Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-n9wrp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-21T02:56:12.188Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Comparing Legislators and Legislatures: The Dynamics of Legislative Gridlock Reconsidered

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 August 2007

Fang-Yi Chiou
Affiliation:
Institute of Political Science, Academia Sinica, 128 Academia Road, Taipei, Taiwan, e-mail: fchiou@gate.sinica.edu.tw
Lawrence S. Rothenberg*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY 14627
*
e-mail: lrot@mail.rochester.edu (corresponding author)

Abstract

Although political methodologists are well aware of measurement issues and the problems that can be created, such concerns are not always front and center when we are doing substantive research. Here, we show how choices in measuring legislative preferences have influenced our understanding of what determines legislative outputs. Specifically, we replicate and extend Binder's highly influential analysis (Binder, Sarah A. 1999. The dynamics of legislative gridlock, 1947–96. American Political Science Review 93:519–33; see also Binder, Sarah A. 2003. Stalemate: Causes and consequences of legislative gridlock. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution) of legislative gridlock, which emphasizes how partisan, electoral, and institutional characteristics generate major legislative initiatives. Binder purports to show that examining the proportion, rather than the absolute number, of key policy proposals passed leads to the inference that these features, rather than divided government, are crucial for explaining gridlock. However, we demonstrate that this finding is undermined by flaws in preference measurement. Binder's results are a function of using W-NOMINATE scores never designed for comparing Senate to House members or for analyzing multiple Congresses jointly. When preferences are more appropriately measured with common space scores (Poole, Keith T. 1998. Recovering a basic space from a set of issue scales. American Journal of Political Science 42:964–93), there is no evidence that the factors that she highlights matter.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author 2007. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Society for Political Methodology 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Authors' note: Thanks to Sarah Binder and Keith Poole for furnishing data used in our analysis and to Chris Achen and Kevin Clarke for advice. All errors remain our own. Online appendix is available on the Political Analysis Web site.

References

Achen, Christopher. 1985. Proxy variables and incorrect signs on regression coefficients. Political Methodology 11: 299316.Google Scholar
Bailey, Michael. 2005. Bridging institutions and time: Creating comparable preference estimates for presidents, senators, representatives and justices, 1950-2002. Unpublished manuscript, Georgetown University.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. 1999. The dynamics of legislative gridlock, 1947-96. American Political Science Review 93: 519–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. 2003. Stalemate: Causes and consequences of legislative gridlock. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Brady, David W., and Volden, Craig. 2006. Revolving gridlock: Politics and policy from Jimmy Carter to George W. Bush. 2nd ed. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Chiou, Fang-Yi, and Rothenberg, Lawrence S. 2003. When pivotal politics meets partisan politics. American Journal of Political Science 47: 503–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cole, Rosanne. 1969. Data errors and forecasting accuracy. In Economic forecasts and expectations, ed. Mincer, Jacob, 4073. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Coleman, John J. 1999. Unified government, divided government, and party responsiveness. American Political Science Review 93: 821–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeVaro, Jed L., and Lacker, Jeffrey M. 1995. Errors in variables and lending discrimination. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 81(3): 1932.Google Scholar
Edwards, George C. III, Barrett, Andrew, and Peake, Jeffrey. 1997. The legislative impact of divided government. American Journal of Political Science 41: 545–63.Google Scholar
Greene, William H. 2003. Econometric analysis. 5th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Hashimoto, Masanori, and Kochin, Levis. 1980. A bias in the statistical estimation of the effects of discrimination. Economic Inquiry 18: 478–86.Google Scholar
Herron, Michael C. 2004. Studying dynamics in legislator ideal points: Scale matters. Political Analysis 12: 182–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodges, S. D., and Moore, P. G. 1972. Data uncertainties and least squares regression. Applied Statistics 21: 185–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howell, William, Adler, Scott, Cameron, Charles, and Riemann, Charles. 2000. Divided government and the legislative productivity of Congress, 1945-1994. Legislative Studies Quarterly 25: 285312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katsouyanni, K., Schwartz, J., Spix, C., Touloumi, G., Zmirou, D., Zanobetti, A., Wojtyniak, B. et al. 1996. Short-term effects of air pollution on health: A European approach using epidemiological time series data. The APHEA protocol. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 50 (Suppl 1): S128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1996. Institutional and partisan sources of gridlock: A theory of divided and unified government. Journal of Theoretical Politics 8: 740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1998. Pivotal politics: A theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Maurice D. 1973. Errors in the variables bias in the presence of correctly measured variables. Econometrica 41: 985–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1991. Divided we govern. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T. 1998. Recovering a basic space from a set of issue scales. American Journal of Political Science 42: 964–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T. 2003. Changing minds! Not in Congress. Unpublished manuscript, University of Houston.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rao, Potluri. 1973. Some notes on the errors-in-variables model. American Statistician 27: 217–8.Google Scholar
Rothenberg, Lawrence S., and Sanders, Mitchell. 2004. Much ado about very little: Reply to Herron. Political Analysis 12: 191–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, J., Spix, C., Touloumi, G., Bachárová, L., Barumamdzadeh, T., le Tertre, A., and Piekarksi, T. et al. 1996. Methodological issues in studies of air pollution and daily counts of deaths or hospital admissions. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 50 (Suppl 1): S311.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Snyder, James M. 1992a. Artificial extremism in interest group ratings. Legislative Studies Quarterly 17: 319–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, James M. 1992b. Long-term investing in politicians; or, give early, give often. Journal of Law and Economics 35: 1543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Chiou and Rothenberg Supplementary Material

Appendices

Download Chiou and Rothenberg Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 151.7 KB