Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T17:55:24.379Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Marketing the Market: The Ideology of Market Mechanisms for Biodiversity Conservation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 July 2013

Jerneja Penca*
Affiliation:
European University Institute, Florence (Italy). Email: jerneja.penca@eui.eu.

Abstract

The emergence of market mechanisms for the protection of biodiversity and ecosystem services in recent years has been portrayed by most conservation institutions and epistemological frameworks as an unprecedented opportunity for the conservation of nature. This article shifts the focus from the improved effectiveness arguments concerning such mechanisms to examine their institutional and political context and origins. It outlines the field of transnational biodiversity markets and uncovers the normative biases it displays. The regulatory vocabulary of ‘market mechanisms’ is juxtaposed to the more explicit ideological approach professed by the critics of neoliberalism. The argument is that, rather than an inevitable component in contemporary conservation governance, market mechanisms imply a set of contested choices for certain values, a particular economic development trajectory, a particular understanding of the biodiversity problem, and a weak role for legal obligations. Transnational environmental law needs to establish its interest beyond that of the regulation literature if it is to account for the proliferating movements around the world in favour of a reasserted normative guidance for the markets and against the process of marketing the market.

Type
Symposium: Markets For Ecosystem Services
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 E.g. UN GA Resolution A/RES/65/161 of 20 Dec. 2011 (declaring the United Nations Decade on Biodiversity (2011–20) as the timeframe for implementing the Strategic Plan for Biodiversity agreed in Nagoya Japan in Oct. 2010), available at: http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=A/RES/65/161.

2 Morrow, K., ‘Rio+20, the Green Economy and Re-orienting Sustainable Development’ (2012) 14(4) Environmental Law Review, pp. 279–97.Google Scholar

4 Daily, G.C. & Matson, P.A., ‘Ecosystem Services: From Theory to Implementation’ (2008) 105(28) Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, pp. 9455–6, at 9455.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed

5 E.g., Barnosky, A.D. et al. ., ‘Has the Earth’s Sixth Mass Extinction Already Arrived?’ (2011) 471 Nature, pp. 51–7.Google Scholar

6 This article emerges from one such occasion, the Conference on Regulatory and Institutional Frameworks for Markets for Ecosystem Services, held at the University of Surrey (UK) on 6–7 June 2012. Another example includes the Workshop on Markets for Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services, at Chatham House, London (UK), 29 Nov. 2011, organized by the Secretariat of the CBD and the UNEP World Conservation Monitoring Centre.

7 See, e.g., the following themed/special issues: (2004) 35(3) Geoforum, pp. 269–394; (2005) 16(1) Capitalism Nature Socialism, pp. 1–137; (2010) 42(3) Antipode, pp. 469–799; (2012) 43(3) Geoforum, pp. 363–426.

8 See, e.g., Kysar, D., ‘Sustainable Development and Private Global Governance’ (2008) 83 Texas Law Review, pp. 2109–66Google Scholar; Driesen, D.M., ‘Sustainable Development and Market Liberalism’s Shotgun Wedding: Emissions Trading under the Kyoto Protocol’ (2008) 83(1) Indiana Law Journal, pp. 2169Google Scholar; Dryzek, J., ‘Ecology and Discursive Democracy: Beyond Liberal Capitalism and the Administrative State’ (1992) 3(2) Capitalism, Nature, Socialism, pp. 1842Google Scholar; Schweickart, D., ‘Is Sustainable Capitalism an Oxymoron?’ (2009) 8(2/3) Perspectives on Global Development and Technology, pp. 559–80.Google Scholar

9 See, e.g., Kelman, S., What Price Incentives? Economists and the Environment (Auburn House, 1981)Google Scholar; Anderson, E., Value of Ethics in Economics (Harvard University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Sagoff, M., The Economy of the Earth: Philosophy, Law, and the Environment (Cambridge University Press, 2008)Google Scholar; O’Neill, J., Holland, A. & Light, A., Environmental Values (Routledge, 2008)Google Scholar; Sandel, M.J., What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets (Allen Lane, 2012).Google Scholar

