Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-07T04:40:50.332Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Origins and Practice of Emissions Trading

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 April 2009

Hugh S. Gorman
Affiliation:
Michigan Technological University
Barry D. Solomon
Affiliation:
Michigan Technological University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

An important development in the field of environmental policy has been the growing acceptance and use of emissions trading as a cost-effective means to meet and maintain environmental quality standards. In the first half of the twentieth century, emissions trading programs not only would have been seen as unnecessary; they would have been inconceivable. The legal, bureaucratic, and technological infrastructure necessary to support such systems simply did not exist. Furthermore, most people did not see the release of pollutioncausing contaminants into the shared environment as transactions to be measured and monitored. Today, the use of emissions trading programs as a policy tool both reflects and represents the dramatic changes in pollution control policy that have since occurred.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA. 2002

References

Notes

1. Other policy options include pollution taxes or effluent charges, refundable deposit systems, reducing market barriers, and reducing government subsidies. See, for example, Stavins, Robert N., “Harnessing the Marketplace,” EPA Journal 18 (0506 1992): 2125Google Scholar; Stavins, Robert N., “Market-Based Environmental Policies,” in Portney, Paul R. and Stavins, Robert N., eds., Public Policies for Environmental Protection, 2d ed. (Washington, D.C., 2000), 3176.Google Scholar

2. Solomon, Barry D., “New Directions in Emissions Trading: The Potential Contribution of New Institutional Economics,” Ecological Economics 30 (09 1999): 371387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3. Tripp, James T. B. and Dudek, Daniel J., “Institutional Guidelines for Designing Successful Transferable Rights Programs,” Yale Journal on Regulation 6 (Summer 1989): 369391Google Scholar; Haddad, Brent M., Putting Markets to Work: The Design and Use of Marketable Permits and Obligations (Paris: OECD Occasional Papers No. 19, 1997)Google Scholar; Haddad, Brent M. and Jefferiss, P., “Forging Consensus on National Renewables Policy: The Renewable Portfolio Standard and the National Public Benefits Trust Fund,” Electricity Journal 12 (03 1999): 6880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4. Tarlock, Daniel A., Law of Water Rights and Resources (New York, 1988)Google Scholar; Haddad, Brent M., Rivers of Gold: Designing Markets to Allocate Water in California (Washington, D.C., 2000).Google Scholar

5. Gorman, Hugh S., Redefining Efficiency: Pollution Concerns, Regulatory Mechanisms, and Technological Change in the U.S. Petroleum Industry (Akron, Ohio, 2001).Google Scholar

6. Hays, Samuel P., Beauty, Health, and Permanence: Environmental Politics in the United States, 1955–1985 (New York, 1987).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7. Hahn, Robert W. and Stavins, Robert N., “Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era from an Old Idea?Ecology Law Quarterly 18 (1991): 2325Google Scholar; Nelson, E., “Pollution Trading: Buying and Selling Pieces of Our Lives,” Z Magazine (09 1993): 4751Google Scholar; Grandon, Ron, “Activists Bare the Achilles Heel of Emissions Trading Programs,” EM (Environmental Manager) 5 (06 1999): 56Google Scholar; Ginsburg, R., “Playing with Fire: L.A.'s Pollution Trading Experiment,” Dollars and Sense 193 (0506 1994): 2325, 42Google Scholar; Drury, Richard T., Belliveau, Michael E., Kuhn, J. Scott, and Bansal, Shipra, “Pollution Trading and Environmental Injustice: Los Angeles' Failed Experiment in Air Quality Policy,” Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum 9 (Spring 1999): 231289.Google Scholar

8. Solomon, Barry D. and Lee, Russell, “Emissions Trading Systems and Environmental Justice,” Environment 42 (10 2000): 3245Google Scholar; Tietenberg, Thomas H., “Tradeable Permits for Pollution Control When Emission Location Matters: What Have We Learned?Environmental and Resource Economics 5 (03 1995): 95113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9. Coase, Ronald H., “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics 3 (10 1960): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10. Crocker, Thomas D., “The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems,” in Wolozin, Harold, ed., The Economics of Air Pollution (New York, 1966): 6186Google Scholar; Dales, John H., “Land, Water, and Ownership,” Canadian Journal of Economics 1 (11 1968): 791804CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dales, John H., Pollution, Property, and Prices (Toronto, 1968).Google Scholar

