Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-13T11:10:53.426Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Tax Revolts and Political Change

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 October 2011

Ballard C. Campbell
Affiliation:
Northeastern University

Extract

The adoption of Proposition 13 in 1978 sent shock waves throughout the American polity. California's attack on property taxes was not the first fiscal limitation adopted in the 1970s, but it carried clear national implications that the earlier measures lacked. By successfully challenging the political establishment, the initiative drive in the Golden State energized campaigns elsewhere to restrict taxes. The echo of Proposition 13 reverberated in Massachusetts, whose voters approved a cap on property taxes (Proposition 2 ½) in 1980. Citizens on the nation's two coasts had signaled thumbs down on fiscal affairs in their states.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA. 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

1. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1984 (Washington, D.C., 1985), tables 93, 94Google Scholar; Tvedt, Sherry, “Enough Is Enough: The Origins of Proposition 2 ½” (M.A. thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1981), 1920Google Scholar; Kuttner, Robert, Revolt of the Haves: Tax Rebellions and Hard Times (New York, 1980)Google Scholar. State indexing laws: Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1982–1983 (Washington, D.C., 1984), table 67.Google Scholar

2. Washington Post, 2 February 1979. The push for a balanced-budget amendment stalled at thirty-two states in the mid-1980s. New York Times, 19 March 1985.

3. This article cannot discuss all aspects of the model. I will review its general contours, noting changes in fiscal policy in four major crises prior to the 1970s.

4. Nettels, Curtis, The Emergence of a National Economy, 1775–1815 (New York, 1962), chap. 3Google Scholar; Morris, Richard B., The Forging of the Union, 1781–1789 (New York, 1987), chap. 6Google Scholar; Flannagan, John H., “Trying Times: Depression in New Hampshire, 1781–1789” (Ph.D. dissertation, Georgetown University, 1972)Google Scholar; McCusker, John J. and Menard, Russell R., The Economy of British America, 1607–1789 (Chapel Hill, 1985), chap. 17.Google Scholar

5. Flannagan, “Depression in New Hampshire,” 81–119; Szatmary, David P., Shays's Rebellion: The Making of an Agrarian Insurrection (Amherst, Mass., 1980), chap. 2.Google Scholar

6. Fiske, John, The Critical Period in American History, 1783–1789 (Boston, 1888), 166.Google Scholar

7. Brown, Rodger, Redeeming the Republic: Federalists, Taxation, and the Origins of the Constitution (Baltimore, 1993).Google Scholar

8. Flanngan, “Trying Times,” 248; Szatmary, Shays's Rebellion, 29.

9. Nevins, Allan, The American States During and After the Revolution, 1775–1789 (New York, 1924), 432–56, 529–33, 557–60Google Scholar; Nettels, National Economy, chap. 4.

10. Szatmary, Shays's Rebellion, chaps. 4, 5, and 124–26; Nettels, National Economy, 83–88; Brown, Redeeming the Republic, 104–20; Papenfuse, Edward C., “The Legislative Response to a Costly War: Fiscal Policy and Factional Politics in Maryland, 1777–1789,” in Hoffman, R. and Albert, P., eds., Sovereign States in an Age of Uncertainty (Charlottesville, Va., 1981), 134–56Google Scholar; Morris, Forging of the Union, 266; and Fisk, Critical Period, chap. 4, “Drifting Toward Anarchy.”

11. Scholars who saw conservative reaction to state actions as central to the movement for a stronger national government include Nevins, The American States, 570; Nettels, National Economy, 89–92; Brown, Redeeming the Republic; Wood, Gordon S., The Creation of the American Republic, 1776–1787 (New York, 1969), chaps. 10, 11, esp. p. 465.Google Scholar

12. Rezneck, Samuel, “The Social History of an American Depression, 1837–43,” American Historical Review (1935): 662–87Google Scholar; Margo, Robert A., “Wages and Prices during the Antebellum Period: A Survey of New Evidence,” in Gallman, R. and Wallis, J., eds., American Economic Groivth and Standards of Living Before the Civil War (Chicago, 1992)Google Scholar; Holt, Michael F., “The Election of 1840, Voter Mobilization, and the Emergence of the Second Party System,” in Cooper, W., Holt, M., and McCardell, J., eds., A Master's Due (Baton Rouge, La., 1985), esp. 35.Google Scholar

13. Ratchford, B. U., American State Debts (Durham, N.C., 1941), 79105Google Scholar; Kirkland, Edward C., Men, Cities, and Transportation (Cambridge, Mass., 1948), 1:132–34.Google Scholar

14. Sowers, Don C., The Financial History of New York State: From 1789 to 1912 (New York, 1914), 70Google Scholar; Gunn, L. Ray, The Decline of Authority: Public Economic Policy and Political Development in New York, 1800–1860 (Ithaca, N.Y., 1988), chap. 5.Google Scholar

15. Goodrich, Carter, “The Revulsion Against Internal Improvements,” Journal of Economic History (1950): esp. 156–57Google Scholar; Ratchford, American State Debts, 121–22.