10 See Böhm, S. & Dabhi, S. (eds), Upsetting the Offset: The Political Economy of Carbon Markets (Mayfly Books, 2009)Google Scholar; Newell, P. & Paterson, M., Climate Capitalism: Global Warming and the Transformation of the Global Economy (Cambridge University Press, 2010)Google Scholar; Lohmann, L., ‘Uncertainty Markets and Carbon Markets: Variations on Polanyian Themes’ (2010) 15(2) New Political Economy, pp. 225–54Google Scholar; Winter, G., ‘The Climate is No Commodity: Taking Stock of the Emissions Trading System’ (2010) 22(1) Journal of Environmental Law, pp. 125.Google Scholar

11 See, e.g., Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Harnessing Markets for Biodiversity: Towards Conservation and Sustainable Use (OECD, 2003)Google Scholar, available at http://www.peblds.org/files/Publications/OECD/OECD_Harnessing_Markets_for_Biodiversity.pdf; Madsen, B., Carroll, N. & Moore Brands, K., State of Biodiversity Markets Report: Offset and Compensation Programs Worldwide (Ecosystems Marketplace, 2010)Google Scholar, available at: http://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/documents/acrobat/sbdmr.pdf.

12 Bobbitt, P., The Shield of Achilles: War, Peace, and the Course of History (Anchor Books, 2002).Google Scholar

13 Levi-Faur, D., ‘The Global Diffusion of Regulatory Capitalism’ (2005) 598(1) The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, pp. 1232, at 14.Google Scholar

14 E.Fisher, C., ‘Unpacking the Toolbox: Or Why the Public/Private Divide is Important in EC Environmental Law’, in Freedland, M. & Auby, J.B. (eds), The Public Law/Private Law Divide: Une entente assez cordiale? (Hart, 2006), pp. 215–42.Google Scholar

15 Teubner, G., ‘Altera Pars Audiatur: Law in the Collision of Discourses’, in Rawlings, R. (ed.), Law, Society and Economy (Oxford University Press, 1997), pp. 149–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Perez, O., ‘The Many Faces of the Trade-Environment Conflict: Some Lessons for the Constitutionalization Project’, in Joerges, C., Sand, I.J. & Teubner, G. (eds), Transnational Governance and Constitutionalism (Hart, 2004), pp. 233–56.Google Scholar

17 Callies, G.P. & Zumbansen, P., Rough Consensus and Running Code: A Theory of Transnational Private Law (Hart, 2012), at p. ixGoogle Scholar; Heyvaert, V. & Etty, T.F.M., ‘Introducing Transnational Environmental Law’ (2012) 1(1) Transnational Environmental Law, pp 111, at 2.Google Scholar

18 Swanson, T., ‘Economics of a Biodiversity Convention’ (1992) 21(3) Ambio, pp. 250–7.Google Scholar

19 See, e.g., O’Sullivan, R. & Saines, R., ‘International Market Solutions to Protect Tropical Rainforests’, in Freestone, D. & Streck, C. (eds), Legal Aspects of Carbon Trading: Kyoto, Copenhagen, and Beyond (Oxford University Press, 2009), pp. 583605Google Scholar, at 594.

20 See, e.g., Lutz, E. & Oliver Caldecott, J. (eds), Decentralization and Biodiversity Conservation (World Bank, 1996)Google Scholar; Reid, C.T., ‘The Privatisation of Biodiversity? Possible New Approaches to Nature Conservation Law in the UK’ (2011) 23(2) Journal of Environmental Law, pp. 203–31.Google Scholar

21 See McCarthy, J., ‘Devolution in the Woods: Community Forestry as Hybrid Neoliberalism’ (2005) 37(6) Environment and Planning A, pp. 9951014.Google Scholar

22 See especially Costanza, R. et al. ., ‘The Value of the World’s Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital’ (1997) 387(6630) Nature, pp. 253–60Google Scholar; United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), Millennium Ecosystem Assessment: Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Synthesis (UNEP, 2005)Google Scholar; TEEB, The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Mainstreaming the Economics of Nature: A Synthesis of the Approach, Conclusions and Recommendations of TEEB (2010), available at: http://www.teebweb.org/publications/teeb-study-reports/synthesis.

23 UNEP, ibid., at p. 21.

24 See, e.g., Donnelly, C., Delegation of Governmental Power to Private Parties: A Comparative Perspective (Oxford University Press, 2007).Google Scholar

25 See, e.g., Raustiala, K., ‘Nonstate Actors in the Global Climate Regime’, in Luterbacher, U. & Sprinz, D.F. (eds), International Relations and Global Climate Change (MIT, 2001), pp. 95118Google Scholar; Streck, C., ‘Innovativeness and Paralysis in International Climate Policy’ (2012) 1(1) Transnational Environmental Law, pp. 137–52.Google Scholar

26 Rio de Janeiro (Brazil), 5 June 1992, in force 29 Dec. 1993, available at: http://www.cbd.int/convention/text. Although technically a treaty, I refer to the CBD regime as an institution, based on the specific role played by the Conferences of Parties: see Brunnée, J., ‘COPing with Consent: Law-Making under Multilateral Environmental Agreements’ (2004) 15(1) Leiden Journal of International Law, pp. 152Google Scholar; Lefeber, R., ‘Creative Legal Engineering’ (2000) 13(1) Leiden Journal of International Law, pp 19.Google Scholar

27 CBD, Art. 11.

28 Sustainable use of components of biodiversity and ‘the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising out of the utilization of genetic resources’ are two of objectives of the CBD: Art 1.

29 See, e.g., UNEP/CBD/COP/3/18; UNEP/CBD/COP/5/15 (the programme of work on incentives, adopted in 2000); UNEP/CBD/COP/6/16.

30 Menzel, S., ‘Financial Support for Biodiversity Protection in Developing Countries: Does the CBD Mechanism Lead to an Appropriate Level of Biodiversity Protection?’ in R. Buse et al. . (eds), Valuation and Conservation of Biodiversity – Interdisciplinary View on the Convention on Biological Diversity (Springer, 2005), pp. 2341.Google Scholar

31 See, e.g., Kaul, I., Grunberg, I. & Stern, M.A., ‘Introduction’, in Kaul, I., Grunberg, I. & Stern, M.A. (eds), Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century (Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. xix–xxxvi,Google Scholar (identifying the ‘incentive gap’ or the focus on aid mechanisms as part of three key obstacles to a better supply of global public goods).

32 Critical for that was the establishment of the Working Group on Economic Instruments in Environmental Policymaking in June 2001, which operates within the Economics and Trade Branch of UNEP.

33 UNEP, Economic Instruments in Biodiversity-related Multilateral Environmental Agreements (2004), available at: http://www.unep.ch/etb/publications/EconInst/ecoInstBioMea.pdf.

34 UNEP, Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication (2011), available at: http://www.unep.org/greeneconomy/portals/88/documents/ger/GER_synthesis_en.pdf; see also the final resolution of Rio+20, ‘The Future We Want’, UN Doc. A/66/L.56, available at: http://www.uncsd2012.org/rio20/thefuturewewant.html. See also Morrow, n. 2 above; Penca, J., ‘Green Economy and Environmental Law: A Mismatch and Why Bother?’, in Sancin, V. (ed.), International Environmental Law: Contemporary Concerns and Challenges (G.V. Založba, 2012).Google Scholar

35 The Business and Biodiversity Programme is a specific unit of the Secretariat, focusing specifically on influencing private sector policy and practice.

36 MacDonald, K.I., ‘The Devil is in the (Bio)Diversity: Private Sector “Engagement” and the Restructuring of Biodiversity Conservation’ (2010) 42(3) Antipode, pp. 513–50, at 537–8.Google Scholar

37 IUCN, ‘Position Paper on Green Economy: Transitioning to a Green Economy – Building on Nature’(2012), available at: https://cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/position_paper_on_green_economy_22march2012.pdf.

38 J. Metcalfe & F. Vorhies, ‘Exploring the Case for a Green Development Mechanism’, International Workshop on Innovative Financial Mechanisms: First meeting, Bonn (Germany), 27–29 Jan. 2010, available at: http://www.cbd.int/financial/doc/gdm-exploring-the-case-en.pdf.

39 D. Jarrett, ‘Biodiversity, Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital: Terms Matter’, Ecometrica, 27 Nov. 2012, available at: http://ecometrica.com/blog/biodiversity-ecosystem-services-and-natural-capital-terms-matter.

40 E.g., TEEB, The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity for National and International Policy Makers – Summary: Responding to the Value of Nature (2009), available at: http://www.teebweb.org/publications/teeb-study-reports/national-and-international.

41 Bishop, J. et al. ., Building Biodiversity Business (Shell International and IUCN, 2008), at p. 11.Google Scholar

42 Ibid., at p. 10.

43 GRAIN, ‘No Air, Don’t Sell Yourself’ (April 2005) Seedling, pp. 3441Google Scholar, available at: http://www.grain.org/article/archive/categories/34-seedling-april-2005.

44 The WWF builds strong relationships with businesses especially through the initiatives ‘Strategic Partnerships’ and ‘Transforming Markets’; available at http://www.wwf.org.uk/what_we_do/working_with_business/how_we_work_with_business.

45 CI pioneers the use of ‘conservation incentive agreements’ as a key mechanism for ‘strategies that make conservation economically viable’, available at: http://www.conservation.org/learn/culture/communities/Pages/incentives.aspx.

46 ‘Markets & Enterprise’ is one of four programme areas of the WRI, available at: http://www.wri.org/markets.

47 Pursuing ‘non-confrontational, pragmatic, market-based solutions to conservation challenges’ is the very rationale of the Nature Conservancy, available at http://www.nature.org/about-us/our-partners/index.htm.

48 E.g., the signatures of: Acción Ecológica, Carta abierta a la secretaría de la Convención de diversidad boilógica y a los gobiernos de Japón, India, Noruega, Suecia y Ecuador, available at: http://www.accionecologica.org/component/content/article/1543-carta-abierta-a-la-secretaria-de-la-convencion-de-diversidad-biologica-y-a-los-gobiernos-de-japon-india-noruega-suecia-y-ecuador.

49 Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D., ‘The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice’ (1981) 211 Science, pp. 453–8Google Scholar; Hajer, M., The Politics of Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and the Policy Process (Clarendon Press, 1995).Google Scholar

50 James, A., Gaston, K.J. & Balmford, A., ‘Can We Afford to Conserve Biodiversity?’ (2001) 51(1) BioScience, pp. 4352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

51 See, e.g., Escobar, A., ‘Whose Knowledge, Whose Nature? Biodiversity, Conservation, and the Political Ecology of Social Movements’ (1998) 5(1) Journal of Political Ecology, pp. 5382.Google Scholar

52 Madsen et al., n. 11 above.

53 In 2010 there were 39 markets and 25 under development: ibid.

54 D.P. Wheeler & J.M. Strock, ‘Official Policy on Conservation Banks’, 7 Apr. 1995, available at: http://ceres.ca.gov/wetlands/policies/mitbank.html.

55 Business and Biodiversity Offsets Programme, Standard on Biodiversity Offsets (2012), available at: http://www.forest-trends.org/documents/files/doc_3078.pdf.

