Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-11T10:20:42.208Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Douglass C. North’s The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860 Revisited

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

Stanley L. Engerman*
Affiliation:
The University of Rochester

Extract

Douglass North’s The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860, while not the most controversial of the works of “new economic historians” in the 1960s, was among the first and was probably the most widely used of any of these in undergraduate history courses. In addition to its widespread use—possibly the first introduction of many history students to an economic approach to their subject—it framed, if not originated, a number of hypotheses about the process of American economic growth and about various specific relationships which have been and remain the basis of empirical work. In examining its importance the question is not just whether on certain specific points North was right, but also whether the book generated important hypotheses for empirical testing. In these latter regards here clearly was an important book, and, while it may seem to be incomplete or to fail on some specific issues, we should add that even now it is often unclear what the “right” answers might be.

Type
Retrospective Review
Copyright
copyright © Social Science History Association 1977 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

In preparing this review, I have benefited from discussions with Mary Young.

References

Notes

1 Englewood Cliff, N.J., 1961. Reissued in paperback by W. W. Norton, Company in 1966.

2 Callender, G. S., “The Early Transportation and Banking Enterprises of the States in Relation to the Growth of Corporations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 17 (November 1902), 111-162CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also the introductions to various sections in Guy Stevens Callender, Selections from the Economic History of the United States, 1765-1860 (Boston, 1909). On Callender, see Engelbourg, Saul, “Guy Stevens Callender: A Founding Father of American Economic History,” Explorations in Economic History, 9 (Spring 1972), 255-267CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 See, in particular, North, Douglass C., “Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 62 (June 1955), 243-258CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and the subsequent discussion with Tiebout the following year.

4 North on page 68 notes: “Given the social structure, attitudes and motivation of American society, and the rich quantity and quality of resources which made even the self-sufficient farmer well off as compared with his European counterpart, the United States economy would not have stagnated.” But he argues both that: “Without cotton the development in the size of the market would have been a much more lengthy process,” and “cotton was the most important proximate cause of expansion.” These still suggest that attention to the preconditions remains a most fruitful area of research, particularly so given what we now know about economic growth in the eighteenth century (although there the “export base” model would still be considered quite appropriate). Harold Woodman raised the question of the reasons for, and possible shifts in, motivation in the United States, an important point (but not one incompatible with North’s) though, as written, North seems to suggest that the same motives were always there, but led to different observed patterns of response given different external stimuli. See Woodman’s, The State of Agricultural History,” in Bass, Herbert J., ed., The State of American History, (Chicago, 1970), 220-248Google Scholar.

5 David, Paul A., “The Growth of Real Product in the United States Before 1840: New Evidence, Controlled Conjectures,” Journal of Economic History, 27 (June 1967), 151-197CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Note also that both these estimates and the evidence analyzed by Fogel, Robert W. in Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History (Baltimore, 1964)Google Scholar, Chapter IV, present a quite different picture of the economic conditions in the 1820s than does North.

6 Goldin, Claudia D. and Lewis, Frank D., “The Role of Exports in American Economic Growth during the Napoleonic Wars, 1793 to 1807,” (Paper presented to the MSSB Conference on Exports and Growth 1975)Google Scholar.

7 North, Douglass C., “Early National Income Estimates of the U. S.,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 9 (April 1961), 387-396CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Easterlin, Richard A., “Review” [of North’s, D.C. The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860], Journal of Economic History, 22 (March 1962), 122-126Google Scholar. This review is an abridged version of the longer review presented at the 1961 Purdue Cliometrics conference.

9 Lebergott, Stanley, “Labor Force and Employment, 1800-1960,” in Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Output, Employment, and Productivity in the United States After 1800 in Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 30 (New York, 1966), 117-204Google Scholar.

10 Kravis, Irving B., “The Role of Exports in Nineteenth-Century United States Growth,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 20 (April 1972), 387-405CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Kravis, Irving B., “Trade as a Handmaiden of Growth: Similarities between the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries,” Economic Journal, 80 (December 1970), 850-872CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Williamson, Jeffrey G., American Growth and the Balance of Payments, 1820-1913 (Chapel Hill, 1964)Google Scholar.