11. Baumol, William J. and Oates, Wallace E., “The Use of Standards and Prices for Protection of the Environment,” Swedish Journal of Economics 73 (1971): 4254CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Tietenberg, Thomas H., “The Design of Property Rights for Air Pollution Control,” Public Policy 22 (Summer 1974): 275292Google Scholar; Ferrar, Terry A. and Whinston, Andrew B., “Taxation and Water Pollution Control,” Natural Resources Journal 12 (07 1972): 307317.Google Scholar

12. Crocker, Thomas D. and Rodgers, A. J. III, Environmental Economics (Hinsdale, Ill., 1971).Google Scholar

13. Montgomery, W. David, “Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs,” Journal of Economic Theory 5 (12 1972): 395418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14. H. Jacoby and G. Schaumburg, “Administered Markets in Water Quality Control: A Proposal for the Delaware Estuary,” unpublished (described in Montgomery, “Market in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs”).

15. For these “criteria” pollutants, which are common pollutants that are not highly toxic, the EPA assessed their effect on human health and specified the level at which those effects occur. See also Skillern, Frank F., Environmental Protection: The Legal Framework (New York, 1981), 83143.Google Scholar

16. Ibid. The EPA addressed deterioration in attainment areas by issuing a series of Prevention of Significant Deterioration rules that treated pristine areas differently from “growth” areas.

17. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, “Emission Offset Interpretative Ruling,” 44 Fed. Reg. 3274-82 (1979)Google Scholar; Haddad, Brent M., “Marketable Permits and Pollution Charges: Two Case Studies,” in Palmisano, John and Neves, Carol, eds., The Environment Goes to Market: The Implementation of Economic Incentives for Pollution Control (Washington, D.C., 1994), 31Google Scholar; U.S. General Accounting Office, A Market Approach to Air Pollution Control Could Reduce Compliance Costs Without Jeopardizing Clean Air Goals (Washington, D.C., 1982).Google Scholar

18. Section 173, 42 U.S.C., part 7503.

19. For an examination of questions and policies that arose, see Liroff, Richard A., Air Pollution Offsets (Washington, D.C., 1980).Google Scholar

20. EPA's New Emissions Policy Flawed,” Oil and Gas Journal 75 (4 04 1977): 5253.Google Scholar

21. U.S. General Accounting Office, A Market Approach to Air Pollution Control Could Reduce Compliance Costs Without Jeopardizing Clean Air Goals; Dwyer, John P., “California's Tradeable Emissions Policy and Its Implications for the Control of Greenhouse Gases,” in OECD, Climate Change: Designing a Tradeable Permit System (Paris, 1992), 3536.Google Scholar

22. Foster, Vivien and Hahn, Robert W., “Designing More Efficient Markets: Lessons from Los Angeles Smog Control,” Journal of Law and Economics 38 (04 1995): 1948CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stavins, Robert N., “Transaction Costs and Tradeable Permits,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 29 (09 1995): 133148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23. Tripp and Dudek, “Institutional Guidelines for Designing Successful Transferable Rights Programs,” 385–86.

24. Hahn, Robert W., “Economic Prescriptions for Environmental Problems: How the Patient Followed the Doctor's Orders,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (Spring 1989): 99CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hahn, Robert W. and Hester, Gordon L., “Marketable Permits: Lessons for Theory and Practice,” Ecology Law Quarterly 16 (1989): 368376.Google Scholar

25. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, “Air Pollution Control: Recommendations for Alternative Emission Reduction Options Within State Implementation Plans,” 44 Fed. Reg. 71, 780 (1979) (revised bubble policy).Google Scholar

26. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Emission Reduction Banking & Trading Update 2 (10 1980)Google Scholar; Elman, Barry S., “Emissions Trading and Economic Incentives Under the Clean Air Act,” in Complying with the New Clean Air Act (Washington, D.C., 1991).Google Scholar

27. Popkin, Roy, “EPA's Policy on the Bubble,” EPA Journal 13 (09 1987): 2931.Google Scholar

28. Liroff, , Reforming Air Pollution Regulation: The Toil and Trouble of EPA's Bubble (Washington, D.C., 1986); 98101Google Scholar; Hahn, Robert W. and Hester, Gordon L., “Where Did All the Markets Go? An Analysis of EPA's Emissions Trading Program,” Yale Journal on Regulation 6 (Winter 1989): 123132Google Scholar.