16. Rezneck, Samuel, “Distress, Relief, and Discontent in the United States During the Depression of 1873–78,” Journal of Political Economy (1950): 498, 501Google Scholar; Bogart, Ernest L. and Thompson, C. M., The Industrial State, 1870–1893 (Springfield, III., 1920), 438Google Scholar; Kleppner, Paul, The Third Electoral System, 1853–1892: Parties, Voters, and Political Cultures (Chapel Hill, N.C., 1979), 122.Google Scholar

17. For example, Keyssar, Alexander, Out of Work: The First Century of Unemployment in Massachusetts (Cambridge, Mass., 1986), 133–35.Google Scholar

18. Wells, O. V., “Depression of 1873–79,” Agricultural History (1937): 240–47Google Scholar; Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, A. J., A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (Princeton, 1963), 3444.Google Scholar

19. Hart, Albert B., Commonwealth History of Massachusetts, vol. 5 (New York, 1930, 1966 ed.), 352Google Scholar; Bogart and Thompson, Industrial State, 289; Swisher, Carl B., Motivation and Political Technique in the California Constitutional Convention, 1878–79 (Claremont, Calif., 1930), 9.Google Scholar

20. Bullock, Charles J., Historical Sketch of the Finances and Fiscal Policy of Massachusetts from 1780 to 1905 (New York, 1907), 139Google Scholar (appendix A); Huse, Charles P., The Financial History of Boston, 1822–1909 (Cambridge, Mass., 1916), 206–11Google Scholar; Bogart and Thompson, Industrial State, 289, 302; Miller, Edmund T., A Financial History of Texas (Austin, 1916), 416–17Google Scholar (table 14), 399; Swisher, California Constitutional Contention, 7–9.

21. Sylla, Richard, “Long-Term Trends in State and Local Finance: Sources and Uses of Funds in North Carolina, 1800–1977,” in Engerman, S. and Gallman, R., eds., Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth (Chicago, 1986), 842–43Google Scholar; Platt, Harold, City Building in the New South: The Growth of Public Services in Houston, Texas, 1830–1910 (Philadelphia, 1983), 5163Google Scholar; Monkkonen, Eric H., The Local State: Public Money and American Cities (Stanford, Calif., 1995), 26, 68.Google Scholar

22. Yearley, Clifton K., The Money Machines: The Breakdown and Reform of Governmental and Party Finance in the North, 1860–1920 (Albany, N.Y., 1970), esp. chap. 1Google Scholar; also Teaford, Jon C., The Unheralded Triumph: City Government in America, 1870–1900 (Baltimore, 1984), 287304Google Scholar; Swisher, California Constitutional Convention, 66–85.

23. Goodrich, “Revulsion Against Internal Improvements”; Secrist, Horace, An Economic Analysis of the Constitutional Restrictions upon Public Indebtedness in the United States (Madison, Wis., 1914), 5960Google Scholar, and appendixes I-III; Illinois Legislative Reference Bureau, “State and Local Finance,” Constitutional Convention Bulletins (Springfield, 1920), 4:294300.Google Scholar

24. The crisis of subnational finance in the 1930s is summarized in Campbell, Ballard C., The Growth of American Government: Governance from the Cleveland Era to the Present (Bloomington, Ind., 1995), 8387, 178–81.Google Scholar

25. Beito, David T., Taxpayers in Revolt: Tax Resistance During the Great Depression (Chapel Hill, 1989), chap. 1, 141Google Scholar; Adams, James R., Secret of the Tax Revolt (San Diego, 1984), 277Google Scholar; Hartley, James E., Sheffrin, S., and Vasche, J. D., “Reform During Crises: The Transformation of California's Fiscal System During the Great Depression,” journal of Economic History (1996): 660–62Google Scholar; Gorvine, Harold, “The New Deal in Massachusetts,” in Braeman, John, Bremner, R., and Brody, D., The New Deal (Columbus, Ohio, 1975), 2:1320.Google Scholar

26. Campbell, Growth of American Government, 179–84.

27. In 1975 joblessness rose to 8.5 percent, but the CPI dropped only to 9.1 percent, down from 11.0 percent in the previous year. The 1975 stagflation rate of 17.6 was exceeded only by 1980 (20.6) and 1981 (17.9).

