Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-ckgrl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-01T21:18:33.554Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Aggregate effects of firing costs with endogenous firm productivity growth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 March 2022

Borja Petit*
Affiliation:
CUNEF Universidad, C/ Pirineos, 55, 28040 Madrid, Spain
*
Email: bpetit@cunef.edu, Phone: (+34) 91 444 51 61.

Abstract

This article quantifies the aggregate effects of firing costs in a model of firm dynamics where firm-level productivity is determined by innovation. In the model, the productivity distribution is endogenous, and thus, potentially affected by policy changes, allowing the model to capture both the static (allocative efficiency) and dynamic effects (changes in the distribution of firms’ productivity) of firing costs. The model is calibrated to match key features of firms’ hiring and firing behavior using firm-level data from Spanish nonfinancial firms. I show that firing costs equivalent to 2.5 monthly wages produce a 4% loss in aggregate productivity relative to the frictionless economy. The aggregate productivity losses rise to more than 10% when firing costs are equivalent to 1 year’s wage. I show that a model with a standard AR(1) productivity process can only generate between 45 and 50% of these losses. Overall, the results suggest that ignoring the effects of frictions on the dynamics of firms’ productivity can substantially underestimate their effects.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2), 323351.Google Scholar
Almunia, M., Lóopez-Rodríguez, D. and Moral-Benito, E. (2018) Evaluating the macro-representativeness of a firm-level database: An application for the Spanish economy, Documentos Ocasionales 1802, Banco de España. Google Scholar
Atkeson, A. and Burstein, A. (2010) Innovation, firm dynamics and international trade. Journal of Political Economy 118(3), 433484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartelsman, E., Haltiwanger, J. and Scarpetta, S. (2013) Cross-country differences in productivity: The role of allocation and selection. American Economic Review 103(1), 305334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentolila, S. and Bertola, G. (1990) Firing costs and labour demand: How bad is eurosclerosis. The Review of Economic Studies 57(3), 381402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costain, J. (2017) Costly Decisions and Sequential Bargaining, Documentos de trabajo 1729, Banco de España. Google Scholar
Costain, J., Nakov, A. and Petit, B. (2022) Flattening of the Phillips curve with state-dependent prices and wages. The Economic Journal 132(642), 546–581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Da-Rocha, J.-M., Diego, R. and Marina, M. T. (2019) Firing costs, misallocation, and aggregate productivity. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 98(3), 6081.Google Scholar
Gabler, A. and Poschke, M. (2013) Experimentation by firms, distortions, and aggregate productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(1), 2638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia-Macia, D., Hsieh, C.-T. and Klenow, P. J. (2019) How destructive is innovation? Econometrica 87(5), 15071541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Santana, M., Moral-Benito, E., Pijoan-Mas, J. and Ramos, R. (2016) Growing like Spain: 1995-2007. International Economic Review 61(1), 383416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grece, C. (2016) The online advertising market in the EU – Update 2015 and Focus on programmatic advertising, European Audiovisual Observatory.Google Scholar
Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, E. (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. The Review of Economic Studies 58(1), 4361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guner, N., Ventura, G. and Xu, Y. (2008) Macroeconomic implications of size-dependent policies. Review of Economic Dynamics 11(4), 721744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S. and Miranda, J. (2013) Who creates jobs? Small versus large versus young. The Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 347361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haltiwanger, J., Scarpetta, S. and Schweiger, H. (2014) Cross country differences in job reallocation: The role of industry, firm size and regulations. Labour Economics 26(2), 1125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopenhayn, H. (2014) Firms, misallocation, and aggregate productivity: A review. Annual Review of Economics 6(1), 735770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopenhayn, H. and Rogerson, R. (1993) Job turnover and policy evaluation: A general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Political Economy 101(5), 915938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsieh, C.-T. and Klenow, P. J. (2009) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in Chinaand India. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4), 14031448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsieh, C.-T. and Klenow, P. J. (2014) The life cycle of plants in India and Mexico. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3), 10351084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klette, T. J. and Kortum, S. (2004) Innovating firms and aggregate innovation. Journal of Political Economy 112(5), 9861018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López-García, P., Puente, S. and Gómez, A. L. (2007). Firm productivity dyanmics in Spain, Banco de España., Documentos de trabajo 0739.Google Scholar
López-Martín, B. (2017) From firm productivity dynamics to aggregate efficiency. The World Bank Economic Review 30(Supplement_1), S57S66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mukoyama, T. and Osotimehin, S. (2019) Barriers to reallocation and economic growth: The effects of firing costs. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11(4), 235270.Google Scholar
Poschke, M. (2009) Employment protection, firm selection, and growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 56(8), 10741085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ranasinghe, A. (2014) Impact of policy distortions on firm-level innovation, productivity dynamics and TFP. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 46(1), 114129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Restuccia, D. and Rogerson, R. (2008) Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with heterogeneous establishments. Review of Economics Dynamics 11(4), 707730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Restuccia, D. and Rogerson, R. (2013) Misallocation and productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(1), 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutton, J. (1997) Gibrat’s legacy. Journal of Economic Literature 35, 4059.Google Scholar
Sutton, J. (2002) The variance of firm growth rates: The ’scaling’ puzzle. Physica 312(4), 577590.Google Scholar
Turen, J. (2019) Rational Inattention-driven Dispersion with Volatility Shocks. Documentos de trabajo 530, Instituto de Economía, Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Petit supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Petit supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 211.8 KB