13 Caves, Richard E., “ ‘Vent for Surplus’ Models of Trade and Growth,” in Baldwin, R. E., et al., Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments (Chicago, 1965), 95-115Google Scholar. For a detailed discussion of the “export base” model, specifically relating to the Chambers-Gordon discussion of the Canadian wheat boom of the 1890s, see also his “Export-Led Growth and the New Economic History,” in Bhagwati, Jagdish N., et al., eds., Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth (Amsterdam, 1971), 403-442Google Scholar.

14 Temin, Peter, The Jacksonian Economy (New York, 1969)Google Scholar.

15 Temin, Peter, “The Causes of Cotton-Price Fluctuations in the 1830’s,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 49 (November 1967), 463-470CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Wright, Gavin, “An Econometric Study of Cotton Production and Trade, 1830-1860,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 53 (May 1971), 111-120CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

17 See, however, Shetler, Douglas, “The Supply of Cotton 1818-1841,” Unpublished, UCLA, 1971Google Scholar.

18 Berry, Thomas Senior, Western Prices Before 1861: A Study of the Cincinnati Market (Cambridge, 1943)Google Scholar.

19 Kohlmeier, A. L., The Old Northwest as the Keystone of the Arch of the American Federal Union (Bloomington, 1938)Google Scholar.

20 Smith, Walter Buckingham and Cole, Arthur Harrison, Fluctuations in American Business, 1790-1860 (Cambridge, 1935)Google Scholar.

21 Schmidt, Louis Bernard, “Internal Commerce and the Development of a National Economy before 1860,” Journal of Political Economy, 47 (December 1939), 798-822CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Taylor, George Rogers, The Transportation Revolution, 1815-1860 (New York, 1951)Google Scholar.

23 Gallman, Robert E., “Self-Sufficiency in the Cotton Economy of the Antebellum South,” Agricultural History, 44 (January 1970), 5-23Google Scholar.

24 Hutchinson, William K. and Williamson, Samuel H., “The Self-Sufficiency of the Antebellum South: Estimates of the Food Supply,” Journal of Economic History, 31 (September 1971), 591-612CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Hilliard, Sam Bowers, Hog Meat and Hoecake: Food Supply in the Old South, 1840-1860 (Carbondale, 1972)Google Scholar.

26 Lindstrom, Diane, “Southern Dependence upon Interregional Grain Supplies: A Review of Trade Flows, 1840-1860,” Agricultural History, 44 (January 1970), 101-113Google Scholar.

27 Fishlow, Albert, “Antebellum Interregional Trade Reconsidered,” American Economic Review, 54 (May 1964), 352-364Google Scholar, as well as his American Railroads and the Transformation of the Ante-Bellum Economy (Cambridge, 1965), particularly Chapter VII.

28 See the interchange between Fishlow and Fogel in Ralph L. Andreano, ed., New Views on American Economic Development: A Selective Anthology of Recent Work (Cambridge, 1965), 187-224.

29 Clark, John G., The Grain Trade in the Old Northwest (Urbana, 1966)Google Scholar.

30 Lindstrom, Diane L., “Demand, Markets, and Eastern Economic Development: Philadelphia, 1815-1840,” Journal of Economic History, 35 (March 1975), 271-273CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also the dissertation from which this abstract is drawn.

31 Herbst, Lawrence A., “Interregional Commodity Trade from the North to the South and American Economic Development in the Antebellum Period,” Journal of Economic History, 35 (March 1975), 264-270CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Again, see also the dissertation which is abstracted in this publication.

32 See Bruchey, Stuart, “Douglass C. North on American Economic Growth,” Explorations in Entrepreneurial History (second series) 1 (Winter 1964), 145-158Google Scholar and North’s response in that issue. For a discussion of growth in the period to 1860 which draws out some of the implications of this critique, see also Bruchey’s, , The Roots of American Economic Growth, 1607-1861: An Essay in Social Causation (New York, 1965)Google Scholar.