29. For examples of such policy questions, see Liroff, Reforming Air Pollution Regulation; and Skillern, Environmental Protection. See also Exxon, Unocal Detail Air Pollution Initiatives,” Oil and Gas Journal 88 (25 06 1990): 1617.Google Scholar

30. Dudek, Daniel J. and Palmisano, John, “Emissions Trading: Why Is This Thoroughbred Hobbled?Columbia Journal of Environmental Law 13 (06 1988): 217256Google Scholar; Hahn and Hester, “Where Did All the Markets Go? 109–53.

31. Chevron USA, Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837-47, rehearing denied, 468 U.S. 1227 (1984); Levin, Michael H., “The Supreme Court's ‘Bubble’ Decision: What It Means,” EPA Journal 10 (09 1984): 1011.Google Scholar

32. Freeman, A. Myrick III, “Water Pollution Policy,” in Portney, Paul R., ed., Public Policies for Environmental Protection (Washington, D.C., 1990), 97149.Google Scholar

33. Zander, Bruce, “Nutrient Trading—in the Wings,” and “Innovations at Boulder Creek,” EPA Journal 17 (1112 1991): 4750Google Scholar; Hall, John and Howett, Ciannat, “Albemarle-Pamlico: Case Study in Pollutant Trading,” EPA Journal 20 (Summer 1994): 2729Google Scholar; Jarvie, Michelle and Solomon, Barry D., “Point-Nonpoint Effluent Trading in Watersheds: A Review and Critique,” Environmental Impact Assessment Review 18 (03 1998): 135157CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Letson, David, “Point/Nonpoint Source Pollution Reduction Trading: An Interpretive Survey,” Natural Resources Journal 32 (04 1992): 219232Google Scholar; Peplin, Robert, Regulating Runoff,” Forum for Applied Research and Public Policy 13 (Fall 1998): 4548Google Scholar; Houck, Oliver A., The Clean Water Act TMDL Program: Law, Policy, and Implementation (Washington, D.C., 1999).Google Scholar

34. Podar, Mahesh and Kashmanian, Richard M., “Charting a New Course,” Forum for Applied Research and Public Policy 13 (Fall 1998): 4044Google Scholar; Kashmanian, Richard M., Podar, Mahesh, Luttner, Mark A., and Graff, Robert G., “The Use and Impact of Intraplant Trading in the Iron and Steel Industry to Reduce Water Pollution,” Environmental Professional 17 (12 1995): 309315.Google Scholar

35. Weaver, E. E., “Effects of Tetraethyl Lead on Catalyst Life and Efficiency in Customer Type Vehicle Operations,”paper presented at the International Automotive Engineering Congress, DetroitMichigan13–17 January 1969Google Scholar; Olson, Donel R., “The Control of Motor Vehicle Emissions,” in Engineering Control of Air Pollution, ed. Stern, Arthur, vol. 4 of Air Pollution (New York, 1977), 620623.Google Scholar

36. Rosner, David and Markowitz, Gerald, “‘A Gift of God’? The Public Health Controversy over Leaded Gasoline During the 1920s,” in Dying for Work: Workers' Safety and Health in Twentieth-Century America, ed. Rosner, David and Markowitz, Gerald (Bloomington, 1987).Google Scholar

37. W. D. Preston and H. A. Toulmin, “The Automobile Powerplant and Its Fuel Requirements, 1972–1982,” Research and Development, box 13, series 6, Sun Oil Collection, Hagley Museum and Library.

