Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-08T03:21:16.642Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fisher and Veblen: Two Paths for American Economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

In the early years of the twentieth century, two outspoken and brilliant American economists, Thorstein Veblen and Irving Fisher, offered sharply-contrasting visions of how the discipline of economics should be transformed. Each taught at a leading university and had added prominence as a journal editor, but pursued economic inquiry in ways alien to senior colleagues at his university and in the profession at large. Despite the gulf separating their approaches to economics, they had been doctoral students of the same mentor, William Graham Sumner of Yale, and had each been deeply influenced by Sumner. This paper uses the exchange on neoclassical capital theory between Veblen and Fisher in the Political Science Quarterly in 1908 and 1909 to illuminate their approaches to economics and to question why the American economics profession came to follow Fisher's path–even though Veblen, unlike Fisher, attracted devoted disciples and was considered in American social thought (excepting academic economists) as the standard-bearer of “the New Economics.” Despite Veblen's antipathy to those aspects of Fisher's work that became dominant in mainstream economics, there was a close affinity between Veblen's Theory of Business Enterprise (1904) and Fisher's debt-deflation theory of depressions, which remained (until very recently) outside the mainstream and has been taken up by such heterodox economists as Hyman Minsky.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Allen, Robert Loring. 1993. Irving Fisher: A Biography, Blackwell Publishers, Cambridge, MA, and Oxford, UK.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1975. “Thorstein Veblen as an Economic Theorist,” The American Economist, 19, no. 1, 5–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, William J. 1988. “The Fortunes of Political Economy in an Atmosphere of Academic Conservatism,” in Barber, William J., ed., Breaking the Academic Mould: Economists and American Higher Learning in the Nineteenth Century, Wesleyan University Press, Middle-town, CT, pp. 132–68, 400–405.Google Scholar
Canning, John B. 1929. The Economics of Accountancy: A Critical Analysis of Accounting Theory, The Ronald Press Co., New York.Google Scholar
Chambers, R. J. 1971. “Income and Capital: Fisher's Legacy,” Journal of Accounting Research, 9, no. 1, 137–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, R. J. 1979. “Canning's The Economics of Accountancy—After 50 Years,” The Accounting Review, 10, 764–75.Google Scholar
Coats, A. W. 1954. “The Influence of Veblen's Methodology,” Journal of Political Economy, 62, no. 6, 12, 529–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commager, Henry Steele. 1950. The American Mind, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1907. “Political Economy and Business Economy: Comments on Fisher's Capital and Income,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 22, 11, 120–25.Google Scholar
Covaleski, M. and Dirsmith, M.. 1991. “Maintaining Accounting as the Paramount Interest in Accounting Research: Re-Examining the Contributions of DR Scott,” The Accounting Historians Journal, 18, no. 1, 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1991. “Cranks, Heretics and Macroeconomics in the 1930s,” History of Economics Review, 16, Summer, 11–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1994. “Irving Fisher's Debt–Deflation Theory of Great Depressions,” Review of Social Economy, 52, no. 1, 92–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1995. “Irving Fisher, J. M. Keynes and the Transition to Modern Macroeconomics,” in Cottrell, Allin F. and Lawlor, Michael S., eds., News Perspectives on Keynes, annual supplement to History of Political Economy, 27, Duke University Press, Durham, pp. 247–66.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph. 1934. Thorstein Veblen and His America, with new appendices, Augustus M. Kelley, Reprints of Economic Classics, New York, 1966.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph. 1973. “New Light on Veblen,” in Veblen, 1973, 5–326.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Thrainn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions, Cambridge Surveys of Economic Literature, Cambridge University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fetter, Frank A. 1907. “The Nature of Capital and Income,” Journal of Political Economy, 15, 03, 129–48, as reprinted in Frank A. Fetter, Capital, Interest and Rent: Essays in the Theory of Distribution, edited by Rothbard, Murray N., Sheed Andrews and McMeel, Kansas City, 1977.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1892. “Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices,” Transactions of the Connecticut Academy, 9, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 1.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1896. “Appreciation and Interest,” Publications of the American Economic Association, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 1.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1906. The Nature of Capital and Income, Macmillan, New York, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1907. The Rate of Interest, Macmillan, New York, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 3.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1907a. “Professor Fetter on Capital and Income,” Journal of Political Economy, 15, 07, 421–34, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1909a. “Capital and Interest,” Political Science Quarterly, 24, no. 3, 504–16; excerpted in Fisher, 1997, 3, pp. 475–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1909b. “A Reply to Critics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 23, 05, 536–41; excerpts on Flux and Commons reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 3, pp. 473–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving, with Brown, Harry G.. 