28. Vogel, David, Fluctuating Fortunes: The Political Power of Business in America (New York, 1990), esp. chaps. 6 and 7Google Scholar; Ferguson, Thomas and Rodgers, Joel, Right Turn: The Decline of the Democrats and the Future of American Politics (New York, 1986), chap. 3Google Scholar; Gordon, David M., Fat and Mean: The Corporate Squeeze of Working Americans and the Myth of Managerial “Downsizing” (New York, 1996), 69, 81, 262, and chap. 8.Google Scholar

29. Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr., The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics (Cambridge, Mass., 1987), 138–41Google Scholar; Kiewiet, D. Roderick, “Policy-Oriented Voting in Response to Economic Issues,” American Political Science Review 75 (1981): 448–59.Google Scholar

30. Wilson, George, Inflation: Causes, Consequences, and Cures (Bloomington, Ind., 1982), chap. 6Google Scholar; Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, 201–8; Kaufman, George G., “Inflation, Proposition 13 Fever, and Suggested Relief,” in Kaufman, and Rosen, K., eds., The Property Tax Revolt: The Case of Proposition 13 (Cambridge, Mass., 1981), 215–17Google Scholar. See the index of consumer confidence in Stanley, Harold W. and Niemi, R., Vital Statistics on American Politics (Washington, D.C., 1995), 400Google Scholar. White quoted in Nocera, Joseph, A Piece of the Action: How the Middle Class Joined the Moneyed Class (New York, 1994), 178.Google Scholar

31. Edsall, Thomas B., Chain Reaction: The Impact of Race, Rights, and Taxes on American Politics (New York, 1992)Google Scholar; Bernstein, Michael A. and Adler, D., eds., Understanding American Economic Decline (New York, 1994).Google Scholar

32. Campbell, Growth of American Government, 113, 182.

33. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Intergovernmental Perspective 7 (Fall 1981): 27Google Scholar; Mishel, Lawrence, Bernstein, J., and Schmitt, J., The State of Working America, 1996–1997 (Washington, D.C., 1996), 9697Google Scholar; ACIR, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1984 (Washington, D.C., 1985), table 36Google Scholar; ACIR, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1976–77 (Washington, D.C., 1977), table 76Google Scholar; ACIR, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1990 (Washington, D.C., 1992), table 82.Google Scholar

34. Miller, Warren E. and Traugott, Santa A., American National Election Studies Data Sourcebook (Cambridge, Mass., 1989), 272, 274.Google Scholar

35. New York Times, 11 November 1989; Linda, L. M. and Bennett, Stephen E., Living with Leviathan: Americans Coming to Terms with Big Government (Lawrence, Kan., 1990), 2734.Google Scholar

36. Bennett, Leviathan, 87; Sears, David O. and Citrin, Jack, Tax Revolt: Something for Nothing in California (Cambridge, Mass., 1982), 4770Google Scholar, 231; Ferguson, Right Turn, 18–19; Campbell, Growth of American Government, 234.

37. Lipset, Seymour M. and Schneider, William, The Confidence Gap: Business, Labor, and Government in the Public Mind (New York, 1983), 151–59Google Scholar; Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, 8, 18, 331; Bennett, Leviathan, 81; Page, Benjamin and Shapiro, Robert, “Changes in Americans' Policy Preferences,” Political Science Quarterly (1982): 38Google Scholar; Hibbs, American Political Economy, 128–33.

38. Lowery, David and Sigelman, Lee, “Understanding the Tax Revolt: Eight Explanations,” American Political Science Review (1981): 963–74Google Scholar; Broder, David, “The Puzzlement of Taxation,” Boston Globe, 29 February 1979Google Scholar. Also Sears and Citrin, Tax Revolt, 208–15, 230–31; Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, 164; Jack Citrin, Introduction, in Schwadron, Terry, ed., California and the American Tax Revolt (Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1984), 1617.Google Scholar

39. Mayhew, David R., Placing Parties in American Politics (Princeton, 1986), chap. 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Mayhew found that strong partisan traditions were consistently related to small public economics between 1953 and 1980, although the relationship diminished to near zero over time.

40. Nevada voters passed a Proposition 13 clone as a constitutional initiative in 1978, but they rejected it in 1980 on the required second referendum. In the intervening year the legislature adopted a tax-reform and expenditure-limit measure.

41. Moreover, states in the traditional-party/no initiative category that enacted limitation measures had lower readings on the Mayhew Traditional Party Organization scale than did the states that avoided cap laws. The three states that adopted property-levy limitations were Indiana, Louisiana, and New Mexico.

42. The median “tax burden” (state-local tax revenue as a percentage of personal income) among strong-party states where limitations were adopted was 11.6 percent and 12.2 percent where they were not. Among the weak-party states, the median tax burden among states that adopted limitations was 12.7 percent and 11.6 percent among states that did not. The tax burden among the six states where voters initiated property tax limitations (California et al.) was 12.9 percent.

The median percentage reduction in revenue dependence on local property taxes between FY 67 and FY 77 was -22 percent for all fifty states, but only -11.5 percent for the six Proposition 13-type states (California et al.), signifying that latter group had lagged in reforming property taxes.

43. Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, chaps. 1–6; Sears and Citrin, Tax Revolt; Kaufman, “Inflation,” 217–19; Couch, Winston W., Bollens, J., and Scott, S., California Government and Politics (Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1981), esp. 234–35, 276–77Google Scholar; Adams, Secret of the Tax Revolt, chap. 6.

44. On proposition 2 ½: Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, 162–63, chap. 8; Tevdt, “Enough Is Enough”; Adams, Secret of the Tax Revolt, chap. 12; Susskind, Lawrence and Horan, Cynthia, “Proposition 2 ½: The Response to Tax Restrictions in Massachusetts,” Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science (1983), 5771Google Scholar; Hale, Dennis, “Massachusetts: William F. Weld and the End of Business as Usual,” in Beyle, Thad L., ed., Governors and Hard Times (Washington, D.C., 1992).Google Scholar

45. Dwyre, Diana, O'Gorman, M., Stonecash, J., and Young, R., “Disorganized Politics and the Have-Nots: Politics and Taxes in New York and California,” Polity (1994): 2932Google Scholar, 35–37; Adams, Secrets of the Tax Revolt, chap. 5.

46. Stark, Bennett S., “The Political Economy of State Public Finance: A Model of the Determinants of Revenue Policy: the Illinois Case, 1850–1970” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin, Madison, 1982)Google Scholar; Gove, Samuel K. and Masotti, Louis H., eds., After Daley: Chicago Politics in Transition (Urbana, III. 1981)Google Scholar, esp. chapters by Gove and Milton Rakove; Kuttner, Revolt of the Haves, 300–301; New York Times, 8 March 1979; Parker, Joan A., The Illinois Tax Increase of 1983: Summit and Resolution (Springfield, III., 1984), 1012.Google Scholar

47. Dwyre, “Disorganized Politics,” 44–46. Break, George, “Proposition 13's Tenth Birthday,” in Stocker, Frederick D., ed., Proposition 13: A Ten-Year Retrospective (Cambridge, Mass., 1991), 191–93Google Scholar, discounted a major shift toward regressivity in California.

48. Suskind, “Proposition 2 ½,” 160–63; Division of Local Services, Massachusetts Department of Revenue, City and Town (November 1994), 4, and (December 1993), 6.

49. Rodney T. Smith, “Local Fiscal Arrangements, Home Rule, and California's Fiscal Constitution After Proposition 13,” in Stocker, Proposition 13, 79–80; O'Sullivan, Arthur, Sexton, Terri A., and Sheffrin, Steven M., Property Taxes and Tax Revolts: The Legacy of Proposition 13 (New York, 1995), 115, 137CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Schwadron, California and the American Tax Revolt, 80.

50. See the essays by Richard W. Gable on California and Dennis Hall on Massachusetts in Beyle, Governors and Hard Times, and the chapters by Jeffrey I. Chapman on California and Bruce Wallin on Massachusetts in Gold, Steven D., ed., The Fiscal Crisis of the States (Washington, D.C., 1995).Google Scholar

51. Sears and Citrin, Tax Revolt, 41.

52. Campbell, The Growth of American Government, chap. 10.

53. Campbell, The Growth of American Government, 2–5, and Federalism and Public Performance: Perspectives on American Political Development (forthcoming) develops this typology.