Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-767nl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-09T00:14:27.493Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social Restraints on Food Production in Indonesian Subsistence Culture

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 April 2011

Extract

In 1968 David E. Bell, vice-president of the Ford Foundation, said: “Fifteen years ago, many thought it was a relatively simple matter to raise farm output in less-developed countries. All that was needed was to make U.S. technology available to the farmers in those countries by establishing extension services or their equivalent. This notion rapidly proved to be a monumental misconception.” The monumental misconception was that peasants in less-developed countries would be eager to maximize food production in order to overcome perennial food shortages, if they had the opportunity to learn the techniques of Western agriculture. This did not happen. Indonesian peasants, after learning of the techniques of the Green Revolution, rejected full participation in it. Why? Many observers in Indonesia and elsewhere have partially explained this rejection but in my opinion they missed the main reason because they failed to recognize that peasant cultures have social values and institutions that act as strong restraints on food production.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The National University of Singapore 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Bell, David E., “Can World Famine Be Prevented?” Ford Foundation Reprint (1968), 7Google Scholar.

2 Soemardjan, Selo, “The Influence of Social Structure on the Javanese Peasant Economy,” Wharton, Clifton R. Jr., ed., Subsistence Agriculture and Economic Development (Chicago: Aldine, 1969), pp. 4546.Google Scholar

3 Hodder, B. W., Economic Development in the Tropics, (London: Methuen, 1971), pp. 119142Google Scholar. Another author, after listing government inadequacies, assigns the rest of the blame for India's chronic food shortage to the “peasant's natural conservatism”: see Lewis, John P., Quiet Crisis in India: Economic Development and American Policy, (Garden City: Doubleday Anchor Books, 1964), pp. 155157Google Scholar.

4 Kuznets, Simon, “Economic Aspects of Fertility,” Behrman, S.J., Corsa, L. Jr., and Freedman, R., eds., Fertility and Family Planning — A World View, (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969), p. 176Google Scholar.

5 Koentjaraningrat, , “The Village in Indonesia Today,” in Koentjaraningrat, , ed., Villages in Indonesia (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1967), p. 403.Google Scholar

6 Penny, David H., “Indonesia” in Shand, Richard T., ed., Agricultural Development in Asia (Canberra: Australian National University Press, 1969), p. 263.Google Scholar

7 See Nash, Manning, Primitive and Peasant Economic Systems (San Francisco: Chandler, 1966), p. 25Google Scholar; Dewey, Alice, “Capital, Credit and Saving in Javanese Marketing,” in Firth, Raymond and Yamey, B.S., eds., Capital Saving and Credit in Peasant Societies (Chicago: Aldine, 1964), pp. 231234, 239–242;Google Scholar and Foster, Brian L., “Ethnicity and Commerce,” American Ethnologist, Vol. 1 (1974), 440441CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 Koentjaraningrat, ed., Villages in Indonesia, pp. 16–21

9 van der Kroef, Justus M., “Land Tenure and Social Structure in Rural Java,” Rural Sociology, Vol. 25 (1960), 415420Google Scholar; and Geertz, Clifford, The Social History of an Indonesian Town (Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1965), pp. 2125.Google Scholar

10 Clifford Geertz, op-cit. p. 25.

11 See Spencer, Joseph E., Shifting Cultivation in Southeastern Asia (Berkeley: U. of Calif. Press, 1966), pp. 7677, 86–93Google Scholar; Pelzer, Karl J., Pioneer Settlement in the Asiatic Tropics (New York: American Geographical Society, 1945), pp. 165167, 255Google Scholar; and Jay, Robert R., Javanese Villagers: Social Relations in Rural Modjokuto (Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1969), pp. 194.Google Scholar

12 Brewster, John M., “Beliefs, Values and Economic Development,” Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 43 (1961), 783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 See Boserup, Ester, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth (Chicago: Aldine, 1965), pp. 2931, 46–48Google Scholar; Clark, Colin and Haswell, Margaret, The Economics of Subsistence Agriculture (London: Macmillan, 1970), p. 45CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Seavoy, Ronald E., “The Transition to Continuous Rice Cultivation in Kalimantan,” Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 63 (1973), 218225CrossRefGoogle Scholar; idem., The Origin and Use of Tropical Grasslands on Kalimantan, Indonesia,” Journal of Tropical Geography, Vol. 40 (1975), 4852.Google Scholar

14 See Kampto Utomo, “Villages of Unplanned Resettlers in the Subdistrict Kaliredjo, Central Lampung,” in Koentjaraningrat, ed., Villages in Indonesia, pp. 293–297; and Clark, Colin and Haswell, Margaret, The Economics of Subsistence Agriculture (London: Macmillan, 1970), pp. 5455, 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Wertheim, W.F. and The Siauw Giap, “Social Change in Java, 1900–1930,” Pacific Affairs, Vol. 35 (1962), 223227CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The failure of the Dutch-sponsored Ethical Policy, initiated in 1901, was due to an attempt to maximize food production by commercializing peasant agriculture. Peasants today are rejecting ingredients of the Green Revolution for much the same reasons. See my Conclusion.

