Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-n9wrp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T09:33:22.687Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HIGH LEVELS OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE MERCANTILIST ERA

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 April 2014

John M. Letiche*
Affiliation:
Professor Emeritus, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley.

Abstract

This article draws attention to the high levels of unemployment in the mercantilist era, a parallel to conditions in the less developed countries at the present time. Understandably, distinguished economists of the twentieth century, writing before the publication of Keynes’ General Theory, tended to underestimate this problem. Actual causes of the high levels of unemployment are examined, including the fluctuating impacts of merchant entrepreneurs, agricultural revolutions, political unrest, and warfare, as well as nutritional deficiencies, which contributed directly to unemployment.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Anonymous, . 1549Policies to Reduce this Realme of Englande Unto a Prosperous Wealthe and Estate” (MS 1549). In Tawney, R. H. and Power, Eileen, eds., Tudor Economic Documents. 1924. London: Longmans, Green, vol. 3, pp. 311345.Google Scholar
Anonymous, . 1641. Considerations Touching Trade, With the Advance of the King’s Revenue. London.Google Scholar
Becher, J. J. 1688. Politischer Discurs von den eigentlichen Ursachen, dess Auff- und Abnehmens der Städt, Länder und Republicken. Third edition. Frankfurt: Zunner.Google Scholar
Butcher, David. 2008. Lowestoft, 1550–1750: Development and Change in a Suffolk Coastal Town. Woodbridge: Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Cary, John. 1745. A Discourse on Trade, and Other Matters Relative to It. Fifth edition. London: Printed for T. Osborne.Google Scholar
Cau, Cornelis, ed. 1664. Groot Placaet-Boeck. Graven-Hage: Hillebrandt Van Wouw.Google Scholar
Cholmeley, William. 1553. “The Request and Suite of a True-Hearted Englishman.” MS 1553. In Thoms, W. J., ed., The Camden Miscellany. London: The Camden Society.Google Scholar
Clark, Gregory. 2012. “Review Essay: The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850 by Joel Mokyr.” Journal of Economic Literature 50 (1): 8595.Google Scholar
Clark, Peter. 1979. “Migration in England During the Late Seventeenth and Early Eighteenth Centuries.” Past and Present 83, 1 (May): 5790.Google Scholar
Cole, Charles W. 1939. Colbert and a Century of French Mercanitlism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Cole, Charles W. 1943. French Mercantilism, 1683-1700. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, D. C. 1956. “Labour in the English Economy of the Seventeenth Century.” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 8, 3 (April): 280295.Google Scholar
Davenant, Charles. [1695] 1967a. “An Essay upon Ways and Means.” In Whitworth, Sir Charles, ed., The Political and Commercial Works of That Celebrated Writer Charles D’avenant. Farnborough, U.K.: Gregg Press, vol. 1, pp. 19, 72, 205.Google Scholar
Davenant, Charles. [1699] 1967b. “An Essay upon the Probable Methods of Making a People Gainers in the Balance of Trade.” In Charles Whitworth, Sir, ed., The Political and Commercial Works of That Celebrated Writer Charles D’avenant. Farnborough, UK: Gregg Press, vol. 2, pp. 204, 221, 236–238.Google Scholar
Davenant, Charles. [1771] 1967c. “A Second Report to the Honourable Commisioners.” In Whitworth, Sir Charles, ed., The Political and Commercial Works of That Celebrated Writer Charles D’avenant. Farnborough, U.K.: Gregg Press, vol. 5, p. 456.Google Scholar
Deane, Phyllis. 1965. The First Industrial Revolution. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Decker, Matthew. [1744] 1750. An Essay On the Causes of the Decline of the Foreign Trade. Second edition. London: Printed for J. Brotherton.Google Scholar
DeVries, Jan. 1976. The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600–1750. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
DeVries, Jan. 2001. “Economic Growth Before and After the Industrial Revolution: A Modest Proposal.” In Prak, Maarten, ed., Early Modern Capitalism: Economic and Social Change in Europe 1400-1800. London: Routledge, pp. 177194.Google Scholar
Fisher, F. J. 1990. London and the English Economy, 1500–1700. London: Hambledon Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W., DeVries, Jan (contributor), and Johnson, Paul (contributor). 2004. Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100: Europe, America, and the Third World. West Nyack, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fortrey, Samuel. [1663, 1856] 1954. England’s Interest and Improvement. In McCulloch, J. R., A Select Collection of Early English Tracts. London: Cambridge University Press, p. 15.Google Scholar
Gee, Joshua. [1729] 1731. The Trade and Navigation of Great Britain Considered. Third edition. London: printed by Sam. Buckley.Google Scholar
Hales, John. [Ms 1550; 1581]. 1893. A Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England. Edited by Lamond, Elizabeth. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harris, Joseph. 1757. An Essay Upon Money and Coins. Part 1. London: Sold by G. Hawkins.Google Scholar
Hassinger, Herbert. 1951. “Johann Joachim Becher, 1635–1682.” Veröffentlichungen der Kommission für neuere Geschichte Österreichs, 38.Google Scholar
Heckscher, Eli F. 1955. Mercantilism. Edited by Söderlund, Ernst F.. Revised second edition, volume 2. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Holt, P. M., Lambton, Ann K. S., and Lewis, Bernard, eds. 1970. The Cambridge History of Islam. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, David. [1752] 1889. Essays Moral, Political and Literary. Edited by Green, T. H. and Grose, T. H.. Volume 2. London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Johnson, Harry G., ed. 1974. The New Mercantilism: Some Problems in International Trade, Money, and Investment. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Kauder, Emil. 1924. “Johann Joachim Becher als Wirtschafts und Sozialpolitiker.” Schmoller’s Jahrbuch 48: 811844.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
King, Gregory. 1936. Natural and Political Observations and Conclusions upon the State and Condition of England. In Hollander, Jacob, ed., Two Tracts by Gregory King. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Laffemas, Barthélemy de. 1600. L’Incrédulité ou l’ignorance de ceux qui ne veulent cognoistre le bien et repos de l’Estat et veoir renaistre la vie heureuse des François. Troisième traité: les moyens de chasser la gueuserye, contraindre les fainéants et employer les pauvres. Paris: Chez Iamet et Pierre Mettayer.Google Scholar
Magnusson, Lars. 1994. Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Misselden, Edward. 1622. Free Trade or the Meanes to Make Trade Florish. London.Google Scholar
Misselden, Edward. 1623. The Circle of Commerce or the Ballance of Trade. London.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The Enlightened Economy. An Economic History of Britain, 1700–1850. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Montchréstien, Antoyne de. [1615] 1889. Traité de l’oéconomie politique. Second edition, edited by Funck-Brentano, Th.. Paris: Plon.Google Scholar
Mun, Thomas. [Ca. 1630, 1664] 1903. England’s Treasure by Forraign Trade. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Mun, Thomas. [1621] 1930. A Discourse of Trade, from England Unto the East-Indies. New York: Facsimile Text Society.Google Scholar
Petyt, William. [1680, 1856] 1954. Britannia Languens, or a Discourse of Trade. In J. R. McCulloch, A Select Collection of Early English Tracts on Commerce. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rich, E. E., Wilson, C. H., Coleman, D. C., Mathias, P., and Postan, M. M., eds. 1977. Cambridge Economic History of Europe. Volume 5. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [Ca. 1763] 1896. Lectures on Justice, Police, Revenue, and Arms. Edited by Cannan, Edwin. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Spengler, Joseph J. 1942. French Predecessors of Malthus. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Supple, Barry E. 1954. “Thomas Mun and the Commercial Crisis, 1623.” Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research 27, 75 (May): 9194.Google Scholar
Tawney, R. H., and Power, Eileen, eds. 1924. Tudor Economic Documents. London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1950. “Full Employment at Whatever Cost.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 64: 385407.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1968. “Economic Thought.” In International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences. Sec. 2, volume 4. New York: Macmillan and Free Press, pp. 435443.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1991. “Mercantilist Thought.” In Essays on the Intellectual History of Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press, p. 264.Google Scholar
von Schröder, W. 1686. Fürstliche Schatz- und Rentkammer. Leipzig: Jacobus Gerdesius.Google Scholar
Yarranton, Andrew. 1677. England’s Improvement by Sea and Land. London: Printed by R. Everingham.Google Scholar