56 G. Monbiot, ‘The Unsung World’, 8 Dec. 2012, available at http://www.monbiot.com/2012/12/08/the-unsung-world.

57 Bayon, R., ‘Biodiversity Banking: A Primer’, in The Worldwatch Institute, 2008 State of the World: Innovations for a Sustainable Economy (2009), pp. 123–37Google Scholar, at 126, available at: http://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/media/pdf/SOW08-9-Bayon.pdf.

58 Gibbons, P., ‘A Tree for a Tree: Can Biodiversity Offsets Balance Destruction and Restoration?’, The Conversation, 5 Oct. 2011Google Scholar, available at: http://theconversation.com/a-tree-for-a-tree-can-biodiversity-offsets-balance-destruction-and-restoration-3682.

59 Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Kyoto (Japan), 10 Dec. 1997, in force 16 Feb. 2005, Art. 12, available at: http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/items/2830.php.

60 E.g., Vlachou, A. & Konstantinidis, C., ‘Climate Change: The Political Economy of Kyoto Flexible Mechanisms’ (2010) 42(1) Review of Radical Political Economics, pp. 3249Google Scholar; Cabello, J., ‘The Politics of the Clean Development Mechanism: Hiding Capitalism under the Green Rug’, in Böhm & Dabhi, n. 10 above; C. Voigt, ‘Is the Clean Development Mechanism Sustainable – Some Critical Aspects’ (2008) 15 Sustainable Development Law & Policy, pp. 1521.Google Scholar

61 See decisions UNEP/CBD/VIII/26, para. 6(c); UNEP/CBD/VI/15 Annex, para. 37; UNEP/CBD/VIII/13, para. 4.

62 Metcalfe & Vorhies, n. 38 above.

63 GDI, ‘BioAreas Reference Guide: The BioAreas Standard & Registry for Biodiversity-Responsible Area Management’, Mar. 2012, available at: http://gdi.earthmind.net/files/BioAreas-Reference-Guide-Version1-01Mar2012.pdf.

64 Ibid., at pp. 16–18; the decision being referred to is UNEP/CBD/COP/9/IX, Part B, para. 4.

65 GDI, ‘Biodiversity Tools for the GDI Objectives’, available at: http://gdi.earthmind.net/toolkit/biodiversity.

66 Paul, H. & Lorch, A., ‘Finance, Targets, Green Economy and Innovative Financial Mechanisms’ (2010) 5 Square Brackets, pp. 67.Google Scholar

67 Leahy, S., ‘Environment: Market-based Conservation Brewing in Nairobi’, Inter Press Service, 1 June 2010Google Scholar, available at: http://www.ipsnews.net/2010/06/environment-market-based-conservation-brewing-in-nairobi.

68 Ibid.

69 I use the term REDD to refer to the full scope of activities, covered also by ‘REDD+’, i.e. including those supporting the conservation of forests, their sustainable management and the enhancement of forest carbon stock.

70 See (2008) 10(3) International Forestry Review – Special Issue on REDD; Angelsen, A. et al. . (eds), Analysing REDD+: Challenges and choices (CIFOR, 2012).Google Scholar

71 UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/XIII/6, para. 22.

72 Rio de Janeiro (Brazil), 4 June 1992, in force 21 Mar. 1994, available at: http://unfccc.int/key_documents/the_convention/items/2853.php.

73 See, e.g., Forest Carbon Partnership Facility of the World Bank, available at: http://www.forestcarbonpartnership.org; UN REDD Programme, available at: http://www.un-redd.org; The REDD+ Partnership, available at: http://reddpluspartnership.org/en.

74 See, e.g., Friends of the Earth, ‘Dangerous Distraction – Why Offsetting is Failing the Climate and the People: The Evidence’, June 2009, available at: http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/briefing_notes/dangerous_distraction.pdf; Durban Group for Climate Justice, ‘Durban Statement on REDD’ (2010), available at: http://www.durbanclimatejustice.org/press-releases/durban-statement-on-redd.html; C. Lang, ‘Interview with Teguh Surya, WALHI: “We are against REDD. We are against Carbon Trading”’, 9 Mar. 2012, available at: http://www.redd-monitor.org/2012/03/09/interview-with-teguh-surya-walhi-we-are-against-redd-we-are-against-carbon-trading.

75 Wright, G., ‘Indigenous People and Customary Land Ownership under Domestic REDD Frameworks: A Case Study of Indonesia’ (2012) 7(2) Law, Environment and Development Journal, pp. 119–31.Google Scholar

76 Harvey, C.A. et al. ., What is Needed to Make REDD+ Work on the Ground? Lessons Learned from Pilot Forest Carbon Initiatives (Conservation International, 2010), at p. 54.Google Scholar

77 See, e.g., Humphreys, D., Forest Politics: The Evolution of International Cooperation (Earthscan, 1996)Google Scholar; Humphreys, D., Logjam: Deforestation and the Crisis of Global Governance (Earthscan, 2006).Google Scholar

78 Redfort, K.H. & Adams, W.W., ‘Payment for Ecosystem Services and the Challenge of Saving Nature’ (2009) 23(4) Conservation Biology, pp. 785–7.Google Scholar

79 See, e.g., Acción Ecológica, n. 48 above.

80 Ibid.

81 Farber, D.A., ‘Adapting to Climate Change: Who Should Pay’ (2007) 23(1) Journal of Land Use and Environmental Law, pp. 137, at 26–8.Google Scholar

82 Affolder, N., ‘Transnational Conservation Contracts’ (2012) 25(2) Leiden Journal of International Law, pp. 443–60.Google Scholar

83 UNEP/CBD/WS-IFM/1/1.

84 OECD, Paying for Biodiversity: Enhancing the Cost-Effectiveness of Payments for Ecosystem Services, available at: http://www.oecd.org/env/resources/46135424.pdf.

85 Madsen et al., n. 11 above, at p. vii.

86 Eftec, IEEP et al., ‘The Use of Market-based Instruments for Biodiversity Protection – The Case of Habitat Banking: Technical Report’, Feb. 2010, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/pdf/eftec_habitat_technical_report.pdf.

87 See, e.g., OECD, Handbook of Market Creation for Biodiversity: Issues in Implementation (2004); OECD, n. 11 above, I. Bräuer et al., ‘The Use of Market Incentives to Preserve Biodiversity’, July 2006, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/biodiversity/pdf/mbi.pdf.

88 R. Pirard & E. Broughton, ‘What’s in a Name? Market-based Instruments for Biodiversity’, Institute for Sustainable Development and International Relations (IDDRI), Policy Brief No. 01/2011, available at: http://www.iddri.org/Publications/What-s-in-a-name-Market-based-instruments-for-biodiversity.

89 Samuelson, P.A. & Nordhaus, W.D., Economics (McGraw Hill, 17th edn, 2001), at p. 27.Google Scholar

90 Krugman, P. & Wells, R., Economics (Word, 2nd edn, 2009), at p. 62.Google Scholar

91 Wunder, S. & Vargas, M.T., ‘Beyond Markets: Why Terminology Matters’, The Ecosystem Marketplace, 22 Mar. 2005Google Scholar, available at: http://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/dynamic/article.page.php?page_id=1252&section=water_market&eod=1.

92 Wunder, S., ‘Are Direct Payments for Environmental Services Spelling Doom for Sustainable Forest Management in the Tropics?’ (2006) 11(2) Ecology and Society, pp. 2334.Google Scholar

93 Pirard & Broughton, n. 88 above, at p. 4.

94 Madsen et al., n. 11 above, at p. 1.

95 Pirard & Broughton, n. 88 above, at p. 14.

96 Daily, G., ‘Preface’, in Daily, G. (ed.), Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems (Island Press, 1997), at pp. xvxx.Google Scholar

97 Driesen, D., ‘Alternatives to Regulation? Market Mechanisms and the Environment’, in Cave, M., Baldwin, R. & Lodge, M., The Oxford Handbook of Regulation (Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 203–22.Google Scholar

98 Stavins, R., ‘Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience’, in Freeman, J. & Kolstad, C.D. (eds), Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience (Oxford University Press, 2006), pp 1937, at 19.Google Scholar

99 Wunder, n. 92 above.

100 Freeman, J. & Farber, D., ‘Modular Environmental Regulation’ (2005) 54(4) Duke Law Journal, pp. 795912Google Scholar, at 819; D.M. Driesen, ‘Is Emissions Trading an Economic Incentive Program? Replacing the Command and Control/Economic Incentive Dichotomy’ (1998) 55 Washington and Lee Law Review, pp. 289–350, at 300.

101 See, e.g., J. Freeman & C.D. Kolstad, ‘Prescriptive Environmental Regulations versus Market-based Incentives’, in Freeman and Kolstad, n. 98 above, at pp. 3–16.

102 See, e.g., R.L. Revesz & R.N. Stavins, ‘Environmental Law and Policy’, in A.M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (eds), The Handbook of Law and Economics (Elsevier, 2007), pp. 499–571.

103 Fisher, n. 14 above.

104 Freeman & Kolstad, n. 98 above, at p. 5.

105 E.g. Fiorino, D.J., The New Environmental Regulation (The MIT Press, 2006)Google Scholar; Jordan, A., Wurzel, R.K.W. & Zito, A.R., ‘“New” Instruments of Environmental Governance: Patterns and Pathways of Change’ (2003) 12(1) Environmental Politics, pp. 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

106 E.g., Greenspan Bell, R. & Russell, C., ‘Environmental Policy for Developing Countries: Most Nations Lack the Infrastructure and Expertise Necessary to Implement the Market-based Strategies Being Recommended by the International Development Banks’ (2002) 18(3) Issues in Science and Technology, pp. 6370Google Scholar; Costi, A., ‘Reconciling Environmental Justice and Development in Transition Economies: The Central and Eastern European Reality’, in Bosselman, K. & Richardson, B.J. (eds), Environmental Justice and Market Mechanisms: Key Challenges for Environmental Law and Policy (Kluwer Law, 1999).Google Scholar

107 Grubb, M. et al. ., The Kyoto Protocol: A Guide and Assessment (Royal Institute for International Affairs, 1999), at pp. 108–9Google Scholar; Lohman, L., ‘Marketing and Making Carbon Dumps: Commodification, Calculation and Counterfactuals in Climate Change Mitigation’ (2005) 14(3) Science as Culture, pp. 203–35, at 204–6.Google Scholar

108 Salzman, J. & Ruhl, J.B., ‘Currencies and the Commodification of Environmental Law’ (2000) 53(3) Stanford Law Review, pp. 607–94Google Scholar; Salzman, J., ‘Creating Markets for Ecosystem Services: Notes from the Field’ (2005) 80 New York University Law Review, pp. 870961Google Scholar; Freeman & Kolstad, n. 101 above.

109 But see Driesen, D.M. (ed.), Economic Thought and US Climate Change Policy (The MIT Press, 2010)Google Scholar; D. Driesen, n. 97 above, at p. 219.

110 Heinzerling, L., ‘The Environment’, in Cane, P. & Tushnet, M. (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Legal Studies (Oxford University Press, 2003), pp. 701–24Google Scholar; Coglianese, C. & Courcy, C., ‘Environmental Regulation’, in Cane, P. & Kritzer, H.M. (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Empirical Legal Research (Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 449–68.Google Scholar

111 E.g., Stewart, R.B., ‘Instrument Choice’, in Bodansky, D., Brunnée, J. & Hey, E. (eds), The Oxford Handbook of International Environmental Law (Oxford University Press, 2007), pp. 147–81Google Scholar; Revesz & Stavins, n. 102 above.

112 Campbell, J.L. & Pedersen, O.K., ‘Introduction’, in Campbell, J.L. & Pedersen, O.K. (eds), The Rise of Neoliberalism and Institutional Analysis (Princeton University Press, 2001), pp. 124, at 3.Google Scholar

113 Pokorny, B. et al. ., ‘Market-based Conservation of the Amazonian Forests: Revisiting Win–Win Expectations’ (2012) 43 Geoforum, pp. 387401, at 388.Google Scholar

114 Castree, N., ‘Neoliberalising Nature: The Logics of Deregulation and Reregulation’ (2008) 40(1) Environment and Planning A, pp. 131–52, at 143.Google Scholar

115 Polanyi, K., The Great Transformation (Beacon Press, 2001), at p. 60.Google Scholar

116 Barnett, C., ‘Publics and Markets: What’s Wrong with Neoliberalism?’, in S. Smith et al. . (eds), The Handbook of Social Geography (Sage, 2010), pp. 269–96.Google Scholar

117 Clarke, J., ‘Dissolving the Public Realm?: The Logics and Limits of Neo-liberalism’ (2004) 33(01) Journal of Social Policy, pp. 2748.Google Scholar

118 Monbiot, n. 56 above.

119 E.g., Cloatre, E. & Wright, N., ‘A Socio-Legal Analysis of an Actor-World: The Case of Carbon Trading and the Clean Development Mechanism’ (2012) 39(1) Journal of Law and Society, pp. 7692Google Scholar; Reid, C., ‘Between Priceless and Worthless: Challenges in Using Market Mechanisms for Conserving Biodiversity’ (2013) 2(2) Transnational Environmental Law, pp. 217–33.Google Scholar

120 Spash, C., ‘Ecosystems Services Valuation: Socio-Economics and the Environment in Discussion’ (2008) CSIRO Working Paper SeriesGoogle Scholar, available at: http://csiro.au/files/files/pjpj.pdf; Gómez-Baggethun, E. & Ruiz-Pérez, M., ‘Economic Valuation and the Commodification of Ecosystem Services’ (2011) 35(5) Progress in Physical Geography, pp. 613–28.Google Scholar

121 E.g, McAfee, K., ‘Selling Nature to Save It? Biodiversity and Green Developmentalism’ (1998) 17(2) Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, pp. 133–54.Google Scholar

122 Winter, n. 10 above.

123 Clarke, J.H. & Newman, J.E., The Managerial State: Power, Politics and Ideology in the Remaking of Social Welfare (Sage, 1997), at p. xii.Google Scholar

124 E.g., Dehm, J., ‘Tricks of Perception and Perspective: The Disappearance of Law and Politics in Carbon Markets; Reading Alexandre Kossoy and Phillippe Ambrosi, “State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2010”’ (2011) 7(2) Macquarie Journal of International and Comparative Environmental Law, pp. 118.Google Scholar

125 Rockström, J. et al. ., ‘Planetary Boundaries: Exploring the Safe Operating Space for Humanity – Stockholm Resilience Centre’ (2009) 14(2) Ecology and Society, pp. 32–8.Google Scholar

126 Wunder & Vargas, n. 91 above.

127 See, e.g., B. de Sousa Santos, ‘Introducción: Las epistemologyías del Sur’, in Formas-Otras: Sabel, nombrar, narrar, hacer (CIDOB Ediciones, 2011–12), pp. 9–22, available at: http://www.boaventuradesousasantos.pt/media/INTRODUCCION_BSS.pdf. Note also the World People’s Conference on Climate Change and the Rights of Mother Earth, held in June 2012 in Cochabamba (Bolivia).

128 Levien, M. & Paret, M., ‘A Second Double Movement? Polanyi and Shifting Global Opinions on Neoliberalism’ (2012) 27(6) International Sociology, pp. 724–44.Google Scholar