16 I have used three sources to shape the generalizations of this article: (1) the scholarly literature of economics, sociology, geography, and anthropology; (2) my own extensive travels as an exploration geologist through the archipelago; and (3) early accounts of travellers through the Netherlands Indies, especially those of naturalists who visited parts of Java which today are densely populated but were then nearly vacant. The descriptions of old vacant areas of Java resemble conditions that are now found on many of the outer islands. The naturalists' accounts usually described the agricultural technology that was being used in the districts they passed through because this information was directly related to the kinds of plants and animals that were available for collecting. See especially Bartlett, Harley H., Fire in Relation to Primitive Agriculture and Grazing in the Tropics (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1955, 1961)Google Scholar, an annotated bibliography in 3 volumes. The following observers were consulted: F.M. van Asbeck, W. W. Feither, and A.T. A. van den Unen (1915); A. Ballot (1904); H. A.B. Bunnemeyer (1918); Henry O. Forbes (1878–1883); Julius Jacobs (1894); Franz Junghuhn (1847–1854); William Marsden (1783); Alfred R. Wallace (1869).

17 Freeman, J. D., Iban Agriculture (London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office, 1955), p. 81Google Scholar. It is highly likely that when observers of peasant societies make the statement ‘agricultural labour is considered to be woman's work’, it means that such labour has a low social value while hunting, herding, and war have a high social value.

18 Koentjaraningrat, “The Village in Indonesia Today”; Andrea W. Palmer, “Siturdja: A Village in Highland Priangan”; and Koentjaraningrat, “Tjelapar: A Village in South Central Java,” in Koentjaraningrat, ed., Villages in Indonesia, pp. 394–397, 320, 274.

19 van der Kroef, Justus M., “Entrepreneur and Middle Class in Indonesia,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 2 (1954), 312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Geertz, Clifford, “Religious Belief and Economic Behavior in a Central Javanese Town: Some Preliminary Considerations,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 4 (1956), 139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21 Wolf, Eric R., “Closed Corporate Peasant Communities in Mesoamerica and Central Java,” Southwestern Journal of Anthropology, Vol. 13 (1957), 25CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Potlatches, as formerly practised by the Indians of the Northwest coast of North America, are an extravagant form of consumption in a subsistence society but they differ only by degree from similar expenditures of wealth connected with marriages, funerals and pilgrimages in other subsistence societies (Manning Nash, Primitive and Peasant Economic Systems, pp. 25, 73).

22 A slametan consists mostly of rice so that no person leaves without satisfying his hunger. The condiments for a group of twenty men consists of four or five small bowls of spiced vegetables, chili peppers, and chopped fish or meat so that everyone present gets a little sauce to put on his rice and a small mouthful of meat. For an excellent description, see Jay, Robert R., Javanese Villagers: Social Relations in Rural Modjokuto (Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1969), pp. 206216.Google Scholar

23 van der Kroef, Justus M., “Entrepreneur and Middle Class in Indonesia,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 2 (1954), 311312CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24 Foster, George M., “Peasant Society and the Image of Limited Good,” American Anthropologist, Vol. 67 (1965), 301308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

25 Nitisastro, Widjojo, Population Trends in Indonesia (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1970), pp. 1926, 174, 208.Google Scholar

26 Furnivall, John S., Colonial Policy and Practice (New York: N.Y. University Press, 1956), p. 223.Google Scholar

27 Ester Boserup, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth, p. 61.

28 Geertz, Clifford, Agricultural Involution: The Process of Ecological Change in Indonesia, (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1971), p. 80Google Scholar.

29 Foster, George M., “Peasant Society and the Image of Limited Good,” American Anthropologist, Vol. 67 (1965), 307CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30 Myint, Hia, The Economics of Developing Countries (New York: Praeger, 1969), p. 44.Google Scholar

31 Hayami, Yujiro and Ruttan, Vernon W., Agricultural Development: An International Perspective (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1971), pp. 1724.Google Scholar

32 See Boeke, Julius H., The Evolution of the Netherlands Indies Economy (New York: Institute of Pacific Relations, 1946), pp. 25, 112–113Google Scholar; and Clifford Geertz, Agricultural Involution, p. 105.

33 See Clifford Geertz, Agricultural Involution, 120; and Mellor, John W., The Economics of Agricultural Development (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1966), pp. 148149.Google Scholar

34 van der Kroef, Justus M., “Economic Development in Indonesia; Some Social and Cultural Impediments,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 4 (1956), 120122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 Clifford Geertz, Agricultural Involution, p. 123.

36 Ibid., p. 116.

37 Ibid., p. 122.

38 Ibid., p. 110.

39 Ibid., p. 142.

40 Rostow, Walt W., The Process of Economic Growth (New York: Norton, 1962), pp. 1113, 20–22.Google Scholar

41 Schutjer, Wayne A. and Coward, E. Walter Jr., “Planning Agricultural Development — The Matter of Priorities,” Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 6 (1971), 38.Google Scholar