Institute for Economic Research and CESifo (Meier)
VOLKER MEIER*
Affiliation:
University of St. Gallen and CESifo (Kolmar), University of Munich, Ifo Institute for Economic Research and CESifo (Meier)
*
*Martin Kolmar, Institute of Public Finance and Fiscal Law, University of St. Gallen, Varnbüelstrasse 19, CH-9000, St. Gallen, Switzerland. Phone: + + 41-(0)71-224-2535, Fax: + + 41-(0)71-224-2670, E-mail: martin.kolmar@unisg.ch
Corresponding author. Volker Meier, Department of Economics, University of Munich, Schackstr. 4, D-80539 Munich, Germany. Phone: + + 49-(0)89-2180-6261, E-mail: Volker.Meier@lrz.unimuenchen.de

Abstract

In an environment with asymmetric information and intragenerational externalities, the implementation of a first-best efficient Clarke–Groves–Vickrey mechanism may not be feasible if it has to be self-financing. By using intergenerational transfers, the arising budget deficit can be covered in every generation only if the initial allocation is not dynamically efficient. While introducing a pay-as-you-go scheme without addressing the externality already yields a Pareto improvement, further welfare gains can be captured by using the additional resources to achieve a perfect internalization.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abel, A. B., Mankiw, N. G., Summers, L. H. and Zeckhauser, R. J. (1989) Assessing dynamic efficiency: theory and evidence. Review of Economic Studies, 56: 119.Google Scholar
Breyer, F. (1989) On the intergenerational Pareto efficiency of pay-as-you-go financed pension systems. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145: 643658.Google Scholar
Browning, E. K. (1975) Why the social insurance budget is too large in a democracy. Economic Inquiry, 13: 373388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, J. K. (1996) Transition from a pay-as-you-go to a fully funded pension system: the case of differing individuals and intragenerational fairness. Journal of Public Economics, 60: 131146.Google Scholar
D'Aspremont, C. and Gérard-Varet, L. A. (1979) Incentives and incomplete information. Journal of Public Economics, 11: 2545.Google Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review, 55: 11261150.Google Scholar
Dionne, G. and Doherty, N. (1992) Adverse selection in insurance markets: a selective survey. In Dionne, G. (ed.), Contributions to Insurance Economics. Boston: Kluwer, pp. 97–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenge, R. (1995) Pareto efficiency of the pay-as-you-go pension system with intragenerational fairness. Finanzarchiv 52: 357363.Google Scholar
Gordon, R. H. and Varian, H. R. (1988) Intergenerational risk sharing. Journal of Public Economics, 37: 185202.Google Scholar
Gresik, T. A. and Satterthwaite, M. A. (1989) The rate at which a simple market converges to efficiency as the number of traders increases: an asymptotic result for optimal trading mechanisms. Journal of Economic Theory, 48: 304332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homburg, S. (1990) The efficiency of unfunded pension schemes. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146: 640647.Google Scholar
Kolmar, M. (1997) Intergenerational redistribution in a small open economy with endogenous fertility. Journal of Population Economics, 10: 335356.Google Scholar
Mailath, G. J. and Postlewaite, A. (1990) Asymmetric information bargaining problems with many agents. Review of Economic Studies, 57: 351367.Google Scholar
Makowski, L. and Mezzetti, C. (1994) Bayesian and weakly robust first best mechanisms: characterizations. Journal of Economic Theory, 64: 500519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D. and Green, J. R. (1995) Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Merton, R. C. (1983) On the role of social security as a means for efficient risk sharing in an economy where human capital is not tradable. In Bodie, Z. and Shoven, J. (eds.), Financial Aspects of the United States Pension System. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, pp. 325358.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. (2004) Putting Auction Theory to Work. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. and Satterthwaite, M. A. (1983) Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 28: 265281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, W. (1995) Public pensions, family allowances and endogenous demographic change. Journal of Population Economics, 8: 161183.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971) A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1958) An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. Journal of Political Economy, 66: 467482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (1999) Social security and institutions for intergenerational, intragenerational and international risk-sharing. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policies, 50: 165204.Google Scholar
Sinn, H.-W. (2000) Why a funded pension system is useful and why it is not useful. International Tax and Public Finance, 7: 389410.Google Scholar
Spremann, K. (1984) Intergenerational contracts and their decomposition. Journal of Economics, 44: 237253.Google Scholar
Wigger, B. U. (2001) Pareto-improving intergenerational transfers. Oxford Economic Papers, 53: 260280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar