Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-wtssw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-19T23:48:25.188Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Pharmacists Challenge Third Party Prescription Programs: A Legal Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 April 2021

Extract

Rare is the pharmacist today who does not participate as a service provider in one or several third party prescription insurance programs. Latest figures indicate that 372.7 million prescriptions or 25.4 percent of all prescriptions dispensed in this country were paid for at least in part by some form of prescription drug insurance.’ The economic impact which these third party programs are having on the retail pharmacist has caused their prominence as one of the most serious and important issues in pharmacy today.

Most third party prescription programs (TPPPs) are similar in structure and include a program administrator or insurance company, a sponsor (often an employer or labor union), subscribers or beneficiaries. and the participating pharmacies. Typically, the insurer or program administrator (hereinafter. the administrator) offers a contract or a “pharmacy agreement” to each pharmacy in a particular area. Each pharmacy must then decide whether or not to accept the agreement and become a participating pharmacy.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Society of Law, Medicine and Ethics 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Fink, J.L. Siecker, B., Manager's Guide to Third Party Programs (Pharmacy Management Institute, Washington, D.C.) (1982) at xi.Google Scholar
One of the major problems with TPPPs is that many program administrators are not insurance companies. Thus, these program administrators are not regulated by the state and escape having to post performance bonds, establish escrow accounts, etc.Google Scholar
15 U.S.C. §1 (1976).Google Scholar
See, e.g., Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.S. 773 (1975); Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968); United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940); Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1917).Google Scholar
Address byBernstein, Lewis, Chief of the Special Litigation Section of the Justice Department, National Association of Retail Druggists Annual Convention, in Las Vegas, Nevada, October 15, 1969. See also Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 102 S. Ct. 2466 (1982).Google Scholar
556 F.2d 1375 (5th Cir. 1977), aff'd, 440 U.S. 205 (1979) [hereinafter referred to as Royal Drug].Google Scholar
440 U.S. at 216.Google Scholar
Medical Arts Pharmacy v. Blue Cross and Blue Shield, 518 F. Supp. 1100 (D. Conn. 1981) [hereinafter referred to as Medical Arts].Google Scholar
Id. at 1106–08. The pharmacist/plaintiffs also contended that the insurer was party to a horizontal conspiracy to fix prices with other insurers, but introduced no evidence to prove this claim.Google Scholar
Id. Courts have found resale price maintenance schemes to be illegal per se. Accord Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968); United States v. Parke, Davis & Co., 362 U.S. 29 (1960); Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 (1951).Google Scholar
Although the district court considered the purchaser issue to be critical, 518 F. Supp. at 1109, the appellate court, 675 F.2d 502, 505–06 (2d Cir. 1982). held that the distinction between Blue Shield as purchaser and as indemnitor was irrelevant. Blue Shield is the ultimate payor, and thus the drug plan differs significantly from invalidated vertical arrangements.Google Scholar
Medical Arts, supra note 8, at 1106–07. See Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979); National Soc'y of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978). See also United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.S. 596 (1972);Allison, , Ambiguous Price Fixing and the Sherman Act: Simplistic Labels or Unavoidable Analysis? Houston Law Review 16:761 (1979).Google Scholar
Medical Arts, supra note 8, at 1109. Several authorities believe that novel or unique agreements, especially in the health care field or involving the professions require a rule of reason analysis. See Kallstrom, Health Care Costs by Third Party Payors: Fee Schedules and the Sherman Act, Duke Law Journal 1978:645;Leibenluft, Pollard, , Antitrust Scrutiny of the Health Professions: Developing a Framework for Assessing Private Restraints, Vanderbilt Law Review 34:927 (1981); Prepaid Prescription Plans Under Antitrust Scrutiny: A Stern Challenge to Health Care Cost Containment, Northwestern University Law Review 75:506 (1980). But see Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, supra note 5.Google Scholar
675 F.2d 502 (2d Cir. 1982).Google Scholar
Sausalito Pharmacy, Inc. v. Blue Shield of California, [1981-1] Trade Cas. (CCH) para. 63.885 (N.D. Cal. March 16, 1981), aff'd, 677 F.2d 47 (9th Cir. 1982).Google Scholar
National Soc'y of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 696 (1978).Google Scholar
As of Autumn 1982, five states have passed legislation regulating third party prescription plans. These include: Georgia, Alabama, Tennessee, Illinois, and Connecticut. Similar bills have been introduced in at least 12 other states, including: Arizona, Colorado, Idaho, Kentucky, Maryland, New Jersey, New York, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Texas, Virginia, and West Virginia, Pharmacists in several other states are also considering the introduction of bills in future state legislative sessions.Google Scholar
See, e.g., Ga. Code Ann. §1208 (1979).Google Scholar
Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Alabama v. Alabama Pharmaceutical Association, No. CV-81-PT10125 (N.D. Ala. July 1981) (case was dismissed).Google Scholar
Pub. L. No. 93-406, Title 1, §2, 88 Stat. 832 (codified at 29 U.S.C. §§1001-1381 (1976)).Google Scholar
15 U.S.C. §1 (1976).Google Scholar
U.S. Conts. art. 1, §10.Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §§1001-1381 (1976).Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §1144(a) (1976) (emphasis added).Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §1144(b)(2)(A) (1976).Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §1144(b)(2)(B) (1976).Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §1002(1) (1976).Google Scholar
Royal Drug, 404 U.S. at 216–17.Google Scholar
29 U.S.C. §1144 (1976).Google Scholar
See Royal Drug, 404 U.S. at 215.Google Scholar
But see Wadsworth v. Whaland, 562 F.2d 70 (1st Cir. 1977) (New Hampshire law requiring group insurance policies to include emotional disorders was upheld under the “savings clause” even though the law indirectly affected employee benefit plans). See also Insurers' Action Council, Inc. v. Heaton, 423 F. Supp. 921 (D. Minn. 1976). For analysis of Wadsworth v. Whaland, see ERISA Preemption and Indirect Regulation of Employee Benefit Welfare Plans through State Insurance Laws, Columbia Law Review 78:1536 (1978); ERISA Preemption of State Law: The Meaning of “Relate To” in Section 514, Washington University Law Quarterly 58:143 (1980). For cases contrary to Wadsworth, see Hewlett-Packard Co. v. Barnes, 571 F.2d 502 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 439 U.S. 831 (1978); Standard Oil Co. v. Agsalud, 442 F. Supp. 695 (N.D. Cal. 1977).Google Scholar
451 U.S. 504 (1981) [hereinafter referred to as Alessi]. See also Hewlett-Packard Co. v. Barnes, supra note 31; Standard Oil Co. v. Agsalud, supra note 31.Google Scholar
In Royal Drug, supra note 6, the court of appeals stated: “[P]olicyholders are basically unconcerned with the contract between the insurer and the Participating Pharmacy… .” 556 F.2d at 1381.Google Scholar
585 P.2d 12 (Or. App. 1978).Google Scholar
Alessi, supra note 32, at 525 n.21. See also American Telephone and Telegraph Co. v. Merry, 592 F.2d 118 (2d Cir. 1979); Stone v. Stone, 450 F. Supp. 919 (N.D. Cal. 1978).Google Scholar
The argument that third party legislation has competitive effects could be greatly strengthened by the showing of specific claims that third party agreements have anticompetitive effects.Google Scholar
National Soc'y of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 790 (1976).Google Scholar
“The powers not delegated to the United States … or prohibited to the states are reserved to the states… .” U.S. Const. amend. X. See Blumstein, Calvani, , State Action as a Shield and a Sword in a Medical Services Antitrust Context: Parker v. Brown in Constitutional Perspective, Duke Law Journal 1978:389 (extensive examination of the state action exemption applying the perspectives of the tenth and eleventh amendments).Google Scholar
445 U.S. 97 (1980) [hereinafter referred to as Midcal].Google Scholar
317 U.S. 341 (1943).Google Scholar
See New Motor Vehicle Bd. v. Orrin W. Fox Co., 439 U.S. 96 (1978); Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U.S. 389 (1978); Bates v. State Bar of Arizona, 433 U.S. 350 (1977); Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. 579 (1976); Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.S. 773 (1975).Google Scholar
Midcal, supra note 39, at 97.Google Scholar
Id. In Midcal, the Supreme Court invalidated a California statute requiring wine producers and wholesalers to set retail prices. State immunity was denied under the second policy because no “active supervision by the state” existed. California simply authorized price-setting by private parties. The state did not establish the prices nor review the reasonableness of the price schedules.Google Scholar
U.S. Const. art. 1, §10.Google Scholar
Home Bldg. & Loan Ass'n v. Blaisdell, 290 U.S. 398 (1934).Google Scholar
Allied Structural Steel Co. v. Spannus, 438 U.S. 234 (1978) [hereinafter referred to as Spannus]. See also United States Trust Co. v. New Jersey, 431 U.S. 1 (1977).Google Scholar
Spannus, supra note 46.Google Scholar
Linkletter v. Walker, 381 U.S. 618, 627 (1965); El Paso v. Simmons, 379 U.S. 497 (1965).Google Scholar
See Spannus, supra note 46, at 250.Google Scholar