Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-qxsvm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-27T07:19:29.876Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Consumption Smoothing in the Working-Class Households of Interwar Japan

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 February 2024

Kota Ogasawara*
Affiliation:
Associate Professor, Tokyo Institute of Technology - Department of Industrial Engineering and Economics, 2-12-1, Ookayama, Meguro-ku, Tokyo 152-8550, Japan.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

I analyze factory worker households in the early 1920s in Osaka to examine idiosyncratic income shocks and consumption. Using the household-level monthly panel dataset, I find that while households could not fully cope with idiosyncratic income shocks at that time, they mitigated fluctuations in indispensable consumption during economic hardship. In terms of risk-coping mechanisms, I find suggestive evidence that savings institutions helped mitigate vulnerabilities and that both using borrowing institutions and adjusting labor supply served as risk-coping strategies among households with less savings.

Type
Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

The insurance contracts offered through market and nonmarket mechanisms are important strategies for households to smooth their consumption in the face of idiosyncratic shocks. A collapse of consumption smoothing impedes human capital accumulation and the demographic structure itself, especially in developing economies (Foster Reference Foster1995; Rose Reference Rose1999; Gertler and Gruber Reference Gertler and Gruber2002; Dercon and Krishnan Reference Dercon and Krishnan2002). Therefore, households’ risk-coping behavior has been widely studied ever since a series of pioneering studies provided a systematic empirical design to test consumption smoothing (Rosenzweig Reference Rosenzweig1988; Mace Reference Mace1991; Cochrane Reference Cochrane1991).Footnote 1

In the past, risk-sharing institutions and self-insurance behavior also played an important role in allowing working-class households to cope with idiosyncratic shocks during periods of economic development.Footnote 2 This study systematically investigates the risk-coping behavior of working-class urban households. To do so, I digitize a detailed monthly longitudinal budget survey on factory worker households conducted after WWI in Osaka, the second largest city in Japan.Footnote 3 Utilizing an empirical design that exploits the within variations in the households’ consumption and income, I estimate the income elasticity to determine the extent of consumption insurance. The result indicates that the factory worker households could not fully deal with idiosyncratic shocks. Their income elasticity of total consumption expenditure is found to be comparable to that of urban households in developing countries at the same development stage. Nonetheless, the income elasticities of consumption by subcategory suggest that they might have mitigated the fluctuations in indispensable consumption to some degree. While the elasticities for luxury categories such as furniture, clothes, and entertainment expenses were greater, payments for a few indispensable categories such as food and housing were clearly inelastic. I also provided evidence suggesting that savings institutions helped mitigate idiosyncratic shocks. The households precautionarily saved the surplus built up and relied more on withdrawals from savings than borrowing when they faced the shocks. Temporary income from borrowing, particularly from pawnshops, as well as from the additional labor supply of the wife and child had also played a role among relatively vulnerable households.

This current study contributes to the literature in the following two ways. First, it contributes to the historical literature by adopting a systematic empirical design to test risk-sharing, which can be used in future economic history studies. Different types of analytical specifications have thus far been applied in the field of economic history, which makes comparing the degrees of risk sharing in different countries and eras complicated. In the current study, I employ a standardized empirical design to test risk-sharing (Cochrane Reference Cochrane1991) and compare the estimated income elasticities with those in modern developing societies.Footnote 4 The degree of consumption smoothing can reflect the maturity of insurance markets in a given economy (Dercon Reference Dercon2004). Therefore, applying this approach to other historical panel datasets will offer comparable estimates for a diverse range of economies.

Second, the current study uses a household-level monthly expenditure panel dataset. Since the concept of consumption smoothing pertains to the dynamics of household behavior over time, panel data on household budgets are preferable to test households’ smoothing behavior (Mace Reference Mace1991). However, most previous economic history studies have used cross-sectional data rather than panel data.Footnote 5 To bridge this gap, I use monthly variations in the household budget to investigate risk-coping behavior among working-class households. Relatedly, Japan is a suitable country for investigating risk-coping behavior for the following reasons. While national health insurance schemes expanded in many European countries between the end of the nineteenth century and the early twentieth century, Japan did not establish such a scheme until the mid-twentieth century (Bowblis Reference Bowblis2010). In addition, while the prevailing fragile labor contracts resulted in high turnover rates among factory workers, the unemployment insurance bill was not passed until the late twentieth century. Therefore, idiosyncratic income shocks cannot be compensated by public insurance schemes. This feature of prewar Japan offers an ideal environment for studying consumption-smoothing responses to idiosyncratic income shocks.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The second section briefly reviews the historical context and explains the risk-coping devices. The third section introduces the data used and discusses the sample characteristics. The fourth section empirically analyzes consumption smoothing, and the fifth section assesses risk-coping mechanisms. The final section concludes.

BACKGROUND

The Nature of Risk

In early twentieth-century Japan, employment contracts were typically fragile and stipulated no fixed term of employment; thus, the labor mobility of factory workers, comprising not only unskilled workers but also skilled workers, was extremely high (Moriguchi Reference Moriguchi2000). After WWI, large companies began to introduce comprehensive corporate welfare programs for factory workers to accumulate firm-specific human capital, and the Retirement Allowance Fund Law of 1936, which obligated employers to set up a retirement allowance fund for their employees, complemented these enterprise-based welfare programs (Moriguchi Reference Moriguchi2003). As a result, the average annual turnover rates of large companies began to decline after the war and fell to below 10 percent in the late 1920s (Hyodo Reference Hyodo1971).

However, the factory workers employed by such large companies comprised only about 20 percent of all production workers in the late 1920s (Moriguchi Reference Moriguchi2003, p. 644). Additionally, the average annual turnover rate of small and medium-sized enterprises was still approximately 30 percent (Hyodo Reference Hyodo1971; Taira Reference Taira1970). Therefore, except for a few favored workers among large companies, worker uncertainty in the labor market was high in interwar Japan, a period in which no comprehensive social security system had yet been established (Odaka Reference Odaka, Okazaki and Okuno-Fujiwara1999).Footnote 6

In addition to unemployment, sickness and injury could be another source of uncertainty for workers. The Factory Act of 1916 included an article setting an allowance for workers taking medical leave. In reality, however, most of the factories subject to the Act did not fully compensate workers who took medical leave.Footnote 7 Moreover, because the Act applied only to factories with 15 or more workers, workers in many small factories were entirely neglected.Footnote 8 Thus, sicknesses and injuries might have caused a certain reduction in factory workers’ incomes.

Despite these uncertainties, Japan’s economic growth remained stable during the interwar period (Nakamura Reference Nakamura1981). Inequality among members of the working class, measured in terms of the Gini coefficient, decreased between the early 1920s and early 1930s (Yazawa Reference Yazawa2004; Bassino 2006). Consequently, representative measures of human and physical capital accumulation, such as average years of education and children’s height, climbed steadily during this period.Footnote 9 These developmental outcomes suggest that working-class households might have coped with the risks to a certain extent.

Risk-Coping Devices

SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS

Precautionary savings are an important primary risk-coping device (Deaton Reference Deaton1991; Carroll Reference Carroll1997; Carroll, Dynan, and Krane Reference Carroll, Dynan and Krane2003). In prewar Japan, postal savings (yūbin chokin) and savings banks (chochiku ginkō) were widely used saving institutions around 1920 (Okazaki Reference Okazaki and Saito2002; Tanaka Reference Tanaka2012). In Osaka city, there were 117 postal savings offices and 55 savings banks in 1920. The number of people with postal savings and savings bank accounts was reported to be 725,642 and 1,648,150, respectively, accounting for approximately 60 percent and 130 percent of the number of citizens measured in the census.Footnote 10 Although the statistics must double count people having multiple accounts, they suggest that a large proportion of workers had savings accounts. Average savings per manufacturing worker were roughly 50 yen and 35 yen in postal savings and savings banks in 1920, respectively, approximately equivalent to 30–50 percent of the average monthly income of urban factory workers.Footnote 11 This implies that, despite having only small amounts of savings, factory workers might have drawn on their savings in the event of economic hardship, as suggested by James and Suto (Reference James and Suto2011).Footnote 12

Another type of savings institution was a mutual loan association (mujin), in which members deposited a fixed amount of money into a unit and withdrew it according to certain association rules. However, the association distributed deposits to members using either lotteries or bidding. This means that members could not withdraw the right deposits at the right time. In addition, a large deposit per unit (usually 100–300 yen) meant most members of mujin were probably owners of small businesses, such as merchants.Footnote 13 Moreover, less than 2 percent of the working population in Osaka in 1915 invested money in this way (Osaka City Office 1934, p. 251). In this light, unlike postal savings and savings banks, mutual loan associations were not useful risk-coping devices for factory workers, a large and growing proportion of the urban population.

LENDING INSTITUTIONS

Urban working-class households in prewar Japan could access a few lending institutions.Footnote 14 Among these, pawnshops (shichiya) were the most popular lending institutions, especially among factory workers.Footnote 15 Shibuya, Suzuki, and Ishiyama (Reference Shibuya, Suzuki and Ishiyama1982) argued that factory workers were the most frequent users of pawnshops in cities for a few main reasons (pp. 328–338). First, pawnshops were easier to access than other lending institutions because lenders did not need to check the credit of borrowers. Furthermore, since inexpensive clothes were the most common pawns at that time, workers could borrow money without the risk of falling into heavy debt. Second, the interest rates at pawnshops were relatively low, as they were regulated by the Pawnbroker Regulation Act of 1895. Accordingly, the redemption rate was substantially high: approximately nine out of 10 borrowers could repay their loans within the short term, which enabled them to minimize their interest payments. Finally, physical accessibility was sufficiently high because the number of pawnshops was substantially greater than that of other lending institutions, such as mutual loan associations and usuries.Footnote 16

In Osaka city, pawnshops were regarded as a major lending institution among factory workers (Osaka City Office 1920, p. 153). Of the 983 pawn shops in October 1919, factory workers accounted for 60 percent of all users and 43 percent of the borrowing.Footnote 17 More than 80 percent of those loans were from clothes and the redemption rate was approximately 95 percent.Footnote 18 The average amount borrowed by factory workers per event was 11 yen, accounting for roughly 10 percent of the mean monthly income of factory workers at that time. These amounts suggest that those households used pawnshops to smooth their consumption when they faced idiosyncratic shocks rather than to buy luxury goods or invest, which would require much higher borrowing.