38. No-lead Will Magnify Gasoline Woes,” Oil and Gas Journal 72 (21 01 1974): 4747.Google Scholar

39. Low-lead, No-lead Gasoline Units Set by Cities, Ashland,” Oil and Gas Journal 69 (15 02 1971): 45Google Scholar; Who's Moving to Reduce or Eliminate Lead in Gasoline,” Oil and Gas Journal 69 (11 10 1971): 35, table.Google Scholar

40. Advertisement, Fluor Corporation, Oil and Gas Journal 69 (15 02 1971): 2123Google Scholar. The Foster Wheeler Corporation placed a similar type of advertisement on pp. 58–59.

41. Smooth-Sailing Refiners Eye Storm Clouds in US,” Oil and Gas Journal 73 (15 09 1975): 7982Google Scholar; EPA Sticks to Present Lead-Out Timetable,” Oil and Gas Journal 72 (20 05 1974): 36Google Scholar; Douglas Costle to Oswall Newell Jr., 16 November 1977, General Correspondence, box 260, Office of the Administrator, RG 412, Records of the EPA, National Archives at College Park.

42. Nussbaum, Barry D., “Phasing Down Lead in Gasoline in the U.S.: Mandates, Incentives, Trading, and Banking,” in OECD, Climate Change: Designing a Tradeable Permit System (Paris, 1992), 20.Google Scholar

43. U.S. Lead Entitlement Programs Urged,” Oil and Gas Journal (31 05 1982): 177178.Google Scholar

44. Refiners Split on Lead Phasedown Plan,” Oil and Gas Journal 80 (13 09 1982): 3536.Google Scholar

45. U.S. Lead Entitlement Programs Urged,” Oil and Gas Journal (31 05 1982): 177Google Scholar; Refiners Split on Lead Phasedown Plan,” Oil and Gas Journal (13 09 1982): 45Google Scholar; U.S. EPA Proposes ‘Banking’ of Lead Usage Rights,” Oil and Gas Journal (14 01 1985), 45.Google Scholar

46. Hahn, “Economic Prescriptions for Environmental Problems,” 102; Hahn and Hester, “Marketable Permits,” 380–91.

47. The central office of the EPA responsible for air quality is the Office of Air and Radiation.

48. Whiteman, Lily, “Trades to Remember: The Lead Phasedown,” EPA Journal 18 (0506 1992): 3839Google Scholar; Nussbaum, “Phasing Down Lead in Gasoline in the U.S.,” 27–29.

49. Hahn, Robert W. and McGartland, Albert M., “The Political Economy of Instrument Choice: An Examination of the U.S. Role in Implementing the Montreal Protocol,” Northwestern University Law Review 83 (Spring 1989): 592611Google Scholar; Tripp and Dudek, “Institutional Guidelines for Designing Successful Transferable Rights Programs,” 382–84; Shapiro, Michael H. and Warhit, Ellen, “Marketable Permits: The Case of Chlorfluorocarbons,” Natural Resources Journal 23 (07 1983): 577591.Google Scholar

50. Lee, David, “Trading Pollution,” in Cook, Elizabeth, ed., Ozone Protection in the United States: Elements of Success (Washington, D.C., 1996): 3138.Google Scholar

51. Ibid., 39–53.

52. Nussbaum, “Phasing Down Lead in Gasoline in the U.S.,” 20.

53. Bryner, Gary C., Blue Skies, Green Politics: The Clean Air Act of 1990, 2d ed. (Washington, D.C., 1995): 144147Google Scholar; Stavins, Robert N., “What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (Summer 1998): 6988CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stavins, Robert N., ed., Project 88: Harnessing Market Forces to Protect Our Environment, 12 1988Google Scholar. For an overview of the Project 88 findings, see Stavins, Robert N., “Harnessing Market Forces to Protect the Environment,” Environment 31 (0102 1989): 4Google Scholar. For earlier support of transferable water market schemes, see Boronkay, Carl and Shreves, Charles, “Water Trades Can Help Meet Future Urban Needs,” EDF Letter 20 (05 1989): 7.Google Scholar

