Hostname: page-component-68945f75b7-4zrgc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-06T06:20:33.192Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Has the Expansion of Higher Education Led to Greater Economic Growth?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Craig Holmes*
Affiliation:
Oxford University

Abstract

There is an enduring belief by UK policymakers that a large higher education sector is an important driver of long-run economic growth, which has been part of the narrative since the Robbins Report. Back then, there was plenty of conjecture and assumption, but strikingly little concrete evidence to support such a belief. This paper asks whether the evidence base has strengthened in the 50 years since it was published. It looks at a number of different growth equation specifications and, using international education data, attempts to draw out the contribution of both the number of, and the growth in, graduates since the 1960s. There are three main findings. Firstly, many growth relationships, including those estimated elsewhere in the literature, are quite sensitive to the countries included – which often depends on the variables used – and time period of analysis. I argue that, given these issues, growth equations should always be treated with caution. Secondly, and remembering this caveat, neither the increase nor the initial level of higher education is found to have a statistically significant relationship with growth rates both in the OECD and worldwide. This result is robust to numerous different specifications. Thirdly, there is some evidence, consistent with the existing literature, that levels of technical skills at the end of compulsory education matter. The employment of higher level technical skills (proxied by the number of employed researchers in an economy) is also a strong predictor of growth. This gives a possible mechanism linking the output of (some) of the higher education sector with economic growth. However, it does not imply that mass higher education necessarily leads to higher growth. This depends on the skills produced by an expanding tertiary sector and their utilisation (or underutilisation) in the jobs available to increasing numbers of graduates.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2013 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I would like to thank Ken Mayhew for his advice and suggestions. I'm also thankful for the helpful comments of three anonymous referees that have greatly improved my research.

References

Aghion, P., Boustan, L., Hoxby, C., Vandenbussche, J. (2009), ‘The causal impact of education on economic growth: evidence from the United States’, accessed online 5 January 2013: http://scholar.harvard.edu/files/causal_impact_of_education_0.pdf.Google Scholar
Barro, R.Lee, J. (2010), ‘A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010’, NBER Working Paper No. 15902.Google Scholar
BIS (2011), ‘Supporting analysis for the Higher Education White Paper’, BIS Economics Paper No. 14.Google Scholar
Browne Review (2010), Securing a Sustainable Future for Higher Education, www.independent.gov.uk/browne-report.Google Scholar
DES (2004), The Future of Higher Education.Google Scholar
Gemmell, N. (1996), ‘Evaluating the impacts of human capital stocks and accumulation on economic growth: some new evidence’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 58 (1), pp. 928.Google ScholarPubMed
Gemmell, N. (1997), ‘Externalities to higher education: a review of the new growth literature’, Report to the National Committee of Inquiry into Higher Education.Google Scholar
Hanuschek, E.Kimko, D. (2000), ‘Schooling, labour force quality, and the growth of nations’, American Economic Review, 90, pp. 1184–208Google Scholar
Hanushek, E.Woessmann, L. (2007), ‘The role of education quality for economic growth’, World Bank Working Paper No. 4122.Google Scholar
Holmes, C.Mayhew, K. (2013), ‘Are universities the best way to create high skills? The consequences of mass higher education in the UK’, conference paper presented at the 31 st International Labour Process Conference, Rutgers University, 20 March.Google Scholar
Jones, C. (1995), ‘R&D based models of economic growth’, Journal of Political Economy, 103 (4), pp. 759–84.Google Scholar
Jones, C. (1999), ‘Growth: with or without scale effects?’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 89, pp. 139–44.Google Scholar
Keep, E.Mayhew, K. (2004), ‘The economic and distributional implications of current policies on higher education’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20 (2), pp. 298313.Google Scholar
Lindahl, M.Krueger, A.B. (2001), ‘Education and growth: why and for whom?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 39 (4) pp. 1101–36.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. (1988), ‘On the mechanics of economic development’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, pp. 342Google Scholar
Mankiw, G., Romer, D.Weil, D. (1992), ‘A contribution to the empirics on economic growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, pp. 407–37.Google Scholar
Mason, G. (2002), ‘High skills utilisation under mass higher education: graduate employment in service industries in Britain’, Journal of Education and Work, 15 (4), pp. 427–56Google Scholar
Pscharoupoulos, G. (2009), ‘Returns to investment in higher education: European Survey – a contribution to the Higher Education Funding Reform Project CHEPS-led consortium for the European Commission’, accessed online 4 April 2013: http://ec.europa.eu/education/higher-education/doc/funding/vol3_en.pdf.Google Scholar
Robbins Report (1963), Education in England: Higher Education, www.educationengland.org.uk/documents/robbins/index.html.Google Scholar
Romer, P. (1986), ‘Increasing returns and long run economic growth’, Journal of Political Economy, 94 (5), pp. 1002–37.Google Scholar
Romer, P. (1990), ‘Endogenous technological change’, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5), pp. S71102.Google Scholar
Romer, P. (1994), ‘The origins of endogenous growth’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (1), pp. 322.Google Scholar
Sianesi, B.Van Reenan, J. (2003), ‘The returns to education: macroeconomics’, Journal of Economic Surveys, 17 (2), pp. 157200.Google Scholar
Solow, R. (1956), ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 (1), pp. 6594.Google Scholar
Spence, M. (1973), ‘Job market signaling’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (3): pp. 355–74.Google Scholar
Thurow, L, (1976), Generating Inequality, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Vandenbussche, J., Aghion, A.Meghir, C. (2006), ‘Growth, distance from the frontier and composition of human capital’, Journal of Economic Growth, 11, pp. 97107.Google Scholar
Wolf, A. (2002), Does Education Matter?, Penguin.Google Scholar
Wolff, E. (2001), ‘Productivity convergence and education: evidence from OECD countries’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10 (3): pp. 735–59.Google Scholar
Young, A. (1998), ‘Growth without scale effects’, Journal of Political Economy, 106 (1), pp. 4163.Google Scholar