Money lenders (kinsen kashitsuke gyō) also existed in this period (Osaka City Office 1934, pp. 182–183). In 1926, there were 196 money lenders, but the number of lending events per lender was only 118, substantially smaller than that of pawnshops (i.e., approximately 4,000 pawns per shop in the same year). Furthermore, while the average loan amount per pawn was usually 5–10 yen in pawnshops, this figure was substantially large for money lenders at slightly under 300 yen, approximately three times the average monthly household income of factory workers.Footnote 19 This means that money lenders were predominantly used by business owners, such as the owners of small enterprises, merchants, and landowners (Shibuya Reference Shibuya2000, pp. 184, 248). Indeed, by the early 1920s, most money lenders had become usuries (kōrigashi).Footnote 20 Since usuries expected to siphon money from those guarantors rather than the borrowers themselves, three or more joint guarantors with credibility were required to access those lenders. This feature made it harder for the working class to use usuries.

Finally, the main customers of ordinary banks and credit unions (shinyō kumiai) at that time were companies, including other banks. In 1920, there were 24 ordinary banks, with an average loan amount of approximately 27 thousand yen; further, a large part of their collateral was stock certificates.Footnote 21 Although the 24 credit unions might have been accessible to workers, their 4,451 members accounted for only 0.4 percent of the working population in Osaka city in 1926 (Osaka City Office 1934, p. 276).

INFORMAL INSURANCE PROVIDED BY NETWORKS

Evidence on rural economies in today’s developing countries has highlighted the importance of informal networks (e.g., gifts from friends and family) for coping with idiosyncratic shocks because formal insurance markets rarely exist in village economies (Rosenzweig Reference Rosenzweig1988).Footnote 22 Systematic statistics on gifts from personal networks in prewar Japan are unavailable. However, a survey of 185 factory worker households in Tokyo city and surrounding suburban municipalities in November 1922 found that the average monthly income from personal networks was 2.9 yen, accounting for 2.8 percent of total monthly income (Social Affairs Division 1925, pp. 58–59).Footnote 23 This suggests that using temporary income from personal networks might have been a useful strategy for urban factory worker households.

LABOR SUPPLY ADJUSTMENTS

The traditional and still prevalent view of the labor supply among urban working-class households in prewar Japan is the male breadwinner model. In that period, the wife’s elasticity of labor supply was considerably low, and children rarely worked compared with the extensive use of child labor during the Industrial Revolution in Europe (Saito Reference Saito1995, Reference Saito1996; Chimoto Reference Chimoto2012). However, a cross-sectional analysis of poor households in Tokyo found a negative correlation between the income of the household head and the working status of children aged 15 years and older (Yazawa Reference Yazawa2004, p. 315). Although this is a suggestive result, one must be careful about the fact that all existing studies have relied on cross-sectional data, meaning that the dynamic compensating responses to idiosyncratic shocks to the household head’s earnings have not yet been investigated. Considering this, I quantify the labor supply of the wife and children in response to shocks to the income of the household head in the fifth section.

To summarize, working-class households were able to use formal and informal risk-coping strategies. Although informal insurance via private networks is not documented as a separate income category, I consider three categories (i.e., withdrawals and gifts, borrowing, and labor supply adjustments) when I evaluate those strategies in the fifth section. I do so using the best available household-level longitudinal budget dataset, which I will introduce in the following section.

DATA

The Sample

I compiled the data on the monthly budget of working-class households between July 1919 and July 1920 from the Report of Labor Research (RLR).Footnote 24 In this survey, the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka investigated the monthly income and expenditure of 411 wage-earning and salaried workers in the Osaka city area. Although the details of the sampling method were not recorded, as is the case with other historical household survey datasets, households were selected through a labor union or directly at factories. To investigate the features of the sample, I compare the occupations among household heads within RLR households with statistics obtained from the national population census. As shown in Column (1) of Panel A in Table 1, only 14 percent of men in the workforce across Osaka prefecture worked in the agricultural sector, compared with the national figure of 46 percent. Column (2) also indicates that 90 percent of working men in Osaka city worked in the manufacturing, commerce, and transportation industries, compared with the national figure of 40 percent.Footnote 25 This reflects that Osaka was an industrialized city and a nice setting to study the consumption decisions of industrial workers. In the RLR dataset, information on the household head’s occupation can be obtained for 406 of the 411 households. Column (3) shows that these heads mainly worked in the manufacturing industry; 83 percent were factory workers.

Table 1 SAMPLE CHARACTERISTICS: COMPARING THE RLR SAMPLE WITH THE CENSUS

Notes: Panel A summarizes the industrial structures measured in the 1920 population census and RLR households. Occupations are classified using the industrial classification of the first population census conducted in 1920. The figures in Column (3) are based on information on the 406 RLR household heads’ occupations. The five household heads whose occupations are classified as “unknown” are not included. Panel B sorts the adult male factory workers in Osaka city in 1920 and heads of the 237 RLR households by the five sectors in the manufacturing industry. Column (1) lists the percentage share of adult male factory workers in each sector. Column (2) shows the mean monthly income of adult male factory workers. The monthly income is calculated as the monthly earnings plus the monthly equivalent bonus. See Online Appendix B.2 for the finer details. Column (3) lists the percentage share of the household heads in each sector. The sample excludes observations with no identifiable sector. Column (4) shows the mean value of the household head’s monthly income.

Sources: Figures for the RLR households are calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920). Industrial structures in Panel A are from the Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet (1928, pp. 8–11) and (1929a, pp. 84–85, 108–109). The occupational structure and earnings in Panel B are from Osaka City Office (1921, pp. 8(44)–8(45); 1922, pp. 8(46)–8(47)).

Considering this feature of sampling, the current study targets only factory-worker households. I first extracted households whose heads worked in factories during the survey period.Footnote 26 Correspondingly, 335 of the original 411 households remain. I then excluded the 18 households lacking information on monthly income or family structure. Further, 78 households were dropped because they were observed for only one month during the survey period. Finally, two households were dropped on account of having reported unrealistic income and expenditure values (i.e., exceeding 500 yen per month). Accordingly, data on 237 factory-worker households were used in the empirical analyses.Footnote 27

The mean household size of the RLR sample is 4.00, whereas that of the factory worker households in the manufacturing industry of Osaka city taken from the population census is 3.99. Hence, my sample does not contain outliers or otherwise unusual household size values. Column (1) in Panel B of Table 1 shows the percentage share of adult male factory workers in each manufacturing sector in Osaka city in 1920, and Column (3) lists the percentage share among RLR household heads. The heads are more likely to work in the machine sector than in other sectors, consistent with the descriptions in the original RLR document. Column (2) lists the average monthly income of adult male factory workers,Footnote 28 whereas Column (4) lists the average monthly income of the household heads in the RLR sample. Clearly, the average monthly income of adult males is close to the monthly income of the RLR heads in each sector.Footnote 29 In addition, the average monthly incomes of adult males and the monthly incomes of the heads show similar figures across different sectors. Both support the evidence that the disproportion in the occupation structure in the RLR sample does not lead to an upward income bias and that the RLR sample approximates the average factory worker in the manufacturing sector in Osaka city.Footnote 30 Even if there are some differences with other factory workers, or with the laboring population remain, the RLR sample provides a rare opportunity to study consumption and risk-coping strategies in an industrializing economy.Footnote 31

Variables

The key data used in this study are monthly household consumption and income. The RLR reports 10 consumption subcategories: food, housing, utilities, furniture, clothes, education, medical, entertainment, transportation, and miscellaneous. These consumption variables are mainly used to estimate the income elasticities in the fourth section. Other expenditures are divided into tax payments, liquidation of loans, and deposits into savings. On the contrary, income is divided into six categories: head, wife, child, other,Footnote 32 borrowing, and miscellaneous. The borrowing category includes money from lending institutions, while the miscellaneous category includes money from savings withdrawals and gifts (Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka Reference Tada1921, pp. 22–27). Therefore, I rename the miscellaneous category, calling it withdrawals and gifts (not divisible). These income variables are used in the mechanism analysis in the fifth section.

The quality of the data is considered to be sufficiently high to conduct quantitative analyses. The investigators visited all households and instructed them all once or twice per month to check the account books and maintain the quality of the survey (Tada Reference Tada1991a, pp. 11–12). Hence, lazy respondents were unlikely to simply copy and paste entries rather than record each purchase. If this sort of repetition did occur, however, the reported expenses would take the same values during the survey period. To test this potential issue, I check whether the first-differenced values of food expenses have sufficient variation for all the households. The food category is the most useful category for this exercise because it requires careful bookkeeping to sort many grocery items; further, expenditure on food has the largest share of the total as well as large variations due to seasonality and price changes.Footnote 33

I find that the observations of three households take the same values across two consecutive months, accounting for only 0.16 percent of all observations. This supports the evidence that measures of consumption are less likely to contain measurement errors.

Trends

Figure 1a illustrates the rising monthly income and expenditure during the sample period. These trends are consistent with the increasing living standards after WWI (Nakamura and Odaka Reference Nakamura, Odaka, Nakamura and Odaka1989, pp. 36–37). One may wonder whether this upward trend in income suggests that households had more savings or less debt and thus were better able to deal with shocks. However, moderate inflation during the sample period partially canceled out the benefit of the upward trend.Footnote 34 Moreover, Figure 1a indicates that both income and expenditure decreased after April 1920. This trend reflects the recession that followed the war after March 1920 in Japan (Takeda Reference Takeda, Kanji, Akira and Haruhito2002, pp. 9–11). Therefore, my sample period includes expansions and recessions, which should offer an ideal setting within which to analyze the risk-coping behavior of households.

Figure 1 MONTHLY INCOME AND EXPENDITURE BETWEEN JUNE 1919 AND JUNE 1920

Notes: Monthly income and expenditure are illustrated in Figure 1a. The difference between monthly income and monthly expenditure is shown in Figure 1b.

Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

Next, I examine the seasonality and variation of idiosyncratic shocks. Figure 1b shows monthly income minus expenditure. Seasonality is clearly observed in December 1919 and January 1920: both income and expenditure increase steeply in December, when bonuses have been paid (Tada Reference Tada1991b, p. 9).Footnote 35 Although the differences between income and expenditure were largely positive but fluctuating, this difference became statistically significant and negative in January because labor income and consumption expenditure typically increase in December to prepare for New Year events and traditions. Workers also took New Year holidays, which could have reduced their earnings. Figure 2 illustrates the box-and-whisker plots of the residuals from the regression of the first-differences in household income on the first-differences in aggregate income, approximating the variations in idiosyncratic shocks during the sample period.Footnote 36 In the figure, the idiosyncratic shocks were clearer in those months in which the net income (i.e., income minus expenditure) exhibited large fluctuations (Figure 1b). Further, the shocks were relatively large in March and April, that is, soon after the recession began.

