Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-tdptf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-09T22:46:31.787Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Technological and Institutional Context of Cold War Growth Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

Between 1928 and 1968, a common information environment in the Soviet Union, the United Kingdom, and the United States with respect to the role of industrial capital in the economy produced theories of economic growth in all three countries. Emerging from different stages of development and different institutional circumstances in each country, the content of the theory of growth was different in each country. The different stages of development were defined by industrial structure and levels of capital accumulation, not by technological sophistication. In the 1920s and 1930s, all three countries experienced the obsolescence of the steam locomotive and the telegraph, and the emergence of new economic activities related to the internal combustion engine, electricity, radio and the telephone. With respect to technology, as such, there was a fairly common information environment. Differences lay in institutions, rates of investment, and levels of accumulation.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Chakravarty, S. 1969. Capital and Development Planning, M.I.T. Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1929. Russian Economic Development Since the Revolution, 2d ed.; 3d ed., 1948. Routledge and Sons, London.Google Scholar
Domar, E. D. 1948. Capitalism, Socialism and Serfdom, Cambridge University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Domar, E. D. 1957. Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, Oxford, New York.Google Scholar
Erlich, A. 1960. The Soviet Industrial Debate: 1924–1928, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fellner, W. 1951. “The Capital-Output Ratio in Dynamic Economics,” in Money, Trade, and Economic Growth; in Honour of John Henry Williams, Macmillan, New York, 105–34.Google Scholar
Frisch, R. 1933. “Propagation Problems and Impulse Problems in Dynamic Economics,” in Ragnar, Frisch, ed., Economic Essays in Honour of Gustav Cassel, George Allen, London, 171205.Google Scholar
Gerschenkron, A. 1965. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Frederick A. Praeger.Google Scholar
Hahn, F. H. and Mathews, R. C. O.. 1965. “The Theory of Economic Growth; a Survey”, in American Economic Association and the Royal Economic Society, Surveys of Economic Theory, 2, Growth and Development, Macmillan, New York, 1124.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. F. 1948. Towards a Dynamic Economics, Macmillan, London. New York.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1930. “F. P. Ramsey,” Economic Journal, 40, 153–54.Google Scholar
Kalecky, M. 1935. “A Macrodynamic Theory of Business Cycles,” Econometrica, 3, 327–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalecky, M. 1939. Essays in the Theory of Economic Fluctuations, Allen, London.Google Scholar
Kalecky, M. 1952. Theory of Economic Dynamics, George, Allen and Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. 1965. Economic Growth and Structure, W. W. Norton, New York.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread, Yale University Press, New Haven.Google Scholar
Lundberg, E. 1937. Studies in the Theory of Economic Expansion, Kelley and Millman, New York; reprint, Augustus M. Kelley, New York, 1954.Google Scholar
Meade, J. E. 1961. A Neoclassical Theory of Economic Growth, Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Nove, A. 1969. An Economic History of the U.S.S.R., Penguin Press, London.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. 1931. “A Mathematical Theory of Saving,” in Mellor, D. H., ed., Foundations: Essays in Philosophy, Logic, Mathematics, and Economics, Routledge, Kegan and Paul, London, 261–81.Google Scholar
Slutsky, E. 1927. The Summation of Random Causes as the Source of Cyclical Processes, Conjuncture Institute of Moscow, Moscow.Google Scholar
Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 6594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spengler, J. J. 1960. “Marginalism and Neoclassicism,” in Spengler, J. J. and Allen, R. D., eds., Essays in Economic Thought, Rand McNally, Chicago, 534–52.Google Scholar
Weintraub, S. 1966. A Keynesian Theory of Employment, Growth and Income Distribution, Chilton, Philadelphia.Google Scholar
Yule, G. 1927. “On a Method of Investigating Periodicity in Distributed Series,” Transactions of the Royal Society, 226.Google Scholar