Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-ttngx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-17T19:05:19.534Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Capital investment, business behaviour, and the macroeconomy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 March 2023

Michelle Baddeley*
Affiliation:
UTS Economics, UTS Business School, University of Technology Sydney, PO Box 123, Broadway, NSW 2007, Australia

Abstract

GC Harcourt made many fundamental and essential contributions to the development of capital investment theory – most famously via his development of the Cambridge Capital Controversies, exposing conceptual and analytical flaws and contradictions in neoclassical approaches to defining and measuring capital. Relatedly, Harcourt also made essential contributions to our understanding of how accounting rules, used by real-world businesses to guide their investment decision-making, create anomalies and deficiencies in the accumulation of capital at a microeconomic level – with significant, deleterious consequences for the accumulation of capital at a macroeconomic level. In developing Harcourt’s contributions, this paper links Harcourt’s early insights about accounting rules with subsequent developments in behavioural economic models of business decision-making, thus aligning Harcourt’s contributions with insights from behavioural models of investment decision-making. These insights are then combined in showing how the misapplication of investment appraisal criteria at a microeconomic level contributes to under-investment and investment volatility in the macroeconomy, with negative implications for output, employment, labour productivity, wages and cyclical volatility.

Type
Invited Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of UNSW Canberra

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abel, AB (1983) Optimal investment under uncertainty. American Economic Review 73(1): 228233.Google Scholar
Ainslie, G (1991) Derivation of ‘rational’ economic behavior from hyperbolic discount curves. American Economic Review 92(3): 411433.Google Scholar
Akerlof, GA (2002) Behavioral macroeconomics and macroeconomic behavior. American Economic Review 92(3): 411433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, GA and Shiller, R (2009) Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Angeletos, GM and Huo, Z (2021) Myopia and anchoring. American Economic Review 111(4): 11661200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletos, GM, Laibson, D, Repetto, A, et al. (2001) The hyberbolic consumption model: calibration, simulation, and empirical evaluation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(3): 4768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, GC and Hatzopoulos, PD (1999) Ex ante investment appraisal methods and ex post financial performance assessment comparison and the calculation of the cost of capital in UK Firms. Technical report, Aston Research Papers. No. 9908.Google Scholar
Baddeley, MC (2003) Investment: Theories and Analysis. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baddeley, MC (2006) Behind the black box: a survey of real-world investment appraisal approaches. Empirica 33: 329350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baddeley, MC (2014) Rethinking microfoundations of macroeconomics: insights from behavioural economics. European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies 11(1): 99112.Google Scholar
Baddeley, MC (2016) Behavioural macroeconomics: time, optimism and animal spirits. In: Frantz R, Chen S-H, Dopfer K, Heukelom F and Mousavi S (eds) Routledge Handbook of Behavioral Economics. Abingdon: Routledge, 266279.Google Scholar
Baddeley, MC (2017) Keynes’ psychology and behavioural macroeconomics: theory and policy. Economic and Labour Relations Review 28(2): 177196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brainard, WC and Tobin, J (1977) Asset markets and the cost of capital. In: Nelson, R and Balassa, B (eds) Economic Progress: Private Values and Public Policy (Essays in Honor of William Fellner). Amsterdam: North-Holland, 235262.Google Scholar
Chirinko, RS (1993) Business fixed investment spending: modelling strategies, empirical results and policy implications. Journal of Economic Literature 31(4): 18751911.Google Scholar
Cobb, CW and Douglas, PH (1928) A theory of production. American Economic Review 18(1): 139165.Google Scholar
Cohen, J, Ericson, KM, Laibson, D, et al. (2020) Measuring time preferences. Journal of Economic Literature 58(2): 299347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, J and Harcourt, GC (2003) Whatever happened to the Cambridge capital theory controversies. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1): 199214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Grauwe, P (2011) Animal spirits and monetary policy. Economic Theory 47(2–3): 423457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Grauwe, P (2012) Booms and busts in economic activity: a behavioural explanation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 83(3): 484501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, AK and Pindyck, RS (1994) Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Driscoll, JC and Holden, S (2014) Behavioral economics and macroeconomic models. Journal of Macroeconomics 41: 133147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drury, C, Braund, S, Osborne, P, et al. (1992) A Survey of Management Account Practices in UK Manufacturing Companies. Technical report, Research Report. London.Google Scholar
Dudley, CL (1972) A note on reinvestment assumptions in choosing between net present value and internal rate of return. Journal of Finance 27(4): 907915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, GW and Honkapohja, S (2001) Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farmer, REA and Guo, J-T (1994) Real business cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis. Journal of Economic Theory 63: 4273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felipe, J and McCombie, JSL (2014) The aggregate production function: not even wrong. Review of Political Economy 26(1): 6084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, FM (1984) The misuse of accounting rates of return: reply. American Economic Review 74(3): 509517.Google Scholar
