Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-8bljj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-30T00:13:11.752Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Élasticité de substitution et balance des opérations courantes dans un modèle à deux pays

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Delphine Béraud*
Affiliation:
MAD, Université de Paris Iet GREMI, Université du Maine
Get access

Résumé

Dans un monde à deux pays où la mobilité du capital est parfaite, on analyse l'interdépendance des pays lorsque les agents n'ont pas la même élasticité de substitution intertemporelle dans les deux pays. Cette hypothèse implique que plus l'élasticité de substitution intertemporelle est importante, plus le taux de croissance de la consommation est grand. Deux résultats apparaissent: le premier est que la dynamique de l'économie mondiale n'est pas indépendante de la répartition des richesses. Le second concerne les échanges commerciaux et financiers entre les pays. L'écart entre les taux de croissance de la consommation de chaque pays dû à des préférences différentes des agents est un déterminant essentiel des dynamiques de la balance courante et de la balance commerciale des pays.

Summary

Summary

We analyse the interdependence of countries, in a two-country model, when the capital is perfectly mobile and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution differs across the two countries. It follows that the higher the elasticity of substitution, the higher the growth rate of consumption. Moreover, firstly, it is shown that the world economy is dependent of the sharing of wealth between countries. Secondly, we study trade and financial exchanges. The current account and the trade balance of countries are determined by dynamics of consumption of each countries.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1998 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Je remercie A. d'Autume pour l'intérêt qu'il porte à ce travail ainsi que les participants du séminaire du MAD. Je suis seule responsable des éventuelles erreurs et omissions.

References

Bibliographie

Amable, B., Henry, J., Lordon, F. et Topol, R. [1992], Hysteresis: what it is and what it is not, Document de Travail 9216, Cepremap, Paris.Google Scholar
Amable, B., Henry, J., Lordon, F. et Topol, R. [1994], Strong hysteresis versus zero-root dynamics, Economics Letters, 44(1-2), pp. 4347.Google Scholar
D'Autume, A. [1996], Notes sur les modèles à deux pays, Miméo, M.A.D, Paris.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. et Sala-I-Martin, X. [1995], Economie Growth, New York, McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Béraud, D. [1996], La dynamique de la balance courante dans un modèle à deux pays, Cahiers Eco & Maths, 96–18, Université de Paris I, Paris.Google Scholar
Bianconi, M. [1995], Fiscal policy in a simple two-country dynamic model, Journal of Economie Dynamics and Control, 19(1-2), pp. 395419.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. [1979], Backward and forward solutions for economies with rational expectations, American Economic Review, 69(2), pp. 114118.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. [1985], Debt, deficits, and finite horizons, Journal of Political Economy, 93(2), pp. 223247.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. et Fischer, S. [1989], Lectures on Macroeconomics, Cambridge, MIT. Press.Google Scholar
Cross, R. [1993], On the foundation of hysteresis in economic system, Economics and Philosophy, 9(1), pp. 5374.Google Scholar
Devereux, M.B. et Shi, S. [1991], Capital accumulation and the current account in a two-country model, Journal of International Economics, 30(1-2), pp. 125.Google Scholar
Feldstein, M. et Horioka, C. [1980], Domestic saving and international capital flows, The Economic Journal, 90(2), pp. 314329.Google Scholar
Frankel, J.A. [1986], International capital mobility and crowding-out in the U.S. economy: imperfect integration of financial market or of goods markets, in Hafer, R.W. (éd.), How Open is the U.S. Economy, Lexington, Lexington Books, pp. 3376.Google Scholar
Geary, R.C. [1950], A note on a constant utility index of the cost of living, Review of economic Studies, 18(1), pp. 6566.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, F. et Wyplosz, C. [1984], The real exchange rate, the current account, and the speed of adjustment, in Bilson, C. et Marson, R. (éds), Exchange Rates: Theory and Policy, Chicago, Chicago University Press, pp. 335356.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, F. et Wyplosz, C. [1985], The zero root problem: A note on the dynamic determination of the stationary equilibrium in linear models, Review of Economic Studies, 52(2), pp. 353357.Google Scholar
Karayalcin, C. [1994], Adjustment costs in investment, times preferences, and the current account, Journal of International Economics, 37(1-2), pp. 8195.Google Scholar
Lipton, D. et Sachs, J. [1983], Accumulation and growth in a two-country model, a simulation approach, Journal of International Economics, 15(1-2), pp. 135159.Google Scholar
Stone, R. [1954], Linear expenditure systems and demand analysis: An application to the pattern of british demand, Economic Journal, 64, pp. 511527.Google Scholar
Uzawa, H. [1968], Time preference, the consumption function, and optimum asset holdings, in Wolfe, J.N. (éd.), Value, Capital and Growth, Chicago, Aldine, pp. 485504.Google Scholar
Van Der Ploeg, F. [1994], The handbook of International Macroeconomics, Oxford, Blackwell.Google Scholar