54. U.S. EPA, Acid Rain Program: Overview (EPA 430-F-92-019, April 1996).

55. Joskow, Paul L. and Schmalensee, Richard, “The Political Economy of Market-Based Environmental Policy: The U.S. Acid Rain Program,” Journal of Law and Economics 41 (04 1998): 3783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

56. Solomon, Barry D., “Five Years of Interstate SO2 Allowance Trading: Geographic Patterns and Potential Cost Savings,” Electricity Journal 11 (05 1998): 5870.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

57. U.S. EPA, Acid Rain Program: Overview; Claussen, Eileen, “Acid Rain: The Strategy,” EPA Journal 17 (0102 1991): 2123.Google Scholar

58. Ibid.

59. Burtraw, Dallas, “The SO2 Emissions Trading Program: Cost Savings Without Allowance Trades,” Contemporary Economic Policy 14 (04 1996): 7994CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Schmalensee, Richard, Joskow, Paul L., Ellerman, A. Denny, Montero, Juan P., and Bailey, Elizabeth M., “An Interim Evaluation of Sulfur Dioxide Emissions Trading,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (Summer 1998): 5568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

60. 40 Code of Federal Regulations, part 51, 59 (7 April 1994): 16690–717.

61. Lents, James M. and Leyden, Patricia, “RECLAIM: Los Angeles' New Market-Based Smog Cleanup Program,” Journal of the Air & Waste Management Association 46 (03 1996): 195206CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed; Fromm, O. and Hansjurgens, B., “Emissions Trading in Theory and Practice: An Analysis of RECLAIM in Southern California,” Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 14 (1996): 367384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

62. Solomon and Gorman, “State-Level Air Emissions Trading: The Michigan and Illinois Models,” 1156–65.

63. Farrell, Alex, “The NOx Budget: A Look at the First Year,” Electricity Journal 13 (03 2000): 8393CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Farrell, Alex, Carter, R., and Raufer, R., “The NOx Budget: Market-Based Control of Tropospheric Ozone in the Northeast United States,” Resource and Energy Economics 21 (06 1999): 103124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

64. Solomon, “New Directions in Emissions Trading,” 378–79.

65. Tripp and Dudek, “Institutional Guidelines for Designing Successful Transferable Rights Programs”; Solomon, “Global CO2 Emissions Trading”; Solomon and Lee, “Emissions Trading Systems and Environmental Justice.”

66. Ackerman, Frank, Biewald, Bruce, White, David, Wolfe, Tim, and Moomaw, William, “Grandfathering and Coal Plant Emissions: The Cost of Cleaning Up the Clean Air Act,” Energy Policy 27 (1999): 929940CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The authors note that the issue is made even more complex by the relaxed standards offered to older facilities.

67. There is a large and growing scholarly and applied literature addressing international trading of greenhouse gases. The practical issues of designing such programs, including equity considerations, have also been addressed in a series of reports commissioned by the United Nations. See, for example, Rose, Adam, Stevens, Brandt, Edmonds, Jae, and Wise, Marshall, “International Equity and Differentiation in Global Warming Policy,” Environmental and Resource Economics 12 (03 1998): 2551CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Grubb, Michael, Michaelowa, A., Swift, Byron, Tietenberg, Thomas H., Zhang, Z. X., and Joshua, Frank T., Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading (Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1998): 190Google Scholar; Anderson, Dean and Grubb, Michael, eds., Controlling Carbon and Sulphur: Joint Implementation and Trading Initiatives (London, 1997)Google Scholar; Nordhaus, Robert R. and Danish, Kyle W. et al. , “International Emissions Trading Rules as a Compliance Tool: What Is Necessary, Effective, and Workable?Environmental Law Reporter 30 (10 2000): 1083710855.Google Scholar

68. For more details on the lessons from sulfur dioxide allowance trading, see, in general, Stavins, “What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment?” 77–82; Solomon, Barry D., “Global CO2 Emissions Trading: Early Lessons from the U.S. Acid Rain Program,” Climatic Change 30 (05 1995): 8385CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Solomon and Lee, “Emissions Trading Systems and Environmental Justice.”