Figure 2 VARIATIONS IN IDIOSYNCRATIC SHOCKS (IN YEN)

Notes: This figure shows the box-and-whisker plot of the residuals from the regression of the first-difference in income on the first-difference in aggregate income. The 25th, 50th, and 75th percentiles are the bottom, middle (white line), and top of the box, respectively. The caps at the ends of the whiskers show the lower and upper adjacent values, respectively.

Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING

Estimation Strategy

I begin my analysis by investigating whether risk was shared and which categories of consumption were robust to shocks. Following Cochrane (Reference Cochrane1991) and Ravallion and Chaudhuri (Reference Ravallion and Chaudhuri1997), the empirical specification for household i in time t can be characterized as follows:

(1) $${\rm{log}}\;{c_{i,t}} = \theta {\rm{log}}\;{y_{i,t}} + x_{i,g,t}^\prime \psi {\rm{ + }}{\mu _{\rm{i}}}{\rm{ + }}{\phi _{\rm{t}}}{\rm{ + }}{u_{{\rm{i}},{\rm{t}}}},$$

where c i,t is consumption, y i,t is disposable income, µ i is the household fixed effect, φ t is the month-year fixed effect, and u i,t is a random error term.Footnote 37 Household-specific unobservables, such as permanent income and time-constant preferences, are captured by the household fixed effect. In addition, macroeconomic shocks and trends, including seasonality, are controlled for using the month-year fixed effect. Evidence suggests that the households had not lost their heads but had maintained their size during the sample periods. This means that unobservable preference shifts in household consumption do not disturb my results (see Online Appendix C.1 for details).Footnote 38 To be conservative, however, I consider the family size variables interacted with the quarter dummies to control for the potential preference shifts: $${x_{i,{g_t}}}$$ is a vector of the controls, where $${g_t} \in \left\{ {1,{\rm{\;}}2,{\rm{\;}}3,{\rm{\;}}4} \right\}$$ is the group membership variable indicating the quarters. Note that the family size controls are interacted with the quarter dummies because these variables are surveyed once in the initial period (Panels A and C of Table 2 show the summary statistics).Footnote 39 If idiosyncratic income shocks are perfectly insured, the coefficient on the change in the growth rate of individual income must be zero. Therefore, the income elasticity captured as the estimate of θ ranges from zero (full insurance) to one (absence of insurance).

Table 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS: SAMPLE OF RLR HOUSEHOLDS

Notes: Panel A: Summary statistics for all 237 RLR households. Disposable income is income excluding tax payments. Panel B: Summary statistics for the 202 households that received any income from withdrawals and gifts are listed in Panel B-1. The summary statistics for the 65 households that received any income from borrowing are listed in Panel B-2. Disposable income is income excluding tax payments, temporary income from borrowing, and withdrawals and gifts. Summary statistics for the 194 households with three or more family members (i.e., households with children) are listed in Panel B-3. Panel C: Summary statistics of the family size control variables for all 237 RLR households are listed. The group of children aged 0–5 (%) is used as the reference group in the regression analysis.

Sources: Calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

Results

To gain some insights on consumption smoothing, I begin by investigating the raw relationships between the changes in consumption and income. Online Appendix Figures B.2a and B.2b show the distributions of the log-differences in monthly disposable income and expenditure, respectively. Changes in the log of disposable income range from approximately –2.5 to 2.0, whereas changes in the log of expenditure range from approximately –1.5 to 1.5. This finding suggests that income shocks are buffered to some degree. An important fact here is that these idiosyncratic shocks are short-run (temporary) rather than long-run (persistent). Indeed, most households that faced declining disposable income recovered the next month, suggesting that these shocks are caused by temporary sickness and/or layoffs as opposed to chronic diseases or long-term unemployment. This feature of idiosyncratic shocks helps me examine the short-run responses of households.Footnote 40 Online Appendix Figure B.2c describes the relationship between the log-differences in monthly expenditure and disposable income, which shows a positive linear relationship. To delve into this relationship, Figure 3 decomposes total expenditure into the 10 subcategories in Panel A in Table 2, suggesting similar positive relationships between changes in income and most of those subcategories. However, the relationships are rather unclear for housing and education expenditure, implying that some subcategories are less prone to being affected by income shocks.

Figure 3 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE CHANGES IN DISPOSABLE INCOME AND EXPENDITURE

Notes: The relationship between the changes in disposable income and expenditure for the 10 subcategories (Panel A of Table 2) is described in the figures. For comparability, the minimum and maximum values of the y-axis are fixed at –7.0 and 7.0, respectively.

Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

Panel A of Table 3 presents the results for Equation (1). For the total consumption category, I find that the estimated coefficient is 0.39 and is statistically significantly different from zero. This implies that a one percent decrease in income results in a 0.39 percent decrease in consumption. Thus, this result suggests that the risks were not perfectly insured, but they might have been partially mitigated. While comparable estimates for urban working-class households in developing economies are scarce, Townsend (Reference Townsend1995) estimated an income elasticity of approximately 0.4 in Bangkok in Thailand between 1975 and 1990. Given that the average standard of living was in a similar range in both cases, this similarity is considered to be plausible.Footnote 41 By contrast, Townsend (Reference Townsend1994) found much smaller estimates (less than 0.14) in Indian villages between 1975 and 1984. Skoufias and Quisumbing (Reference Skoufias and Quisumbing2005) also reported that the income elasticities of consumption were in a similar range in rural areas of Bangladesh, Ethiopia, and Mali in the 1990s (less than 0.15).Footnote 42 This implies that households in village economies are more likely to have access to informal insurance provided by networks, presumably through their familial relationships, than urban households.Footnote 43 However, directly comparing the income elasticity of urban economies with that of rural economies is practically difficult because village households can use self-consumption to mitigate idiosyncratic shocks, which tend to cause a downward bias in consumption. Ravallion and Chaudhuri (Reference Ravallion and Chaudhuri1997) present much greater estimates (approximately 0.5) by revising the bias in Townsend’s (1994) estimates due to such measurement errors in consumption data. This suggests that better access to savings and lending institutions, which is difficult for village households, can be important for mitigating idiosyncratic shocks. While the urban-to-rural comparison of income elasticities is beyond the scope of this study, this debate indicates that research is required to understand risk-sharing behavior in developing economies. In this light, the result provides the first benchmark estimate of income elasticity for any working-class household in the early phase of industrialization.

Table 3 RESULTS OF ESTIMATING INCOME ELASTICITIES

* = Signficant at the 10 percent level.

** = Signficant at the 5 percent level.

*** = Signficant at the 1 percent level.

Notes: This table shows the results of Equation (1): the regressions of the 11 measures of log-transformed consumption on log-transformed disposable income as well as on the family size controls, household fixed effects, and month-year fixed effects. The family size controls are interacted with the quarter dummies. The estimated coefficients on log-transformed disposable income are listed in the second column (Coef.). Panel A reports the estimates from the regressions using 237 households from June 1919 to June 1920. Panel B-1 reports the estimates from the regression using the 86 households with children aged 6–12 from June 1919 to June 1920. Panels B-2 and B-3 report the estimates from the regressions using the 82 households with children aged 6–12 from June 1919 to March 1920 and June 1919 to March 1920, excluding August 1919, respectively. Standard errors in brackets are clustered at the household level.

Sources: Calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

The estimates of the 10 subcategories in Panel A of Table 3 are statistically significantly positive in most cases. Overall, the elasticities are greater for “luxury” categories such as furniture (0.66), clothes (0.68), and entertainment expenses (0.55). On the contrary, they are relatively small for the other subcategories; those for food, housing, education, medical expenses, and transportation are smaller than the elasticity for total consumption (0.39). Specifically, as I show in a descriptive manner in Figure 3, the estimates of housing and education are particularly inelastic and even statistically insignificant at the critical level of 5 percent. The result for housing may not be surprising given that rent needs to be paid regardless of fluctuations. Indeed, since most landlords of rental houses in cities leased land from landowners, they should have paid ground rent (Kato Reference Kato1990, pp. 79–80). This feature led to rental trouble for the working class around 1920, including evictions (Ono Reference Ono1999, pp. 48–49).

By contrast, the result for education may need further clarification. I first trim the sample to the 86 households that have children aged 6–12. As Panel B-1 of Table 3 shows, the estimate for education is close to zero and statistically insignificant. Next, I remove the potential impacts of graduation on education expenditure. Because Japan’s academic year starts in April and ends in March, some children might have graduated from school at the end of March 1920, which would disrupt education expenditure. To address this issue, I run a regression using an alternative cut-off period between June 1919 and March 1920, as shown in Panel B-2 of Table 3. In the same way, I exclude August 1919 to deal with potential fluctuations due to the summer holiday, as shown in Panel B-3 of Table 3. The results remain unchanged, suggesting that graduation and open seasonality do not affect the findings.

Mean monthly education expenses per child among RLR households with children aged 6–12 are 0.44 yen, considerably lower than other expenses such as clothes, whose per-capita mean is 1.94 yen in those households. After the Order of Primary School (shōgakkō rei) was revised in 1900, primary school was regarded as compulsory education, and tuition fees declined throughout the early twentieth century (Hijikata Reference Hijikata2002). Indeed, average tuition spending was only 0.18 yen per month in Osaka city in 1920, accounting for less than 0.2 percent of the average monthly income of the households analyzed.Footnote 44 Consequently, withdrawals for economic reasons rarely occurred by the 1920s (Hijikata Reference Hijikata2002, p. 32).Footnote 45 This institutional advantage may explain my results.Footnote 46 However, my result for education may be influenced by the data frequency: one can expect less insurance at the monthly level than annually because the consumption of some goods can be delayed in the short term (Nelson Reference Nelson1994). In this light, education could be more of a long-term decision for parents. Thus, one must be careful in concluding that RLR households kept children in education despite idiosyncratic shocks.

Nakagawa (Reference Nakagawa1985) contended that urban factory worker households in the early twentieth century kept spending on miscellaneous payments other than food to maintain their household (p. 379). His argument is based on comparing expenditures on certain consumption categories calculated from several survey reports measured in different years. Despite the methodological differences, my results for food and housing expenses are consistent with his argument. Importantly, I also find that the income elasticities are positive in most consumption subcategories and that their magnitudes vary by category: payments for indispensable items such as food and housing are more likely to be inelastic than those for luxury items such as clothes and furniture.Footnote 47

RISK-COPING STRATEGIES

The foregoing results provide suggestive evidence that the factory worker households smoothed their consumption to some degree. In this section, I investigate whether temporary sources of income such as savings and borrowing served to share risk among households and whether adjusting labor supply helped them cope with shocks.

Savings and Borrowing

ESTIMATION STRATEGY

I derive the empirical specification to test risk-sharing strategies in the spirit of Fafchamps and Lund (Reference Fafchamps and Lund2003). The specification for household i at time t can be characterized as follows:

(2) $${r_{i,t}} = \kappa + \delta {\widetilde y_{i,t}} + x_{i,{g_t}}^{\rm{'}}\gamma + {\nu _i} + {\zeta _t} + {e_{i,t}}$$

Where $${\widetilde y_{i,t}}$$ is disposable income, $${x_{i,{g_t}}}$$ is the family size controls included in Equation (1), νi indicates the household fixed effect, $${\zeta _t}$$ indicates the month-year fixed effect, and ei,t is a random error term.Footnote 48 Since the household fixed effect absorbs variations in permanent income as well as the initial endowment of assets, disposable income $({\widetilde y_{i,t}})$ captures the idiosyncratic income shocks in the regression.

I use several income and expenditure categories for r i,t . First, temporary income from withdrawals and gifts is used to test the role of precautionary savings. I also use monthly deposits to savings to confirm the saving behavior of the households: the signs of the estimates for the withdrawals and gifts and for deposits to savings should be symmetric if the households had precautionarily saved their earnings during good times.Footnote 49 Second, I use temporary income from borrowing and liquidating loans to dually test the roles of lending institutions. One can expect the estimates to be almost symmetric. Finally, I use expenditures on clothes and furniture to test the potential role of pawnshops. Although the borrowing category is indivisible, pawnshops were the most popular lending institutions, and clothes were the dominant article for pawning. Hence, while the estimate for clothes could be sensitive to shocks, that for furniture, a placebo item, should be close to zero and statistically insignificant.

The analytical sample is trimmed to households that received income from either withdrawals and gifts or any borrowing during the sample period.Footnote 50 Panels B-1 and B-2 of Table 2 list the summary statistics.

RESULTS

Panels B-1 and B-2 of Table 2 indicate that households tended to rely more frequently on savings than borrowing (1,023 vs. 154 obs.). This suggests that households regard savings as the first line of defense and borrowing as the second line (Deaton Reference Deaton1991). Given this, I begin my analysis by estimating income elasticity for the savings categories.

Panel A of Table 4 presents the results. Columns (1) and (2) show the estimates for withdrawals and gifts. Columns (3) and (4) show the estimates for deposits to savings. The estimates in Columns (1) and (3) suggest that when households faced negative income shocks, withdrawals and gifts increased, whereas deposits to savings decreased.Footnote 51 To compare the estimate by addressing the attenuation effects induced by censoring, Columns (2) and (4) employ the fixed-effects Tobit model proposed by Honoré (Reference Honoré1992). As expected, the magnitudes become larger in both columns. The estimate for the withdrawals and gifts category is slightly higher than that for deposits to savings (0.46 vs. 0.32). Although inconclusive, as the former income category is indivisible, this margin might suggest the potential contribution of gifts from informal insurance provided by networks (Rosenzweig Reference Rosenzweig1988).

Table 4 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS

* = Signficant at the 10 percent level.

** = Signficant at the 5 percent level.

*** = Signficant at the 1 percent level.

Notes: The results from the fixed-effects Tobit model, as proposed by Honoré (Reference Honoré1992), are reported in Columns (2) and (4) in each panel. A quadratic loss function is applied for the estimation to ensure computational tractability. Robust standard errors are in brackets. Standard errors are clustered at the household level in the linear models. Panel A presents the results for the savings category: withdrawals and gifts (Columns (1) and (2)) and deposits to savings (Columns (3) and (4)). Panel B presents the results for the borrowing category: borrowing (Columns (1) and (2)) and liquidation of loans (Columns (3) and (4)). Panel C presents the results for expenditure on clothes (Columns (1) and (2)) and furniture (Columns (3) and (4)). All the regressions in each panel include the disposable income, family size controls, household fixed effects, and month-year fixed effects. The family size controls are interacted with the quarter dummies.

Sources: Calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

The estimate in Column (2) suggests that a one standard deviation decrease in disposable income increases temporary income from withdrawals and gifts by 16 yen, accounting for roughly 50 percent of the average savings in savings banks of manufacturing workers in Osaka at that time. This finding implies that while precautionary savings served as a primary risk-coping strategy among households, they might not have provided sufficient compensation when households faced a rare but extreme loss of income (e.g., a more than two standard deviation decrease). Despite this, the result for deposits to savings also evokes a serious attribute of urban factory worker households: they saved the surplus built up in good times to prepare for future risks. This finding is consistent with James and Suto’s (2011) historical view of frugal working-class households.

Panel B of Table 4 lists the estimates for the borrowing categories in the same column layout. Columns (1) and (3) suggest that households borrowed money when they faced negative income shocks, whereas they liquidated loans in good times. As expected, the magnitudes become much larger after addressing the censoring issues in Columns (2) and (4). To delve into the mechanism behind the roles of borrowing, I next examine the results for expenditure on luxury items listed in Panel C of Table 4: Columns (1) and (2) for clothes and Columns (3) and (4) for furniture. While the estimates for clothes are weakly statistically significantly positive, the estimates from the placebo test using expenditure on furniture are close to zero and statistically insignificant. This finding seems to be consistent with the historical fact that clothes were the most representative article for pawning at that time, whereas furniture was rarely used, suggesting a role for pawnshops in mitigating idiosyncratic income shocks. Fafchamps, Udry, and Czukas (Reference Fafchamps, Udry and Czukas1998) showed that the ownership of mobile assets such as livestock can be used to mitigate vulnerability to idiosyncratic income shocks in village economies. In this light, my result implies that urban factory worker households in prewar Japan owned clothes as real assets and bought some of those assets in good times, as suggested by Deaton (Reference Deaton1992).

The estimate in Column (2) of Panel B of Table 4 implies that a one standard deviation decrease in disposable income increases temporary income from borrowing by 14 yen. Similarly, the estimate in Column (4) indicates that a one standard deviation increase in disposable income increases liquidation by 12 yen. Given that the average amount borrowed by factory workers per event in pawnshops in Osaka city was 11 yen, these magnitudes are quite reasonable. In other words, urban factory worker households took out loans within their solvencies.

HETEROGENEOUS RESPONSES

These findings suggest that both precautionary savings and borrowing mitigated idiosyncratic income shocks. However, richer households with high precautionary savings may borrow less because they see consumption fluctuations with income as savings run out.Footnote 52 To test such potential heterogeneous responses with respect to borrowing, I stratify the sample based on the median of households’ mean savings expensesFootnote 53 and run regressions for each subsample using Equation (2).Footnote 54 To deal with the attenuations from censoring revealed in Table 4, I use the fixed-effects Tobit estimation in all the regressions.

Panel A of Table 5 presents the results. Columns (1) and (3) show the estimates for withdrawals and gifts for the subsamples below and above the median, respectively. The estimates are statistically significantly negative and have a similar range in both cases. Columns (2) and (4) list the estimates of income from borrowing for the subsamples in the same layout.Footnote 55 The estimate for the subsample with less savings is statistically significantly negative, whereas the estimate for the subsample with more savings is negative but statistically insignificant. The estimate in Column (2) is greater than that in Column (4) in an absolute sense.

Table 5 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS: HETEROGENEOUS RESPONSES

* = Signficant at the 10 percent level.

** = Signficant at the 5 percent level.

*** = Signficant at the 1 percent level.

Notes: The results from the fixed-effects Tobit model, as proposed by Honoré (Reference Honoré1992), are reported. A quadratic loss function is applied for the estimation to ensure computational tractability. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Panel A presents the results for the temporary income categories: Columns (1) and (3) for withdrawals and gifts and Columns (2) and (4) for borrowing. The analytical sample used in Panel A of Table 5 is stratified into two subsamples based on the median of households’ mean monthly deposits to savings: Columns (1) and (2) for households lower than or equal to the median (101 and 33 households for Columns (1) and (2), respectively) and Columns (3) and (4) for households higher than the median (101 and 32 households for Columns (3) and (4), respectively). Panel B presents the results for expenditure on clothes and furniture: Columns (1) and (3) for clothes and Columns (2) and (4) for furniture. The analytical sample used in Panel B of Table 5 is stratified into two subsamples by the median of households’ mean monthly income from borrowing: Columns (1) and (2) for the 31 households less than or equal to the median and Columns (3) and (4) for the 34 households more than the median. All the regressions in each panel include the disposable income, family size controls, household fixed effects, and month-year specific fixed effects. The family size controls are interacted with the quarter dummies.

Sources: Calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

Panel B of Table 5 assesses whether the results are consistent with the role of pawnshops in the same manner as in Panel C of Table 4. In this panel, I stratify the sample based on the median of households’ mean monthly income from borrowing. Columns (1) and (3) present the estimates for clothes for the subsamples below and above the median, respectively. Income elasticity is statistically significantly positive among households that borrowed more, suggesting they might have stored the clothes in good times. The estimate for households with less borrowing is higher, albeit statistically insignificant. Although this result may partially reflect the income effects for clothes, the large standard error implies that a subset of households in this subsample did not pawn clothes. The placebo results seem to support the potential mechanism via pawning, as shown in Panel C of Table 4, where the estimates for the furniture are closer to zero in both subsamples (Columns (2) and (4)).

These results provide suggestive evidence that, while households regarded savings as a primary risk-coping strategy, borrowing was another option for relatively vulnerable households with less precautionary savings.

Labor Supply Adjustments

The increased dependence on the household head’s earnings due to urbanization could increase demand for market purchases of insurance (di Matteo and Emery 2002). However, additional labor supply could be an alternative means of coping with income shocks (Horrell and Oxley Reference Horrell and Oxley2000; Moehling Reference Moehling2001). In the foregoing regressions, I included family structure variables to control for potential preference shifts and related labor supply adjustments. In this subsection, I explicitly test whether shocks to the income of the household head caused the labor supply to be adjusted.

To create a suitable empirical setting for the test, I trim the sample to households with three or more family members, leaving 194 households, including the head and both the wife and the child(ren). I regress either the wife’s or the child’s income on the income of the household head, family size controls, and household and month-year fixed effects.Footnote 56 As shown in Panel B-3 of Table 2, approximately 20 percent (347/1,627) and 15 percent (244/1,627) of the observations have positive values for the wife’s and child’s incomes, respectively. To deal with this censoring issue, I employ the fixed-effects Tobit estimation and run the wife’s and child’s income equations separately.Footnote 57

Panel A of Table 6 presents the results. Column (1) shows the negative but insignificant estimate for the wife’s income. Column (2) shows the statistically significantly negative estimate for the child’s income.Footnote 58 The percentage of working children indicates that this result should come from children aged 13 years and older (i.e., those who have left primary school).Footnote 59 This finding is consistent with the discussion in the fourth section about the low income elasticity for education expenses. In addition, it is in line with the findings from cross-sectional evidence of urban working-class households in prewar Japan exploiting the labor supply of children aged 15 years and older.

Table 6 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS: LABOR SUPPLY ADJUSTMENTS

* = Signficant at the 10 percent level.

** = Signficant at the 5 percent level.

*** = Signficant at the 1 percent level.

Notes: The results from the fixed-effects Tobit model, as proposed by Honoré (Reference Honoré1992), are reported. A quadratic loss function is applied for the estimation to ensure computational tractability. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Panel A shows the results for the 194 households with three or more family members. Panel B stratifies households based on the median of households’ mean monthly deposits to savings. Columns (1) and (2) show the results for the 97 households below the median and Columns (3) and (4) present the results for the 97 households above the median. All the regressions in each panel include the income of the household head, family size controls, household fixed effects, and month-year fixed effects. The family size controls are interacted with the quarter dummies.

Sources: Calculated by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (Reference Tada1919–1920).

However, my estimates from the subsamples stratified by the median of households’ mean deposits to savings show a different story. Panel B of Table 6 presents the results. Columns (1) and (2) show the results for the subsample below the median, and Columns (3) and (4) show those for the subsample above the median. Among the former, the estimate for the wife’s income is now statistically significantly negative (Column (1)), and that for the child’s income is higher (Column (2)). By contrast, the estimates are not statistically significant among households above the median (Columns (3) and (4)). Compared with the elasticities for savings and borrowing, which are approximately 0.5 and 0.8 (Columns (1) and (2) in Panel A of Table 5), the elasticities of the labor supply of the wife and child (approximately 0.2 and 0.6, respectively) are slightly lower, but still within a similar range. Therefore, adjusting labor supply could have been an important risk-coping strategy among households with less savings. Finally, I confirm that these results are robust to using an alternative definition of the shock variable, namely, an indicator variable for the negative shock on the income of the household head (Online Appendix C.2).

CONCLUSION

Using a systematic empirical design with a unique household-based monthly-level panel dataset, this study is the first to investigate historical consumption smoothing behavior among factory worker households in an industrial city in Japan. The income elasticity estimate of total consumption expenditure provides evidence that factory worker households in Osaka in the 1920s were as vulnerable to idiosyncratic shocks as urban households in the developing world at the same developmental stage, such as Bangkok during the 1970s and 1980s. The estimated elasticities of the consumption subcategories also provide suggestive evidence that while households at that time could not fully cope with idiosyncratic shocks, they mitigated the fluctuations in indispensable consumption. Indeed, the results of the mechanism analysis suggest that while households withdrew their savings as the first line of defense to deal with idiosyncratic income shocks, they saved the surplus in good times to prepare for future risks. Among households with less savings, borrowing, particularly from pawnshops, worked as a second line of defense. The additional labor supply of the wife and child in response to shocks to the income of the household head was also observed in relatively vulnerable households.

The risk-coping behavior among urban factory worker households in prewar Japan documented in this study indicates that they partially coped with idiosyncratic short-term income shocks using available sources of temporary income and adjusting labor supply. To delve into the efficiency of historical insurance markets, it is also valuable to investigate whether the long-term variation in income was insured during historical economic growth. As evidence from developed economies suggests that permanent shocks are far less insured than transitory shocks (Blundell, Pistaferri, and Preston Reference Blundell, Pistaferri and Preston2008), long-term shocks may rarely be insured in historical cases. Despite this, the analyses based on the low-frequency budget data should provide new findings on the long-run risk-coping behaviors of the past.

Although the potential role of informal insurance, such as gifts from relatives and insurance sold in the market, should be investigated in more detail, the results of this study reveal the risk-coping mechanisms and illustrate a much clearer picture of consumption smoothing behavior among urban working-class households than the traditional view. This study provides the first estimates of income elasticities of consumption in the historical setting of working-class households in the first industrializing country in Asia. Given the increasing availability of historical panel data, this study’s estimates could serve as a benchmark for future studies on consumption smoothing behavior in other historical contexts.

Footnotes

I wish to thank Dan Bogart, Bishnupriya Gupta, Peter Lindert, Kazushige Matsuda, Stefan Öberg, Tetsuji Okazaki, Sakari Saaritsa, Eric Schneider, Masayuki Tanimoto, Ken Yamada, Elise van Nederveen Meerkerk, Hans-Joachim Voth, and the four anonymous referees. I would also like to thank the seminar participants at the University of Tokyo; Montréal; Massachusetts Institute of Technology; and Paris School of Economics for their helpful comments. I thank Ryo Nagaya for research assistance. There are no conflicts of interest to declare.

1 For instance, Townsend (Reference Townsend1994) found that risk sharing among three villages in southern India insured household-level consumption against idiosyncratic shocks. Fafchamps, Udry, and Czukas (Reference Fafchamps, Udry and Czukas1998) and Fafchamps and Lund (Reference Fafchamps and Lund2003) showed that livestock transactions, gifts, and loans from informal networks are used to mitigate idiosyncratic shocks among rural households in Burkina Faso and the Philippines. As for urban households, Skoufias and Quisumbing (Reference Skoufias and Quisumbing2005) provided evidence that both borrowing and additional labor supply are used for self-insurance in Russia. See Townsend (Reference Townsend1995) and Dercon (Reference Dercon2004) for reviews. Attanasio and Pistaferri (Reference Attanasio and Pistaferri2016) and Meyer and Sullivan (Reference Meyer and Sullivan2017) provide the latest discussions on consumption and income inequality.

2 Kiesling (Reference Kiesling1996) determined the importance of informal sources of income assistance (e.g., savings, transfers, and charity) in Victorian Lancashire (see also Boyer (Reference Boyer1997) for an alternative view). Horrell and Oxley (Reference Horrell and Oxley2000) found evidence that British industrial households used supportive organizations, such as sickness and health benefit clubs, in the late nineteenth century. Scott and Walker (Reference Scott and Walker2012) also found that interwar British working-class households frequently used risk-sharing institutions, such as clubs and hire purchases, to smooth expenditures.

3 According to the first Population Census of 1920, Tokyo and Osaka had 2,173,201 and 1,252,983 citizens, respectively (Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet 1925, 1929c). These two cities accounted for approximately 34 percent of Japan’s urban population at the time (Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet 1929a).

4 Regarding consumption smoothing internationally over time, Persaud (Reference Persaud2019), the most recent study on this topic, revealed that Indian indentureship contracts for South-South migration are used as a device to mitigate the risk of volatility in economic outcomes in India. While Persaud (Reference Persaud2019) focused on coping with the risks of macroeconomic shocks, this study investigates consumption smoothing in the face of idiosyncratic shocks.

5 Owing to data unavailability, it was difficult to compile the household-level longitudinal budget data in the historical context (see James and Suto (Reference James and Suto2011) and Scott and Walker (Reference Scott and Walker2012) for discussions on this). For example, Nakagawa (Reference Nakagawa1985), who investigated consumption patterns in urban factory worker households in the early twentieth century in Japan, compared average expenditure on certain consumption categories documented in several cross-sectional survey reports measured in different years. While an exceptional study by Saaritsa (Reference Saaritsa2011) used a quarterly panel dataset of 142 households from Helsinki in 1928, the current study uses data aggregated at a higher frequency to identify households’ short-run responses.

6 In general, the introduction of government social insurance schemes reduced the purchase of private insurance and the use of precautionary savings (Kantor and Fishback Reference Kantor and Fishback1996; Emery Reference Emery2010). In interwar London, for example, pension payments constituted an income below the poverty line (Baines and Johnson Reference Baines and Johnson1999). However, comprehensive public assistance did not exist in prewar Japan (Kase Reference Kase2006); for example, the unemployment insurance bill was not passed until 1947. This underscores the importance of risk-sharing institutions at that time.

7 For example, many of the factories in Osaka that were subject to the Act paid workers only half of their daily wages for medical leave of up to three months (Department of Social Affairs, Osaka City Office 1923, p. 203).

8 The former Health Insurance Act was enacted in 1927, which extended the scope of the sicknesses and injuries covered by the Factory Act. However, it was still designed only for workers at factories subject to the Factory Act.

9 See Godo (Reference Godo2013) and Schneider and Ogasawara (Reference Schneider and Ogasawara2018), respectively. This accumulation of human and physical capital became a driving force of economic growth in postwar Japan (World Bank 1993).

10 See Osaka City Office (1922, pp. 6(59), 6(61), 6(67)) and Statistical Bureau of the Cabinet (1925, p. 2).

11 See Osaka City Office (1922, pp. 6(63), 6(67)), Bureau of Social Welfare (1923, pp. 24–39), and Postal Savings Bureau (1924, p. 72) for the statistics.

12 They found that savings correlated positively with transitory income in cross-sectional household surveys from the 1910s and 1920s in Japan. According to their estimates, the savings level was higher than that of working-class households in the United States in the early twentieth century. They suggested that the widespread use of postal savings accounts in prewar Japan encouraged or facilitated saving relative to the institutions available to U.S. workers.

13 See Osaka City Office (1934, p. 250) and Banks Division, Secretariat of Finance Ministry (1915, pp. 64–69, 246).

14 I examine the lending institutions in cities. See Saito (Reference Saito1989) and Shibuya (Reference Shibuya2000) for the local contexts of these institutions.

15 While pawnshops had been in decline in early twentieth-century Europe, they remained a popular lending institution throughout twentieth-century Japan (Murhem Reference Murhem2015; Shibuya, Suzuki, and Ishiyama Reference Shibuya, Suzuki and Ishiyama1982). I focus on private pawnshops because public pawnshops only officially began to open in the late 1920s, when the Public Pawnshop Law was enacted in 1927. See Shibuya, Suzuki, and Ishiyama (Reference Shibuya, Suzuki and Ishiyama1982, pp. 412–46) for the historical context of public pawnshops.

16 Inoue (Reference Inoue2021, p. 5) revealed that the average numbers of pawnshops, ordinary banks, mutual loan institutions, and post offices in each prefecture in 1924 were 379, 148, 6, and 184, respectively.

