Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xfwgj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-04T06:19:37.608Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Market Time Supply of Non-Household-Head Hired Farm Worker

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 May 2017

Ronald L. Shane*
Affiliation:
Division of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Nevada, Reno
Get access

Abstract

Traditional models in the agricultural labor literature have examined agricultural labor supply in terms of a labor-leisure trade-off by a single individual. This work examines the question of total annual market days in farm and nonfarm work of secondary family workers engaged in hired farm work. The underlying model is one of home production-consumption. A trade-off of market days between wife and older children in a family is hypothesized. Empirical results are mixed, generally supporting a trade-off in the supply of market days in a family between nonstudents and wives, but not between students and wives.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

This article is a joint contribution of the U.S. Department of Labor, Grant Number MPRM 21-37-7325 and the Nevada Agricultural Experiment Station, Journal Series Number 438.

References

Becker, G.S.A Theory of the Allocation of Time.” Economic Journal 75 (1965): 493517.Google Scholar
Boskin, M.J.The Economics of Labor Supply.” Income MaintenanceGoogle Scholar
Cohen, M.S., Rea, S.A. Jr., and Lerman, R.I.A Micro Model of Labor Supply.” Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, Staff Paper 4, 1970 pp. 8284, 218–219.Google Scholar
DaVanzo, J., DeTray, D.N., and Greenberg, D.H. Estimating Labor Supply Responses: A Sensitivity Analysis. Rand Corporation. Santa Monica, California, 1973.Google Scholar
Gisser, M.Schooling and the Farm Problem.” Econometrica 33 (1965): 582592.Google Scholar
Glover, T. F.Seasonal Employment of Hired Labor in U.S. Agriculture.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, 1971.Google Scholar
Gronau, R.The Intrafamily Allocation of Time: The Value of the Housewives' Time.” The American Economic Review 63(1973): 634651.Google Scholar
Hall, R. E.Wages, Income, and Hours of Work in the U.S. Labor Force.” Income Maintenance and Labor Supply: Econometric Studies. Chicago: Rand McNally College Publishing Company, 1973.Google Scholar
Huffman, W. E.A Cross-sectional Analysis of Nonfarm Work of Farm Operators.” Unpublished paper, University of Oklahoma, June 1973a.Google Scholar
Huffman, W.E.A Cross-sectional Analysis of Off-farm Work of Wives of Farm Operators.” Unpublished paper, University of Oklahoma, September 1973b.Google Scholar
Leibowitz, A.S.Women's Allocation of Time to Market and Nonmarket Activities: Differences by Education.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. Department of Economics. New York: Columbia University, 1972.Google Scholar
Leigh, D.E.Labor Force Participation of Male Youths Living in Low-income Urban Areas.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review (1974): 242248.Google Scholar
Mincer, J.Labor Force Participation of Married Woman: A Study of Labor Supply.” Aspects of Labor Economics. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1962, p. 66.Google Scholar
Ofek, H.Allocation of Goods and Time in a Family Context.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. New York: Columbia University. 1971.Google Scholar
Rea, S.A. Jr.Unemployment and the Supply of Labor.” The Journal of Human Resources 9(1974):279289.Google Scholar
Schuh, G.E.An Econometric Investigation of the Market for Hired Labor in Agriculture.” Journal of Farm Economics 44(1962):307321.Google Scholar
Sexton., R.N.Determinants of Multiple Job-Holding by Farm Operators.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. Department of Economics and Business. Raleigh: North Carolina State University, 1975.Google Scholar
Smith, J.P.The Life Cycle Allocation of Time in a Family Context.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. Chicago: University of Chicago. 1972.Google Scholar
Tyrchniewicz., E.W. and Schuh, G.E.Econometric Analysis of the Agricultural Labor Market.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 51(1969):770787.Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Three Budgets for an Urban Family of Four Persons, 1969–1970.” Supplement to Bulletin 1570-5, Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1972. p. 13.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. “The Hired Farm Working Force—Statistical Reports 1965–1976.” Washington, 1966–1978.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Wage and Labor Standards Administration. “Agriculture and the Child Labor Requirements Under the Fair Labor Standards Act as Amended in 1966.” Child Labor Bulletin No. 102, Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1970, pp. 18.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor. Workplace Standards Administration. “Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938, as Amended.” Child Labor Bulletin No. 101, Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1971, pp. 534.Google Scholar
Wallace, T.D. and Hoover, D.M.Income Effects of Innovation: The Case of Labor in Agriculture.” Journal of Farm Economics 48 (1966): 325336.Google Scholar