Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vpsfw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-22T17:50:40.292Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Place of Law in the Marxian Structure-Superstructure Archetype

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 July 2024

Abstract

Law occupies a critical place in a Marxist theory of society. Yet Marx and Engels did not provide a coherent and detailed discussion of law. Subsequent writers in the Marxist tradition have either developed simplistic versions of the unsustainable thesis that the capitalist class dominates the legal apparatus in a capitalist society, or they have virtually abandoned Marxism as a framework for analysis of the law. This paper examines leading texts of Marx and Engels and employs them to provide the outlines of a plausible Marxist theory of law that can embrace the rich complexity of legal activity in a modern capitalist society.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 1985 by The Law and Society Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

I want to thank Richard Lempert, the Law & Society Review's anonymous reviewers, my colleagues Bob Carp and Tom Dumm, Josh Cohen (M.I.T.) and, especially, Joel Rogers (Rutgers) for their invaluable criticisms and suggestions.

References

References

ADLER, Max (1978) “Ideology as Appearance,” in Bottomore, T. and Goode, P. (eds.), Austro-Marxism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
BIERNE, Piers and Richard, QUINNEY (eds.) (1982) Marxism and Law. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
BOTTOMORE, Tom (1978) “Introduction,” in Bottomore, T. and Goode, P. (eds.), Austro-Marxism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
BUKHARIN, Nikolai (1965) Historical Materialism. New York: Russell & Russell.Google Scholar
CAIN, Maureen and Alan, HUNT (eds.) (1979) Marx and Engels on Law. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
CARR, Cecil Thomas (1909) “Early Forms of Corporateness,” in Association of American Law Schools (eds.), Select Essays in Anglo-American Legal History, Vol. 3. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
COASE, R.H. (1937) “The Nature of the Firm,” 4 Economica (New Semes) 386.Google Scholar
COHEN, G.A. (1978) Karl Marx's Theory of History. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
COHEN, G.A. (1981) “Freedom, Justice and Capitalism,” 126 New Left Review 3.Google Scholar
COLLINS, Hugh (1982) Marxism and Law. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
DAVIS, John P. (1961) Corporations. New York: Capricorn Books.Google Scholar
DODD, E. Merrick (1936) “Statutory Developments in Business Corporation Law, 1886-1936,” 50 Harvard Law Review 27.Google Scholar
ENGELS, Frederick (1959) “Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy,” in Feuer, L.S. (ed.), Marx and Engels: Basic Writings on Politics and Philosophy. Garden City, NY: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
FRASER, Andrew (1976) “Legal Theory and Legal Practice,” 44 Arena 123.Google Scholar
FRASER, Andrew (1978) “The Legal Theory We Need Now,” 40 Socialist Review 147.Google Scholar
GODELIER, Maurice (1976) “The Object and Method of Economic Anthropology,” in Seddon, D. (ed.), Relations of Production. London: Frank Cass.Google Scholar
GORDON, Robert W. (1980) “Review: Freyer's Forums of Order” 54 Business History Review 223.Google Scholar
GRAMSCI, Antonio (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
HABERMAS, Jürgen (1973) Legitimation Crisis. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
HALL, Stuart (1977) “Rethinking the Base and Superstructure Metaphor,” in Bloomfield, J. (ed.), Class, Hegemony and Party. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
HOLDSWORTH, William (1946) Essays in Law and History. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
JESSOP, Bob (1982) The Capitalist State. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
KAMENKA, Eugene (1981) “Demythologizing the Law,” Times Literary Suwlement 475 (May 1).Google Scholar
KRAMER, Stella (1928) The English Craft Gilds. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
LARKIN, Paschal (1969) Property in the Eighteenth Century. New York: Howard Fertig.Google Scholar
LEMPERT, Richard O. (1983) “From the New Editor,” 17 Law & Society Review 3.Google Scholar
LEVI-STRAUSS, Claude (1967) Structural Anthropology. Garden City, NY: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
MacPHERSON, C.B. (1975) “Capitalism and the Changing Concept of Property,” in Kamenka, E. and Neale, R.S. (eds.), Feudalism, Capitalism and Beyond. London: Edward Arnold.Google Scholar
MANDEL, Ernest (1968) Marxist Economic Theory, Vol. 1. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
MARX, Karl (1911) Critique of Political Economy. Chicago: Charles H. Kerr.Google Scholar
MARX, Karl (1973) Grundrisse. Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
MARX, Karl (1976) “Wages,” in Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, Collected Works, Vol. 6. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
MARX, Karl (1977) Capital, Vol. I. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
MARX, Karl and Frederick, ENGELS (1976) “The German Ideology,” in Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, Collected Works, Vol. 5. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
McLENNAN, Gregor (1981) Marxism and the Methodologies of History. London: Verso Editions.Google Scholar
MOORE, Stanley (1980) Marx On the Choice Between Socialism and Communism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
O'HAGAN, Timothy (1981) “On the Withering Away of Superstructures,” in Mepham, J. and Ruben, D.-H. (eds.), Issues in Marxist Philosophy, Vol. IV. Brighton, England: Harvester Press.Google Scholar
PASHUKANIS, Evgeny B. (1978) Law and Marxism: A General Theory. London: Ink Links.Google Scholar
PLAMENATZ, John (1955) German Marxism and Russian Communism. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
POPPER, Karl R. (1959) The Logic of Scientific Discovery. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
RENNER, Karl (1949) The Institutions of Private Law and Their Social Functions. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
SCOTT, William Robert (1951) The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint Stock Companies to 1920, Vol. I. New York: Peter Smith.Google Scholar
SPARKS, Richard F. (1980) “A Critique of Marxist Criminology,” 2 Crime and Justice: An Annual Review of Research 159.Google Scholar
SUMNER, Colin (1979) Reading Ideologies. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
SWEEZY, Paul (1942) The Theory of Capitalist Development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
THOMPSON, E.P. (1975) Whigs and Hunters. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
TUSHNET, Mark (1978) “A Marxist Analysis of American Law,” 1 Marxist Perspectives 96 (Spring).Google Scholar
TUSHNET, Mark (1983) “Review: Collins' Marxism and Law,” 68 Cornell Law Review 281.Google Scholar
VEBLEN, Thorstein (1932) The Theory of Business Enterprise. New York: New American Library.Google Scholar
WEBER, Max (1968) Economy and Society, 3 Vols. New York: Bedminster Press.Google Scholar
WEBER, Max (1977) Critique of Stammler. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
WILLIAMSON, Oliver E. (1975) Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar

Cases Cited

Swift v. Tyson, 41 U.S. (16 PET) 1 (1842).Google Scholar