Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-wp2c8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-20T17:40:28.589Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Dismissal, Expulsion, and Emigration of German-Speaking Economists after 1933

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Harald Hagemann
Affiliation:
University of Hohenheim, D-70593 Stuttgart, Germany. E-mail: hagemann@uni-hohenheim.de

Extract

The dismissal of academicians from German universities under the Restoration of Civil Service Act (Gesetz zur Wiederherstellung des Berufsbeamtentums), promulgated by the National Socialists on April 7, 1933, and the expulsion of academicians from Germany, Austria, and other European countries interrupted or destroyed promising developments in economics, as well as in physics or other areas. According to this new “law,” which was passed by the Nazis in a short cut immediately after coming to power, “disagreeable” persons could be dislocated from the public service predominantly for racist (section 3) or political (section 4) reasons.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Blaug, M. and Sturgis, P. (Eds) (1983) Who's Who in Economics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Blaug, M. (1985) Great Economists since Keynes (Brighton: Wheatsheaf).Google Scholar
Burchardt, F. et al. (1944) The Economics of Full Employment (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
Craver, E. (1986) The Emigration of the Austrian Economists, History of Political Economy, 18(1), pp. 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Craver, E. and Leijonhufvud, A. (1987) Economics in America: The Continental Influence, History of Political Economy, 19(2), pp. 173–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esslinger, H. U. (1999) Entwicklungsökonomisches Denken in Groβbritannien: Zum Beitrag der deutschsprachigen wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Emigration nach 1933 (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Pommerehne, W. W. (1988) The American Domination among Eminent Economists, Scientometrics, 14(1), pp. 97110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagemann, H. (Ed.) (1997) Zur deutschsprachigen wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Emigration nach 1933 (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Hagemann, H. and Krohn, C. -D. (Eds) (1999) Biographisches Handbuch der deutschsprachigen wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Emigration nach 1933, 2 vols (Munich: K.G. Saur).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. (1933) Gleichgewicht und Konjunktur, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie (4), pp. 441–55; English translation, Equilibrium and the Trade Cycle, Economic Inquiry, 18(4), 1980, pp. 523–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janssen, H. (1998) Nationalökonomie und Nationalsozialismus: Die deutsche Volkswirtschaftslehre in den dreiβiger Jahren (Marburg: Metropolis).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1978) The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, XXII: Activities 1939–45: Internal War Finance (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Krohn, C.-D. (1993) Intellectuals in Exile: Refugee Scholars and the New School for Social Research, (Amherst, MA: University of Massachusetts Press).Google Scholar
Leonard, R. J. (1995) From Parlor Games to Social Science: von Neumann, Morgenstern, and the Creation of Game Theory 1928–1944, Journal of Economic Literature, 33(2), pp. 730–61.Google Scholar
Lindahl, E. (1919) Die Gerechtigkeit der Besteuerung (Lund: Gleerup and H. Ohlsson).Google Scholar
Marschak, J. (19241925) Der korporative und der hierarchische Gedanke im Fascismus, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 52(4), pp. 695728; 53(1), pp. 81–140.Google Scholar
Martin, K. (1991) Modern Development Theory, in: Strategies of Economic Development: Readings in the Political Economy of Industrialization (London: Macmillan), pp. 2773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meier, G. M., Seers, D. (Eds) (1984) Pioneers in Development (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. (1996) Public Finance and Finanzwissenschaft Traditions Compared, Finanzarchiv, 53 (2), pp. 145–93.Google Scholar
Musgrave, R. A. (1997) Crossing Traditions, in: Hagemann, H. (Ed.) Zur deutschsprachigen wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Emigration nach 1933 (Marburg: Metropolis), pp. 6379.Google Scholar
Neumark, F. (1980) Zuflucht am Bosporus: Deutsche Gelehrte, Politiker und Künstler in der Emigration 1933–1953 (Frankfurt am Main: Verlag Josef Knecht).Google Scholar
Röder, W. and Strauss, H. A. (Eds) (19801983), Biographisches Handbuch der deutschsprachigen Emigration nach 1933, 3 vols (Munich: K.G. Saur).Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1988) The Passing of the Guard in Economics, Eastern Economic Journal, 14(4), pp. 319–29.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1991) Leontief's “The Economy as a Circular Flow”: An Introduction, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 2(1), pp. 177–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F. M. (2000) The Emigration of German-speaking Economists after 1933, Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), pp. 614–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. (1904) Die “Objektivität” sozialwissenschaftlicher und sozialpolitischer Erkenntnis, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 19(1), pp. 2287.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1896) Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen (Jena: Gustav Fischer).Google Scholar