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money, Macmillan, New York, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 4.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1930. The Theory of Interest, Macmillan, New York, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 9.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions, Adelphi, New York, as reprinted in Fisher 1997, 10.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933. “The Debt–Deflation Theory of Great Depressions,” Econometrica, 1, no. 3, 10, 337–57, as reprinted in Fisher, 1997, 10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1997. Works of Irving Fisher, 14 vols, edited by Barber, William J. assisted by Dimand, Robert W. and Kevin, Foster, consulting editor James, Tobin, Pickering and Chatto, London.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving Norton. 1956. My Father Irving Fisher, Comet, New York.Google Scholar
Johnson, Alvin. 1950. Pioneer's Progress, University of Nebraska Press, Lincoln.Google Scholar
Lee, T. A. 1975. “The Contribution of Fisher to Enterprise Income Theory: A Comment,” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 2, no. 3, 373–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, T. A. 1979. “The Contribution of Fisher to Cash Flow Accounting,” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 6, no. 3, 321–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C., ed. 1936. What Veblen Taught, Viking Press, New York.Google Scholar
Mouck, Tom. 1995. “Irving Fisher and the Mechanistic Character of Twentieth Century Accounting Thought,” The Accounting Historians Journal, 22, no. 2, 43–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polner, Murray. 1965. “Introduction” to William Graham, Sumner, The Conquest of the United States by Spain and Other Essays, edited by Polner, M., Henry Regnery and Company, Chicago.Google Scholar
Ross, Dorothy. 1991. The Origins of American Social Science, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York.Google Scholar
Rostow, Walt W. 1940. “James Harvey Rogers as an Economist,” in James Harvey Rogers (1886–1939) In Memoriam, Overbrook Press, Stamford, CT, 15–28.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1994. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ryan, Christopher K. 1987. Harry Gunnison Brown: Economist, Westview Press, Boulder.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1987. “Sumner, William Graham (1840–1910),” in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Stockton Press, London, 4, 548–49.Google Scholar
Scott, D. R. 1931. The Cultural Significance of Accounts, Henry Holt and Company, New York.Google Scholar
Sowell, Thomas. 1987. “Veblen, Thorstein (1857–1929),” in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Stockton Press, London, 4, 799–800.Google Scholar
Stabile, Donald. 1984. Prophets of Order: The Rise of the New Class, Technocracy and Socialism in America, South End Press, Boston.Google Scholar
Steindl, Frank G. 1993. “Yale and the Monetary Interpretation of the Great Depression,” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 33, no. 4, Winter, 305–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1874. A History of American Currency, Holt, New York.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1883. What Social Classes Owe Each Other, Harper, New York.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1884. Lectures on the History of Protection in the United States, Putnam's Sons, New York.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1885. Protectionism: The -Ism which Teaches that Wastes Makes Wealth, Holt, New York.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham, et al. 1896. “A History of Banking in All Leading Nations,” Journal of Commerce and Commercial Bulletin, New York.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1899. “The Conquest of the United States by Spain,” Yale Law Journal, 8, 168–93, as reprinted in William Graham Sumner, The Conquest of the United States by Spain and Other Essays, edited by Murray, Polner, Henry Regnery Company, Chicago, 1965.Google Scholar
Sumner, William Graham. 1907. Folkways, Ginn, Boston; reprint, Mentor, New York, 1960.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class, Viking Press, New York; reprint, Penguin, New York, 1979.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1904. The Theory of Business Enterprise, Charles Scribner's Sons, New York; reprint, Mentor Books, New York, n. d. [1958?].Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1908. “Fisher's Capital and Income,” Political Science Quarterly, 23, no. 1, 112–28, as reprinted in Veblen, 1934, 148–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thostein Bunde. 1909. “Fisher's Rate of Interest,” Political Science Quarterly, 24, no. 2, 296–303, as reprinted in Veblen, 1934, 137–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1919. The Place of Science in Modern Civilization and Other Essays, B. W. Huebsch, New York; reprint, Russell and Russell, New York, 1961.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1934. Essays in Our Changing Order, edited by Leon, Ardzrooni, Viking, New York.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1948. The Portable Veblen, edited by Max, Lerner, Viking, New York.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein Bunde. 1973. Essays, Reviews and Reports, edited by Joseph, Dorfman, Augustus M. Kelley, Clifton, NJ.Google Scholar
Velupillai, K. 1975. “Irving Fisher on Switches of Technique: A Historical Note,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89, no. 4, 679–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Morton. 1949. Social Thought in America: The Revolt Against Formalism, 2nd ed., Viking, New York; reprinted Beacon Press, Boston, 1957.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver. 1998. “Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works, Where It is Headed,” De Economist, 146, no. 1, 04, 23–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar