Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-5wvtr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-23T23:12:30.949Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

BRITAIN AND GLOBALISATION SINCE 1850: II. THE RISE OF INSULAR CAPITALISM, 1914–1939

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2007

Abstract

At the end of the First World War, the British government attempted to return to the pre-war policy trade-off of fixed exchanges rates on the gold standard, capital mobility and free trade, which entailed a sacrifice of domestic monetary policy. But the attempt proved difficult between 1919 and 1931 when the pursuit of international economic polices was constrained by a growing concern for their domestic economic and political repercussions. In the 1930s, a new policy trade-off emerged: managed exchange rates, capital controls and protectionism, with a greater concern for domestic monetary policy. The essay explains the reasons for the emergence of constraints and the subsequent abandonment of the pre-1914 policy trade-off in terms of five variables: changes in the performance of the economy and its impact on different actors; the politics of the national debt and the constraints on interest rates; the impact of capital exports on debt repayment and as an alternative to interest rates in influencing the exchanges; an adjustment in assumptions about flexibility of wages and costs; and a breakdown in the political culture of free trade and gold.

Type
Presidential Address
Copyright
Copyright © Royal Historical Society 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 R. Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes, ii:The Economist as Saviour, 1920–1937 (1992), 183–6, 191, 476–8. The lecture was delivered in Dublin on 17 Apr. 1933 and published in New Statesman, 8 and 15 July 1933. See also Markwell, D., John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace (Oxford, 2006), 719, 152–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes, ii, note on 478, quoting G. L. Schwartz, New Statesman, 22 July 1933; Markwell, John Maynard Keynes and International Relations, 156–8.

3 Trentmann, F., ‘The Resurrection and Decomposition of Cobden in Britain and the West: An Essay in the Politics of Reputation’, in Rethinking Nineteenth-Century Liberalism: Richard Cobden Bicentenary Essays, ed. Howe, A. and Morgan, S. (Aldershot, 2006), 273Google Scholar, quoting House of Lords Record Office, Stansgate Papers ST28614.

4 See Daunton, M., ‘Britain and Globalisation since 1850: I. Creating a Global Order, 1850–1914’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 16 (2006), 68CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Aghion, P. and Williamson, J. G., Growth, Inequality and Globalization: Theory, Inequality and Policy (Cambridge, 1998)Google Scholar, Part ii; these lectures summarise and bring out some of the implications of O'Rourke, K. H. and Williamson, J. G., Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy (Cambridge, MA, 1999)Google Scholar – see 93 for the metaphor of plants.

6 James, H., The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression (Cambridge, MA, 2001), 13, 197Google Scholar.

7 Eichengreen, B., Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 (New York and Oxford, 1992), 421Google Scholar, 31, 391–4; on the problems of international institutions, see James, End of Globalization, 33–7.

8 Daunton, ‘Britain and Globalisation: I’, 1–38.

9 Matthews, R. C. O., Feinstein, C. H. and Odling-Smee, J. C., British Economic Growth, 1856–1973 (Oxford, 1982), 501CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 503, 543; also Dowie, J. R., ‘1919–20 Is in Need of Attention’, Economic History Review, 28 (1975), 429–50Google Scholar.

10 Broadberry, S. N., ‘The Emergence of Mass Unemployment: Explaining Macroeconmic Trends in Britain during the Trans-World War I Period’, Economic History Review, 43 (1990), 271–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Solomou, S., Themes in Macroeconomic History: The UK Economy, 1919–1939 (Cambridge, 1996), 47CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kitson, M. and Solomou, S., Protectionism and Economic Revival: The British Interwar Economy (Cambridge, 1980), 51–3, 83Google Scholar.

11 Redmond, J., ‘The Sterling Overvaluation in 1925: A Multilateral Approach’, Economic History Review, 37 (1984), 520–32Google Scholar; and Matthews, K. G. P., ‘Was Sterling Overvalued in 1925?’, Economic History Review, 39 (1986), 572–87Google Scholar.

12 Broadberry, ‘Emergence of Mass Unemployment’, 282; Solomou, Themes, 39–40.

13 C. E. Fayle, The War and the Shipping Industry (1927); S. G. Sturmey, British Shipping and World Competition (1962); Daniels, G. W. and Jewkes, J., ‘The Post-War Depression in the Lancashire Cotton Industry’, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 91 (1928), 170–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Tolliday, S., Business, Banking and Politics: The Case of British Steel, 1918–1939 (Cambridge, MA, 1987), 177–8Google Scholar.

14 Solomou, Themes, 47.

15 Arnold, A. J., ‘Profitability and Capital Accumulation in British Industry during the Transwar Period, 1913–24’, Economic History Review, 52 (1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, table 3; Broadberry, S. N., ‘The Impact of the World Wars on the Long-Run Performance of the British Economy’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 4 (1988), 2537CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Matthews, Feinstein and Odling-Smee, British Economic Growth, 186.

16 Daunton, M. J., ‘How to Pay for the War: State, Society and Taxation in Britain, 1917–24’, English Historical Review, 111 (1996), 896903, 912Google Scholar; Daunton, Just Taxes: The Politics of Taxation in Britain, 1914–1979 (Cambridge, 2002), 83–94.

17 Solomou, Themes, 44–5, 53.

18 This and the previous paragraph are based on Daunton, ‘How to Pay for the War’, 882–919.

19 Daunton, Just Taxes, 123, 125–7.

20 Nevin, E., The Mechanism of Cheap Money: A Study of British Monetary Policy, 1931–1939 (Cardiff, 1955)Google Scholar; Daunton, Just Taxes, 188–9.

21 Daunton, ‘Britain and Globalisation: I’, 36.

22 George Wyndham, quoted in E. H. H. Green, The Crisis of Conservatism: The Politics, Economics and Ideology of the British Conservative Party, 1880–1914 (1995), 236.

23 Clarke, P. F., Liberals and Social Democrats (Cambridge, 1978), ch. 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cain, P., Hobson and Imperialism: Radicalism, New Liberalism and Finance, 1887–1938 (Oxford, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24 United Nations, International Capital Movements during the Inter-War Period (Lake Success, New York, 1949), 4, 10, 15Google Scholar.

25 Atkin, J., ‘Official Regulation of British Overseas Investment, 1914–1931’, Economic History Review, 23 (1970), 325Google Scholar.

26 Atkin, ‘Official Regulation’, 326–8.

27 Ibid., 329–31.

28 The National Archive [hereafter TNA], T176/17, O. Niemeyer, 13 May 1925.

29 TNA, T176/17, draft telegram to governor generals of Australia, New Zealand and Canada, 27 May 1925, and O. Niemeyer to H. Lambert (Colonial Office), 30 May 1925; Lambert to Niemeyer, 2 June 1925; Lambert to Leith-Ross, 5 June 1925; Leith-Ross to Fergusson, 8 June 1925.

30 TNA, T176/17, M. Norman to W. S. Churchill, 9 June 1925.

31 TNA, T176/17, Commonwealth of Australia to Churchill, 11 June 1925; S. J. Chapman to Niemeyer, 24 June 1925; R. Horne to Churchill, 3 July 1925; Amery to Churchill, 16 Oct 1925; Churchill to Amery, 20 Oct. 1925; cutting from Morning Post, 23 Oct. 1925, ‘Dominion loans’; T. Coghlan to L. Amery, 27 Oct. 1925; Edgcumbe to Coghlan, 29 Oct. 1925.

32 TNA, T176/17, Churchill to O. Niemeyer, 21 July 1925; Niemeyer to chancellor, 21 July 1925.

33 Atkin, ‘Official Regulation’, 333; TNA, T176/17, R. W. Perks to comptroller-general, Department of Overseas Trade, 28 July 1925.

34 TNA, T176/17, G. W. Paish to Montagu Norman, 29 Sept. 1925, with marginal comments by the Treasury; see also article by Paish, ‘World Commerce and Credit, No. 1, The Treasury Embargo on Foreign Loans’, Westminster Gazette, 31 July 1925; O. Niemeyer, 19 Sept. 1925

35 Atkin, ‘Official Regulation’, 330–1.

36 Clarke, P. F., ‘The Treasury's Analytical Model of the British Economy between the Wars’, in The State and Economic Knowledge: The American and British Experiences, ed. Furner, M. O. and Supple, B. (Cambridge, 1990), 180–3Google Scholar, citing TNA, T172/2095, Leith-Ross memo., 9 Aug. 1928; CP 53(29); Memorandum on Certain Proposals relating to Unemployment (1929), 51.

37 Atkin, ‘Official Regulation’, 333.

38 Clarke, ‘Analytical Model’, 191–3, citing TNA, T175/26, ‘Note on Mr Keynes's Exposition’, ‘The Assumptions of Mr Keynes’; TNA, T200/1, ‘Effects of Lending Abroad’; Clay, ‘Remedies’, in Clay to Osborne, 18 May 1930, Bank of England Archives, S44/1 (1).

39 Atkin, ‘Official Regulation’, 331, 334; UN, International Capital Movements, 54.

40 A. Marshall, Elements of the Economics of Industry (1892), 19, cited in Brown, E. H. Phelps, The Origins of Trade Union Power (Oxford, 1983), 27Google Scholar.

41 J. M. Keynes, The Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill (1925), in Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, xix: Activities 1922–1929: The Return to Gold and Industrial Policy (1981), 218, 224, 233–4.

42 Quoted in Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes, ii, 205.

43 Pigou, A. C., ‘Wage Policy and Unemployment’, Economic Journal, 37 (1927), 355CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 Eichengreen, Golden Fetters, 15–16.

45 Bernanke, B. and Carey, K., ‘Nominal Wage Stickiness and Aggregate Supply in the Great Depression’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (1996), 872CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Eichengreen, B. and Sachs, J., ‘Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s’, Journal of Economic History, 45 (1985), 925–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 Eichengreen, Golden Fetters, 16; see also Cooper, R., ‘Predetermined Wages and Prices and the Impact of Expansionary Government Policy’, Review of Economic Studies, 57 (1990), 205–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 M. Daunton, A Property Owning Democracy? Housing in Britain (1987), 28–31.

48 See James, End of Globalization, 170, citing L. Robbins, The Great Depression (1934), 60–1.

49 Benjamin, D. K. and Kochin, L. A., ‘Searching for an Explanation of Unemployment in Interwar Britain’, Journal of Political Economy, 87 (1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Eichengreen, B., ‘Unemployment in Interwar Britain: Dole or Doldrums?’, Oxford Economic Papers, 39 (1987), 597623CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51 Clay, H., ‘The Public Regulation of Wages in Great Britain’, Economic Journal, 39 (1929), 323–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar; A. C. Pigou, The Theory of Unemployment (1933), 254.

52 Pigou, ‘Wage Policy and Unemployment’, 355–68, citing Rueff and Stamp.

53 H. Clay, The Post-War Unemployment Problem (1929); Clay, ‘Public Regulation’, 323–43; H. Clay, ‘Dr Cannan's Views on Unemployment’, Economic Journal, 40 (1930), 331–5.

54 Pigou, ‘Wage Policy and Unemployment’.

55 J. M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936), 12–14.

56 Cannan, E., ‘The Post-War Unemployment Problem’, Economic Journal, 40 (1930), 4555CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

57 Clarke, ‘Analytical Model’, 179–80, citing TNA, T172/2095, Leith-Ross to Hawtrey, 1 Aug. 1928, and Leith-Ross memo., 9 Aug. 1928.

58 Clarke, ‘Analytical Model’, 184–6, citing TNA, T175/26, Leith-Ross to Hawtrey, 13 Mar. 1929; TNA, T172/2095, Leith-Ross, draft for Churchill, Apr. 1929; Memorandum on Certain Proposals.

59 Trentmann, F., ‘Wealth versus Welfare: The British Left between Free Trade and National Political Economy before the First World War’, Historical Research, 70 (1997), 77CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

60 Trentmann, F., ‘Civil Society, Commerce, and the “Citizen-Consumer”’, in Paradoxes of Civil Society, ed. idem (Oxford and New York, 2000), 321–2Google Scholar; Trentmann, F., ‘Bread, Milk and Democracy: Consumption and Citizenship in Twentieth-Century Britain’, in The Politics of Consumption: Material Culture and Citizenship in Europe and America, ed. Daunton, M. and Hilton, M. (Oxford, 2001), 129–63Google Scholar.

61 Trentmann, ‘The Resurrection and Decomposition of Cobden’, especially 270–6. Trentmann, Harvard University Center for European Studies Working Paper 66, 28–9.

62 Trentmann, F., ‘The Transformation of Fiscal Reform: Reciprocity, Modernization, and the Fiscal Debate within the Business Community in Early Twentieth-Century Britain’, Historical Journal, 39 (1996), 1042–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

63 Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes, ii, 370–2, 374–6.

64 In Tariffs: The Case Examined, ed. W. H. Beveridge (1932).

65 Quoted in Brown, W. A., England and the New Gold Standard, 1919–1926 (New Haven, 1929), 253Google Scholar.

66 Keynes, Economic Consequences of Mr Churchill, 170.

67 Cecco, M. De, Money and Empire: The International Gold Standard, 1890–1914 (Oxford, 1974), 102, 132–41Google Scholar; see the Treasury memorandum by Basil Blackett, 25 May 1914 (TNA, T170/19), printed on 173–206; Hume, L. J., ‘The Gold Standard and Deflation: Issues and Attitudes in the 1920s’, Ecomomica, 30 (1963), 226Google Scholar.

68 Hume, ‘Gold Standard and Deflation’, 225–42.