17 See Osaka City Office (1920, pp. 102, 104, 122, 123, 136, 138) for the statistics used in this paragraph.

18 Shibuya, Suzuki, and Ishiyama (Reference Shibuya, Suzuki and Ishiyama1982, pp. 335–38), analyzing the ledgers of a pawnshop in Osaka, also showed that more than 90 percent of all articles for pawning were clothes. Given the long-term value of a kimono, for example, networks among specialized dealers, sellers, and secondhand clothes shops sprang up, which eventually formed a large secondhand market in prewar Japan (Francks Reference Francks, Francks and Hunter2012, p. 161). Given this market, pawnshops could evaluate the pawned items against prices in the secondhand market (Bank of Japan 1913).

19 See Osaka City Office (1934, pp. 203, 241) and Osaka City Office (1927, p. 6(85)) for the statistics.

20 Usury interest rates were considerably higher than those of pawnshops. For instance, if the loan amount was 10 yen, the average annual interest rate was around 30 percent in pawnshops compared with more than 100 percent in usuries (Shibuya, Suzuki, and Ishiyama Reference Shibuya, Suzuki and Ishiyama1982, p. 348; Shibuya Reference Shibuya2000, pp. 606–607). Given their astronomical interest rates, usuries were regarded as risky lending institutions for working-class households. The Social Welfare Department of Osaka stated that “usuries are literary ‘vampires’, and eradicating them is an urgent issue in social policy” (Osaka City Office 1926, p. 60).

21 See Osaka City Office (1922, pp. 6(28), 6(34), 6(35)) for the statistics.

22 See also Munshi and Rosenzweig (Reference Munshi and Rosenzweig2016) and Attanasio and Krutikova (Reference Attanasio and Krutikova2020) for recent work on the role of informal networks in village economies in the developing world.

23 Tokyo prefecture asked a wide variety of public offices, companies, schools, banks, and factories to sample working-class households with 2–8 family members and earning 60–250 yen per month. While both conditions were not necessarily met, 1,027 households (including 185 factory worker households) were sampled (Social Affairs Division 1925, pp. 3–16). Despite the cross-sectional survey being conducted in a specific month, November is a useful month to study the income structure because there was no specific seasonality in that month in prewar Japan (see the section “Trends”). In addition, the average monthly income (104 yen) in the sampled factory worker households was in a similar range to those of the other representative surveys (Panel B in Online Appendix Table B.2).

24 I use a reprinted edition of the original archives, as found in Tada (Reference Tada1991a). Although James and Suto (Reference James and Suto2011) employed 99 households from the RLR as an annual cross-sectional dataset, the current study is the first to digitize monthly panel data from this survey.

25 These national figures are obtained from the Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet (1929a, pp. 8–11, 1929b, pp. 8–11).

26 I focused on households classified as involved in the manufacturing industry throughout the sample period to analyze the dynamic behavior of factory worker households. Among the 237 households used in the analysis, there were only six heads who changed their occupation within one month of the sample period. However, these temporary changes only slightly affected my main results (see Online Appendix C.1 for details).

27 I conducted a two-sample t-test with unequal variances between the 237 households and the rest of the original 411 households. The differences in the total income, expenditure, and family size control variables (Panel C of Table 2) are not statistically significant at the 5 percent level. Although I focus on factory worker households, this finding implies that RLR households have similar characteristics and thus can be classified into a similar social class.

28 These figures are calculated based on the wage statistics of the manufacturing census. See Online Appendix B.2 for the finer details of the calculation.

29 The textile and chemical sectors have a slightly larger difference because seven households report a higher income of the head—more than 150 yen per month. However, all analytical results are materially similar if I exclude these households. Thus, these differences in the textile and chemical sectors do not hinder my main findings.

30 In Online Appendix B.3, I provide additional evidence that the monthly household income and expenditure and household size of the RLR sample are close to those of the average factory worker households in the representative large cities.

31 See Ogasawara (2022) for the replication files on the ICPSR.

32 The “other” category includes the income of other family members (i.e., other than the head, wife, and children) and income from boarding and lodging. However, this subcategory is negligible because it is zero in almost all of the households.

33 Categories that have fixed and/or censoring natures are unsuitable for such a test. For example, housing expenses rarely change because rent is likely to be fixed. Similarly, expenses on education and transportation tend to take zero values in some households because they should not be unobserved in households without children and in those commuting by walking, respectively.

34 The Bank of Japan (1986, pp. 436–38) suggests that prices increased by approximately 4 percent from 1919 to 1920, whereas the increase in aggregate household expenditure of RLR households was approximately 6 percent in the same period.

35 This bonus was commonly paid to factory workers at that time (Bureau of Social Welfare 1923, p. 9). In Osaka, the bonus was roughly equivalent to one month’s pay (Tada 1919a, pp. 40–49).

36 The specification for household i in time t can be written as , where Income i,t is monthly household income and , in which n t indicates the number of households in time t.

37 Online Appendix A.1 describes the derivation of the specification. I use log disposable income as the income shock variable, following the empirical setting in the literature (Cochrane Reference Cochrane1991). Measurement error is unlikely to be problematic herein, as the account books were rigorously checked by the investigators (see the section “Variables”). I confirm that my main results are driven from negative income shocks by analyzing an alternative specification using an indicator variable for the negative income shock. Online Appendix Table C.3 presents the results.

38 Lewis (Reference Lewis1996) signaled that omitted variable bias may be an issue when the consumption of self-produced goods in village economies is ignored. However, since this study focuses on purchased consumption among urban households, this type of bias should be negligible.

39 See, for instance, Naidu and Yuchtman (Reference Naidu and Yuchtman2013) for the validity of this strategy. The first quarter is set to be a reference quarter in all the regressions. I used the interactions with respect to quarter dummies rather than month-year dummies because optimization in the nonlinear fixed-effect model is unfeasible under such a complex model (Table 4). I have confirmed that the results from the linear fixed-effect models, using the interaction terms with respect to year-month dummies, are virtually identical to the results from Equation (1).

40 In other words, to analyze households’ responses to the long-term variations in incomes, much longer- and low-frequent-budget data are required (Attanasio and Davis Reference Attanasio and Davis1996). Analyzing those historical budget datasets is another avenue for future work.

41 Per-capita GDP (in 2011 dollars) in Japan in 1920 was 2,974, whereas that in Thailand in 1975 was 3,123 (Bolt and van Zanden 2020). While Thailand has experienced rapid economic growth since 1975, the comparison at the initial status should work because the increasing trend is captured by the year fixed effects in the model (Townsend Reference Townsend1995, p. 93).

42 Per-capita GDP (in 2011 dollars) in India was 1,430 in 1975, whereas that in Bangladesh (in 1996), Ethiopia (in 1996), and Mali (in 1997) was also around 1,000 (Bolt and van Zanden 2020).

43 Evidence from more developed societies in the 1990s also indicates that the income elasticity of total consumption in urban areas of Russia (0.22) was greater than that in rural areas of Mexico (0.08) (Skoufias and Quisumbing Reference Skoufias and Quisumbing2005). Per-capita GDP (in 2011 dollars) in Russia and Mexico was 12,400 and 11,511 in the initial survey years, respectively (Bolt and van Zanden 2020).

44 Most primary schools still collected tuition fees in Osaka city in the early 1920s, even though they were no longer high (Osaka City Office 1922, pp. 3(8)–3(9), 3(22)–3(23)). The tuition fee was collected regularly on a specific day every month (Fuji 1925, p. 187). Other education expenses included smaller payments for school supplies such as stationery (Fuji 1925, pp. 90–91). This expenditure must also be included in the education expenses of RLR households.

45 Even in the suburbs, the graduation rate from primary school was approximately 90 percent (Okado Reference Okado2000, p. 30). Hijikata (Reference Hijikata1994, p. 19) also provided evidence that the average dropout rate of primary schools in the 1920s was less than 10 percent.

46 As I explained earlier, the heads of RLR households were average factory workers (see the section “The Sample”). By contrast, those children who could not attend school were mainly from low-income households whose heads were day laborers, rickshaw drivers, and handicraft makers at that time (Okado Reference Okado2000, pp. 34–35).

47 Skoufias and Quisumbing (Reference Skoufias and Quisumbing2005) found that food consumption is more likely to be insured from idiosyncratic shocks than nonfood consumption in Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Mali, Mexico, and Russia in the 1990s. While caution is required when comparing my results with those of other countries in the different developmental stages, the mechanism behind the adjustments must be similar. Another strand of the literature suggests that households could also alter their diet to adjust food expenditure (Öberg Reference Öberg2016).

48 Online Appendix A.2 describes the derivation of the specification. Disposable income in Equation (2) excludes temporary income from borrowing, withdrawals and gifts, as well as tax payments. I confirm that the results are largely unchanged if I use an indicator variable for negative shocks to disposable income instead of disposable income (). Online Appendix C.2 summarizes these results.

49 In addition, the former estimate can be similar to or slightly greater than the latter estimate, as it might include a small gift amount.

50 The results are materially similar if I use the full sample. However, I prefer to deal with the attenuation effects by removing the completely censored units. I have confirmed that the family size characteristics are similar in both the trimmed households and the rest. See Online Appendix C.3 for the finer details.

51 To understand the saving behaviors of households in detail, I prefer to show the estimates for withdrawals and gifts, and deposits to savings separately. However, one can calculate the estimate for the net savings (say withdrawals minus deposits) as a combination of the estimates listed in Columns (1) and (3): the elasticity of net savings is –0.202 – 0.067= –0.269. I provide the full results for net savings and net borrowing in Online Appendix Table C.8.

52 Deaton (Reference Deaton1991) predicts the mechanism by which, among households under a liquidity constraint, assets work to protect consumption against income shocks because the constraint increases the precautionary demand for savings. In Online Appendix Table C.10, I provide suggestive evidence that precautionary savings might have mitigated the shocks among the households potentially facing borrowing constraints.

53 The results are unchanged if I use the expenditure on housing as an alternative cut-off variable that is exogenous to short-run earnings and savings. See Online Appendix C.5 for finer details of the discussion.

54 The specification using a product term between disposable income and a subsample dummy in Equation (2) is undesirable because it postulates many considerably stronger assumptions on the remaining parameters, including the fixed effects.

55 Regressions using liquidation of loans are no longer practical under stratified subsamples because the optimization is computationally demanding, especially when the models are complex, as in the case of small samples. Despite this, I confirm that the results for liquidation of loans from the simplified specification, including disposable income and the household, as well as the quarter-fixed effects, are consistent with the results for income from borrowing: the estimates are statistically significantly positive in both subsamples, whereas the estimate for the subsample above the median is somewhat weak.

56 Income from the other family members (i.e., other than the head, wife, and child) is negligible because most of the observations in this category take zero values, and thus any regressions are infeasible (see the section “Variables”).

57 Neither the multinomial regression model nor the structural method proposed by Heckman (Reference Heckman1979) are adopted because neither technique can profile out the household fixed effects. This is crucial in my analysis, which aims to estimate the income elasticity of the household head using the transitory part of that income after controlling for the household fixed effects. In addition, although the child’s income is not divisible, such a scale effect is effectively controlled for by including family size controls.

58 I confirm that this result is unchanged if I use the linear probability model for the indicator variables that take one for the observations with positive values of either the wife’s or the child’s income.

59 Although the ages of family members are unavailable, the RLR documented the number of family members in several age bins (Panel C of Table 2). Thus, I calculate the percentage of working children as the share of household-year-month cells with a positive income from the child to the total observations: the share is 25 percent for households with children aged 13 and older, but only 1 percent for households with children aged 12 or under.

References

REFERENCES

Attanasio, Orazio P., and Davis, Steven J.. “Relative Wage Movements and the Distribution of Consumption.” Journal of Political Economy 104, no. 6 (1996): 1227–62.Google Scholar
Attanasio, Orazio P., and Krutikova, Sonya. “Consumption Insurance in Networks with Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Tanzania.” Journal of European Economic Association 18, no. 4 (2020): 1589–618.Google Scholar
Attanasio, Orazio P., and Pistaferri, Luigi. “Consumption Inequality.” Journal of Economic Perspective 30, no. 2 (2016): 328.Google Scholar
Baines, Dudley, and Johnson, Paul. “Did They Jump or Were They Pushed? The Exit of Older Men from the London Labor Market, 1929–1931.” Journal of Economic History 59, no. 4 (1999): 949–71.Google Scholar
Bassino, Jean-Pascal. “Inequality in Japan (1892–1941): Physical Stature, Income, and Health.” Economics & Human Biology 4, no. 1 (2006): 6288.Google Scholar
Blundell, Richard, Pistaferri, Luigi, and Preston, Ian. “Consumption Inequality and Partial Insurance.” American Economic Review 98, no. 5 (2008): 1887–921.Google Scholar
Bowblis, John R.The Decline in Infant Death Rates, 1878–1913: The Role of Early Sickness Insurance Programs.” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 1 (2010): 221–32.Google Scholar
Boyer, George R.Poor Relief, Informal Assistance, and Short Time during the Lancashire Cotton Famine.” Explorations in Economic History 34, no. 1 (1997): 5676.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D.Buffer-Stock Saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, no. 1 (1997): 155.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D., Dynan, Karen E., and Krane, Spencer D.. “Unemployment Risk and Precautionary Wealth: Evidence from Households’ Balance Sheets.” Review of Economics and Statistics 85, no. 3 (2003): 586604.Google Scholar
Chimoto, Akiko. “Urbanization and Women’s Participation Rate: Analysis of the Census of 1920.” [in Japanese] Dōshisha Shōgaku 63, no. 5 (2012): 642–62.Google Scholar
Cochrane, John H.A Simple Test of Consumption Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 99, no. 5 (1991): 957–76.Google Scholar
Deaton, Angus. “Saving and Liquidity Constraints.” Econometrica 59, no. 5 (1991): 1221–48.Google Scholar
Deaton, Angus. Understanding Consumption. New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Dercon, Stefan. Insurance Against Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Dercon, Stefan, and Krishnan, Pramila. “In Sickness and in Health: Risk Sharing within Households in Rural Ethiopia.” Journal of Political Economy 108, no. 4 (2002): 688727.Google Scholar
di Matteo, Livio, and Herbert Emery, J. C.. “Wealth and the Demand for Life Insurance: Evidence from Ontario, 1892.” Explorations in Economic History 39, no. 4 (2002): 446–69.Google Scholar
Emery, J. C. Herbert. “‘Un-American’ or Unnecessary? America’s Rejection of Compulsory Government Health Insurance in the Progressive Era.” Explorations in Economic History 47, no. 1 (2010): 6881.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel, and Lund, Susan. “Risk-Sharing Networks in Rural Philippines.” Journal of Development Economics 71, no. 2 (2003): 261–87.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel, Udry, Christopher, and Czukas, Katherine. “Drought and Saving in West Africa: Are Livestock a Buffer Stock?Journal of Development Economics 55, no. 2 (1998): 273305.Google Scholar
Foster, Andrew D.Prices, Credit Markets and Child Growth in Low-Income Rural Areas.” Economic Journal 105, no. 430 (1995): 551–70.Google Scholar
Francks, Penelope. “Kimono Fashion: The Consumer and the Growth of the Textile Industry in Pre-War Japan.” In The Historical Consumer: Consumption and Everyday Life in Japan, 1850–2000, edited by Francks, Penelope and Hunter, Janet, 158–75. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2012.Google Scholar
Gertler, Paul, and Gruber, Jonathan. “Insuring Consumption against Illness.” American Economic Review 92, no. 1 (2002): 5170.Google Scholar
Godo, Yoshihisa. “Economic Growth and Education Stocks in East Asia.” [in Japanese] Keizai Kenkyū 64, no. 1 (2013): 3041.Google Scholar
Heckman, James. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47, no. 1 (1979): 153–61.Google Scholar
Hijikata, Sonoko. School and Community in Prewar Japan. [in Japanese] Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Hijikata, Sonoko. Public, Private, Charity Schools in Modern Tokyo. [in Japanese] Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Honoré, Bo E.Trimmed LAD and Least Squares Estimation of Truncated and Censored Regression Models with Fixed Effects.” Econometrica 60, no. 3 (1992): 533–65.Google Scholar
Horrell, Sara, and Oxley, Deborah. “Work and Prudence: Household Responses to Income Variation in Nineteenth-Century Britain.” European Review of Economic History 4, no. 1 (2000): 2757.Google Scholar
Hyodo, Tsutomu. The Evolution of Labor-Capital Relations in Japan. [in Japanese] Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1971.Google Scholar
Inoue, Tatsuki. “The Role of Pawnshops in Risk Coping in Early Twentieth-Century Japan.” Financial History Review 28, no. 3 (2021): 125.Google Scholar
James, John A., and Suto, Isao. “Early Twentieth-Century Japanese Worker Saving: Precautionary Behaviour before a Social Safety Net.” Cliometrica 5, no. 1 (2011): 125.Google Scholar
Kantor, Shawn E., and Fishback, Price V.. “Precautionary Saving, Insurance, and the Origins of Workers’ Compensation.” Journal of Political Economy 104, no. 2 (1996): 419–42.Google Scholar
Kase, Kazutoshi. “A Study of Proposals of Unemployment Insurance Schemes in Pre-war Japan.” [in Japanese] Shakai Kagaku Kenkyū 58 (2006): 125–55.Google Scholar
Kato, Yuriko. “Rental House Management on Leased Land in Prewar Japan.” [in Japanese] Aoyama Gakuin Jyoshi Tanki Daigaku Kiyō 44 (1990): 79–94.Google Scholar
Kiesling, Lynne L.Institutional Choice Matters: The Poor Law and Implicit Labor Contracts in Victorian Lancashire.” Explorations in Economic History 33, no. 1 (1996): 6585.Google Scholar
Lewis, Karen K.What Can Explain the Apparent Lack of International Consumption Risk Sharing?Journal of Political Economy 104, no. 2 (1996): 267–97.Google Scholar
Mace, Barbara J.Full Insurance in the Presence of Aggregate Uncertainty.” Journal of Political Economy 99, no. 5 (1991): 928–56.Google Scholar
Meyer, Bruce D., and Sullivan, James X.. “Consumption and Income Inequality in the U.S. since the 1960s.” NBER Working Paper No. 23655, Cambridge, MA, August 2017.Google Scholar
Moehling, Carolyn M.Women’s Work and Men’s Unemployment.” Journal of Economic History 61, no. 4 (2001): 926–49.Google Scholar
Moriguchi, Chiaki. “The Evolution of Employment Relations in U.S. and Japanese Manufacturing Firms, 1900–1960: A Comparative Historical and Institutional Analysis.” NBER Working Paper No. 7939, Cambridge, MA, October 2000.Google Scholar
Moriguchi, Chiaki. “Implicit Contracts, the Great Depression, and Institutional Change: A Comparative Analysis of U.S. and Japanese Employment Relations, 1920–1940.” Journal of Economic History 63, no. 3 (2003): 625–65.Google Scholar
Munshi, Kaivan, and Rosenzweig, Mark. “Networks and Misallocation: Insurance, Migration, and the Rural-Urban Wage Gap.” American Economic Review 106, no. 1 (2016): 4698.Google Scholar
Murhem, Sofia. “Credit for the Poor: The Decline of Pawnbroking 1880–1930.” European Review of Economic History 20, no. 2 (2015): 198214.Google Scholar
Naidu, Suresh, and Yuchtman, Noam. “Coercive Contract Enforcement: Law and the Labor Market in Nineteenth Century Industrial Britain.” American Economic Review 103, no. 1 (2013): 107–44.Google Scholar
Nakagawa, Kiyoshi. A City Lower Layer of Japan. [in Japanese] Tokyo: Keisō Shobō, 1985.Google Scholar
Nakamura, Takafusa. Analysis of Interwar Japanese Economy. [in Japanese] Tokyo: Yamakawa Shuppan, 1981.Google Scholar
Nakamura, Takafusa, and Odaka, Konosuke. “Overview.” [in Japanese] In Dual-Structure, edited by Nakamura, Takafusa and Odaka, Konosuke, 1–80. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten, 1989.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A.On Testing for Full Insurance Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Data.” Journal of Political Economy 102, no. 2 (1994): 384–94.Google Scholar
Öberg, Stefan. “Did the Poor Pay More? Income-Related Variations in Diet and Food Quality among Urban Households in Sweden 1913–1914.” Rivista Di Storia Economica 32, no. 2 (2016): 211–48.Google Scholar
Odaka, Konosuke. “Japanese-Style Labour Relations.” In The Japanese Economic System and Its Historical Origins, edited by Okazaki, Tetsuji and Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, Ch. 5. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Ogasawara, Kota. Replication files for “Consumption Smoothing in the Working-Class Households of Interwar Japan.” Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2022-09-20. https://doi.org/10.3886/E180281V1 Google Scholar
Okado, Masakatsu. What Did School Education Bring to Children? Tokyo: Aoki Shoten, 2000.Google Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji. “Selection, Exits and Efficiency in the Japanese Banking Industry: An Historical Perspective.” [in Japanese] In Strategy for the Financial Revitalization in Japan, edited by Saito, Makoto, 230–31. Chūō Keizai Sha, 2002.Google Scholar
Ono, Hiroshi. Economic History of Living Space. [in Japanese] Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Hyōron Sha, 1999.Google Scholar
Persaud, Alexander. “Escaping Local Risk by Entering Indentureship: Evidence from Nineteenth-Century Indian Migration.” Journal of Economic History 79, no. 2 (2019): 447–76.Google Scholar
Ravallion, Martin, and Chaudhuri, Shubham. “Risk and Insurance in Village India: Comment.” Econometrica 65, no. 1 (1997): 171–84.Google Scholar
Rose, Elaina. “Consumption Smoothing and Excess Female Mortality in Rural India.” Review of Economics and Statistics 81, no. 1 (1999): 4149.Google Scholar
Rosenzweig, Mark R.Risk, Implicit Contracts and the Family in Rural Areas of Low-Income Countries.” Economic Journal 98, no. 393 (1988): 1148–70.Google Scholar
Saaritsa, Sakari. “The Poverty of Solidarity: The Size and Structure of Informal Income Smoothing among Worker Households in Helsinki, 1928.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 59, no. 2 (2011): 102–27.Google Scholar
Saito, Hiroshi. Shichiyashi no kenkyū [in Japanese] Tokyo: Shin Hyōron, 1989.Google Scholar
Saito, Osamu. “Child Labor in Modern Japan” [in Japanese] Keizai Kenkyū 46, no. 3 (1995): 216–29.Google Scholar
Saito, Osamu. “Children’s Work, Industrialism, and the Family Economy in Japan.” In Child Labor in Historical Perspective 1800–1985: Case Studies from Europe, Japan, and Colombia, edited by Hugh Cunningham and Pier Paolo Viazzo, 73–90. Florence: UNICEF, 1996.Google Scholar
Schneider, Eric B., and Ogasawara, Kota. “Disease and Child Growth in Industrializing Japan: Critical Windows and the Growth Pattern, 1917–39.” Explorations in Economic History 69 (2018): 6480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Peter M., and Walker, James. “Working-Class Household Consumption Smoothing in Interwar Britain.” Journal of Economic History 72, no. 3 (2012): 797825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shibuya, Ryuichi. Development and Structure of Usuries. [in Japanese] Tokyo: Nihon Tosho Center, 2000.Google Scholar
Shibuya, Ryuichi, Suzuki, Kameji, and Ishiyama, Shojiro. Pawn Shops in Japan. [in Japanese] Tokyo: Waseda University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Skoufias, Emmanuel, and Quisumbing, Agnes R.. “Consumption Insurance and Vulnerability to Poverty: A Synthesis of the Evidence from Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Mali, Mexico, and Russia.” European Journal of Development Research 17 no. 1 (2005): 2458.Google Scholar
Taira, Koji. Economic Development and the Labor Market in Japan. New York and London: Columbia University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Takeda, Haruhito. “Business Cycle and Economic Policy.” [in Japanese] In Japanese Economic History, Vol. 3, edited by Kanji, Ishii, Akira, Hara, and Haruhito, Takeda, 1–51. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Tanaka, Hikaru. “Postal Savings and Mass Saving Behavior in the Early 20th Century: A Case Study of Mishima City in Shizuoka Prefecture.” [in Japanese] Rekishi to Keizai 54, no. 2 (2012): 1631.Google Scholar
Townsend, Robert M.Risk and Insurance in Village India.” Econometrica 62, no. 3 (1994): 539–91.Google Scholar
Townsend, Robert M.Consumption Insurance: An Evaluation of Risk-Bearing Systems in Low-Income Economies.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 no. 3 (1995): 83102.Google Scholar
World Bank. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Yazawa, Hirotake. Income Distribution and Family Economy in Modern Japan. [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Nihon Tosho Center, 2004.Google Scholar

DOCUMENTS

Division, Banks, Secretariat of Finance Ministry. Mujin ni kansuru chōsa (Survey on Mutual Loan), [in Japanese] Tokyo: Banks Division, Secretariat of Finance Ministry, 1915.Google Scholar
Bank of Japan. Nihonginkō hyakunenshi, dai ikkan (The Hundred Year History of the Bank of Japan, Source Material, Vol. 1). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Bank of Japan, 1986.Google Scholar
Bank of Japan. Shichiya ni kansuru chōsa (Survey on Pawnbroking), [in Japanese] Tokyo: Bank of Japan, 1913.Google Scholar
Bureau of Social Welfare. Shokkō seikei jyōtai chōsa (Survey of Living Conditions of Factory Workers). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Bureau of Social Welfare, 1923.Google Scholar
Bolt, Jutta and Luiten van Zanden, Jan. (2020). Maddison Project Database, version 2020. https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/historicaldevelopment/maddison/publications/wp15.pdf (accessed on 5 October 2021).Google Scholar
Department of Social Affairs, Osaka City Office. Rodō chōsa hōkoku, dai nijyūnishū (Report of Labor Research, Series 22). [in Japanese] Kyoto: Koubundou Shobō, 1923.Google Scholar
Ichiro, Fuji. Gakkō keiei no jissai (School Administration). [in Japanese] Fukuoka, 1925.Google Scholar
Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka. “Rodō chōsa hōkoku, dai ni, yon, go, hachishū (Report of Labor Research, Series 2, 4, 5, and 8).” [in Japanese] In Taishō kakei chōsa shūsei (Collection of Household Budget Surveys in the Taisho Era)}, edited by Tada, Yoshizo. Tokyo: Seishi Sha, 1919–1920.Google Scholar
Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka. “Rodō chōsa hōkoku, dai jyusshū (Report of Labor Research, Series 10), Cost of Living among Laborers in Osaka, Japan.” [in Japanese] In Taishō kakei chōsa shūsei (Collection of Household Budget Surveys in the Taisho Era), edited by Tada, Yoshizo. Tokyo: Seishi Sha, 1921.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. “Shichiya ni kansuru chōsa (Survey on Pawn Shops).” [in Japanese] In Report of Labor Research, Series 4, edited by Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka. Osaka: Osaka City Office, 1920.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. Osakashi tōkeisho, Taishō hachinen (Statistical Table of Osaka City, 1919 Edition). [in Japanese] Osaka: Osaka City Office, 1921.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. Osakashi tōkeisho, Taishō kyūnen (Statistical Table of Osaka City, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Osaka: Osaka City Office, 1922.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. Shichiya to kanekashigyō (Pawn Shop and Money Lending Business.) [in Japanese] Osaka: Osaka City Office, 1926.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. Osakashi tōkeisho, Shōwa ichinen (Statistical Table of Osaka City, 1926 Edition). [in Japanese] Osaka: Osaka City Office, 1927.Google Scholar
Osaka City Office. Osakashishi, dai yonkan (History of Osaka City, Vol. 4). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Osaka City Office, 1934.Google Scholar
Postal Savings Bureau. Chokinkyoku tōkei nenpō (Annual Statistical Report of Postal Savings Bureau, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Postal Savings Bureau, 1924.Google Scholar
Social Affairs Division. Chūtō kaikyū seikeihi chōsa (Survey of Living Conditions among Middle Class). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Social Affair Division, 1925.Google Scholar
Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet. Taishō kyūnen kokusei chōsa hōkoku, fuken no bu, dai sankan (Population Census of Japan, Osaka Prefecture, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, 1925.Google Scholar
Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet. Taishō kyūnen kokusei chōsa hōkoku, zenkoku no bu, dai ikkan (Population Census of Japan, Vol. 1, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, 1928.Google Scholar
Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet. Taoshō kyūnen kokuseichōsahōkoku, zenkoku no bu, dai nikan (Population Census of Japan, Vol. 2, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, 1929a.Google Scholar
Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet. Taishō kyūnen kokusei chōsa hōkoku, zenkoku no bu, dai sankan (Population Census of Japan, Vol. 3, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, 1929b.Google Scholar
Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet. Taishō kyūnen kokusei chōsa hōkoku, fuken no bu, dai ikkan (Population Census of Japan, Tokyo Prefecture, 1920 Edition). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Statistics Bureau of the Cabinet, 1929c.Google Scholar
Tada, Yoshizo. Taishō kakei chōsa shūsei, dai sankan (Collection of Household Budget Surveys in the Taisho Era, Vol. 3). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Seishi Sha, 1991a.Google Scholar
Tada, Yoshizo. Taishō kakei chōsa shūsei, dai yonkan (Collection of Household Budget Surveys in the Taisho Era, Vol. 4). [in Japanese] Tokyo: Seishi Sha, 1991b.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 SAMPLE CHARACTERISTICS: COMPARING THE RLR SAMPLE WITH THE CENSUS

Figure 1

Figure 1 MONTHLY INCOME AND EXPENDITURE BETWEEN JUNE 1919 AND JUNE 1920Notes: Monthly income and expenditure are illustrated in Figure 1a. The difference between monthly income and monthly expenditure is shown in Figure 1b.Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (1919–1920).

Figure 2

Figure 2 VARIATIONS IN IDIOSYNCRATIC SHOCKS (IN YEN)Notes: This figure shows the box-and-whisker plot of the residuals from the regression of the first-difference in income on the first-difference in aggregate income. The 25th, 50th, and 75th percentiles are the bottom, middle (white line), and top of the box, respectively. The caps at the ends of the whiskers show the lower and upper adjacent values, respectively.Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (1919–1920).

Figure 3

Table 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS: SAMPLE OF RLR HOUSEHOLDS

Figure 4

Figure 3 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE CHANGES IN DISPOSABLE INCOME AND EXPENDITURENotes: The relationship between the changes in disposable income and expenditure for the 10 subcategories (Panel A of Table 2) is described in the figures. For comparability, the minimum and maximum values of the y-axis are fixed at –7.0 and 7.0, respectively.Sources: Created by the author from the Municipal Bureau of Labor Research of Osaka (1919–1920).

Figure 5

Table 3 RESULTS OF ESTIMATING INCOME ELASTICITIES

Figure 6

Table 4 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS

Figure 7

Table 5 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS: HETEROGENEOUS RESPONSES

Figure 8

Table 6 RESULTS OF TESTING THE RISK-COPING MECHANISMS: LABOR SUPPLY ADJUSTMENTS

Supplementary material: PDF

Ogasawara supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Ogasawara supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 984.7 KB