Fisher, FM and McGowan, JJ (1983) On the misuse of accounting rates of return to infer monopoly profits. American Economic Review 73(1): 8297.Google Scholar
Frederick, S, Loewenstein, G and O’Donoghue, T (2002) Time discounting: a critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40(2): 351401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabaix, X (2020) A behavioral new Keynesian model. American Economic Review 110(8): 22712327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, G and Brighton, H (2009) Homo heuristicus: why biased minds make better inferences. Topics in Cognitive Science 1: 107143.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gigerenzer, G, Todd, PM and ABC Research Group (1999) Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gordon, MJ (1955) The payoff period and the rate of profit. Journal of Business 28(4): 253260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gronchi, S (1986) On investment criteria based on the internal rate of return. Oxford Economic Papers (New Series) 38(1): 174180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R and Jorgenson, D (1967) Tax policy and investment behavior American Economic Review 57(3): 319414.Google Scholar
Harcourt, GC (1965) The accountant in a golden age. Oxford Economic Papers 17(1): 6680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harcourt, GC (1968) Investment decision criteria, investment incentives and the choice of technique. Economic Journal 78(309): 7795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harcourt, GC (1969) Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital. Journal of Economic Literature 7(2): 369405.Google Scholar
Harcourt, GC (1972) Some Cambridge Controversies in the Theory of Capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, C and Laibson, D (2001) Dynamic choices of hyperbolic consumers. Econometrica 69(4): 935957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayashi, F (1982) Tobin’s marginal q and average q: a neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50(1): 213224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howitt, P and McAfee, RP (1992) Animal spirits. American Economic Review 82(3): 493507.Google Scholar
Jorgenson, DW (1963) Capital theory and investment behaviour. American Economic Review 53(2): 247259.Google Scholar
Jorgenson, DW (1971) Econometric studies of investment behavior: a survey. Journal of Economic Literature 9(4): 11111147.Google Scholar
Jorgenson, DW (1996) Investment: Volume I – Capital Theory and Investment Behavior. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Junankar, PN (1972) Investment: Theories and Evidence. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D and Tversky, A (1982) Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D and Tversky, A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2): 263292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katona, G (1946) Psychological analysis of business decisions and expectations. American Economic Review 36(1): 4462.Google Scholar
Kay, JA (1976) Accountants, too, could be happy in a Golden Age: the accountant’s rate of profit and the internal rate of return. Oxford Economic Papers 28(3): 447460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, JM (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Laibson, D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 443478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meeks, JG (1991) Keynes on the rationality of decision procedures under uncertainty: the investment decision. In: Meeks, JG (ed) Thoughtful Economic Man. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 126143.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, T and Rabin, M (1999) Doing it now or later. American Economic Review 89(1): 103124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donoghue, T and Rabin, M (2001) Choice and procrastination. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(1): 121160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donoghue, T and Rabin, M (2015) Present bias: lessons learned and to be learned. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 105(2): 273279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panagiotidis, T and Printzis, P (2021) Investment and uncertainty: are large firms different from small ones? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 184: 302317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pawlak, M and Zarzecki, D (2020) Investment appraisal practice in the European Union countries. European Research Studies 23(2): 687699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pindyck, RS (1991) Irreversibility, uncertainty and investment. Journal of Economic Literature 29(3): 11101148.Google Scholar
Ramsey, JB (1970) The marginal efficiency of capital, the internal rate of return and net present value: an analysis of investment criteria. Journal of Political Economy 78(5): 10171027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, J (1953–54) The production function and the theory of capital. Review of Economic Studies 21(2): 81106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sangster, A (1993) Capital investment appraisal techniques: a survey of current usage. Journal of Business Finance Accounting 20(3): 307332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarnat, M and Levy, H (1969) The relationship of rules of thumb to the internal rate of return: a restatement and generalisation. Journal of Finance 24(3): 479490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, HA (1955) A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69(1): 99118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, HA (1979) From substantive to procedural rationality. In: Hahn, FH and Hollis, M (eds) Philosophy and Economic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press, 6586.Google Scholar
Strotz, RH (1955) Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. The Review of Economic Studies 23(3): 165180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A and Kahneman, D (1974) Judgement under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185: 11241131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wright, FK (1978) Accounting rate of profit and internal rate of return. Oxford Economic Papers 30(3): 464468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar