Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-cjp7w Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-07T23:19:53.722Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HAYEK'S READINGS OF MILL

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2008

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Barry, Norman. 1979. Hayek's Social and Economic Philosophy. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cairnes, John Elliot. 1874. Some Leading Principles of Political Economy Newly Expounded. New York: Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce. 2003. Hayek's Challenge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dostaler, Gilles. 2001. Le libéralisme de Hayek. Paris: La Découverte.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dupuy, Jean-Pierre. 1992. Le sacrifice et l'envie. Paris: Calmann-Lévy.Google Scholar
Ebenstein, Alan. 2001. Friedrich Hayek: A Biography. New York: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Ebenstein, Alan. 2003. Hayek's Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek. London: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, John. 1984. Hayek on Liberty. London: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1931. Prices and Production. London: Routledge, 1946.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1932. “A Note on the Development of the Doctrine of Forced Saving.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 47 (1): 123–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1939. “The Economic Conditions of Interstate Federalism.” In Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 255–72.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1941. “The Counter-Revolution of Science.” In The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason. Indianapolis: Liberty Press, 1979, pp. 183–363.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1942. “J.S. Mill at the Age of Twenty-five.” In Mill, John Stuart, The Spirit of the Age. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. v–xxxiii.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1943. “J.S. Mill's Correspondence.” In Cunningham Wood, John, ed., John Stuart Mill Critical Assessments, Vol. 4. London: Routledge, 1988, pp. 40–43.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1944. The Road to Serfdom. London: Routledge, 1991.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1945. “Individualism: True and False.” In Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 1–32.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1947a. “Opening Address to a Conference at Mont Pélerin.” In The Fortunes of Liberalism. London: Routledge, 1992, pp. 237–48.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1947b. “‘Free’ Enterprise and Competitive Order.” In Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 107–18.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1951. John Stuart Mill and Harriet Taylor. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1954. “Introduction.” In Michael St John, Packe, The Life of John Stuart Mill. London: Secker and Warburg.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1962. “Introduction.” In Mineka, Francis, ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 12. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1963. “The Legal and Political Philosophy of David Hume.” In Economic Freedom. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1991, pp. 101–18.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1968. “A Tiger by the Tail, Section 24 (from a draft for “Competition as a Discovery Procedure”).” In Economic Freedom. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1991, pp. 83–88.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1973. “Liberalism.” In New Studies. London: Routledge, 1978, pp. 119–51.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1976. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. 2: The Mirage of Social Justice. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1979. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. 3: The Political Order of a Free People. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1978. “Hayek interviewed by Jack High.” Transcription by The Idea Channel (www.ideachannel.com).40Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1981. “The Muddle of the Middle.” In Pejovich, Svetozar, ed., Philosophical and Economic Foundations of Capitalism. Lexington: Lexington Books, 1983, pp. 89–100.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1984. “1980s Unemployment and the Unions.” In Economic Freedom. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1991, pp. 315–55.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1988. The Fatal Conceit, the Errors of Socialism. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 1994. Hayek on Hayek. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobsbawm, Eric. 1992. “Libéralisme et socialisme: le cas anglais.” Genèses 9 (October): 44–59.Google Scholar
Hollander, Samuel. 1985. The Economics of John Stuart Mill. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Horwitz, Steven. 2005. “Friedrich Hayek, Austrian Economist: Review Essay of Caldwell and Ebenstein.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (1): 71–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Légé, Philippe. 2005a. “Friedrich Hayek critique de John Stuart Mill: une réflexion sur la notion de justice sociale.” Economies et Sociétés, Oeconomia, Histoire de la Pensée Economique 37 (October): 1819–48.Google Scholar
Légé, Philippe. 2005b. Le libéralisme de Hayek à la lumière de sa lecture de John Stuart Mill. Thèse de doctorat de science Economique. Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne.Google Scholar
Levy, David and Peart, Sandra. 2005. “A Discipline without Sympathy.” Canadian Journal of Economics 38 (3): 937–54.Google Scholar
Levy, David and Peart, Sandra. 2006. “Discussion, Construction and Evolution: Mill, Buchanan and Hayek on the Constitutional Order.” Paper presented at the Summer Institute for the Preservation of the History of Economics, Fairfax, July 10-15.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1836. “On the Definition of Political Economy, and the Method Proper to It.” In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 4. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 309–39.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1843. A System of Logic Ratiocinative and Inductive. In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vols. 7, 8. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1848. Principles of Political Economy. London: A.M. Kelley, 1987.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1849. “Vindication of the French Revolution of February 1848.” In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 20. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 319–59.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1859. On Liberty. In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 18. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 213–310.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1861. Utilitarianism. In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 10. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 203–59.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1865. Auguste Comte and Positivism. In Robson, John M., ed., The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 10. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 261–368.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1873. Autobiography. London: Penguin Classics, 1989.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig. 1927. Liberalism, 2nd edition. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, 1962.Google Scholar
Seiz, Janet and Pujol, Michèle. 2000. “Harriet Taylor Mill.” The American Economic Review 90 (2): 476–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vardaman. 1985. “John Stuart Mill's Famous Distinction between Production and Distribution.” Economics and Philosophy 1: 267–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varouxakis, Georgios. 2002. Mill on Nationality. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar