Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-m42fx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T01:34:20.198Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false
This chapter is part of a book that is no longer available to purchase from Cambridge Core

7 - SOCIAL JUSTICE

Arye L. Hillman
Affiliation:
Bar-Ilan University, Israel
Get access

Summary

We shall now study social justice. We have seen that, unless the rich and the poor form a coalition against the middle, self-interested majority voting is predicted to result in income transfers that benefit the median voter. Director's law indicates that the middle class, of which we expect the median voter in high-income democracies to be part, disproportionately benefits from publicly financed public goods – and the middle class also benefits from tax deductions. Nonetheless, in high-income democracies, the beneficiaries of income redistribution are not the middle class but rather low-income people. The evidence, which was indicated in the previous chapter, therefore does not verify the prediction that the median voter or middle class will use majority voting for personal benefit through income transfers. Rather, in high-income democracies, redistribution of income is consistent with the conception of social justice that people who have not fared well in life should be helped.

However, the taxes paid to finance the income transfers to low-income people are compulsory. The taxes and income transfers contradict Pareto efficiency (taxpayers lose and recipients of income transfers gain) and are contrary to the principle of the natural right of possession of people to their own income. We confront, therefore, the normative question:

How are involuntary income transfers justified?

We shall address this question on the supposition that governments can identify who is effectively paying taxes and bears the burden of taxation, and who benefits from the redistribution of tax revenue, given (as we saw in chapter 4) that legal and effective incidence of taxes and subsidies generally differ.

Type
Chapter
Information
Public Finance and Public Policy
Responsibilities and Limitations of Government
, pp. 489 - 586
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Black, S., Devereux, P., and Salvanes, K., 2005. Why the apple doesn't fall far: Understanding intergenerational transmission of human capital. American Economic Review 95:437–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, J., and Moretti, E., 2003. Mother's education and the intergenerational transmission of human capital: Evidence from college openings. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:1495–532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duncan, G. J., and Brooks-Gunn, J. (Eds.), 1997. Consequences of Growing Up Poor. Russell Sage Foundation, New York.
Goldberger, A. S., and Manski, C. F., 1995. The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life by Richard J. Herrnstein and Charles Murray. Journal of Economic Literature 33:762–76.Google Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J., and Murray, C., 1995. The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life. The Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Bentham, J., 1879. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. The Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. A., 1971. A Theory of Justice. Belknap Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Ng, Y.-K., 1997. A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability. Economic Journal 107:1848–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergson, A., 1938. A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52:310–34. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 7–25.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A., 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C., 1955. Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. Journal of Political Economy 63:209–321. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 46–60.Google Scholar
Neumann, J., and Morgenstern, O., 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.Google Scholar
Sinn, H.-W., 1995. A theory of the welfare state. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97: 495–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R., 1980. Redistributive taxation as social insurance. Journal of Public Economics 14:49–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard, C. L., 1988. The marginal efficiency cost of redistribution. American Economic Review 78:1019–33.Google Scholar
Browning, E. K., and Johnson, W. R., 1984. The trade-off between equality and efficiency. Journal of Political Economy 92:175–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okun, A. M., 1975. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Brookings Institution Press, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D., 1991. The economic role of a work ethic. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 15:365–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCleary, R. M., and Barro, R. J., 2006. Religion and the economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20:49–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M., 1905/1920/1958. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Scribner, New York.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G., 1970. The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84:488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:313–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quiggin, J., 1982. A theory of anticipated utility. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3:323–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yaari, M., 1987. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55:95–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawkes, K., 1993. Why do hunter–gatherers work? An ancient version of the problem of public goods. Current Anthropology 34:314–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, G., 1999. Heaven's Door. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.Google Scholar
Dodson, M. E., 2001. Welfare generosity and locational choices among U.S. immigrants. International Review of Law and Economics 21:47–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, S. P., 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Making of World Order. Simon and Schuster, New York.Google Scholar
Nannestad, P., 2004. Immigration as a challenge to the Danish welfare state?European Journal of Political Economy 20:755–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hochman, H. M., and Rogers, J. D., 1969. Pareto optimal redistribution. American Economic Review 59:542–57.Google Scholar
Sugden, R., 1982. On the economics of philanthropy. Economic Journal 92:341–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abrams, B. A., and Schmitz, M. S., 1978. The crowding-out effect of government transfers on private charitable contributions. Public Choice 33:29–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, R. D., 1984. A positive model of private charity and public transfers. Journal of Political Economy 92:136–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., 1975. The Samaritan's dilemma. In Phelps, E. (Ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, pp. 71–87.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D., 1989. Efficient status seeking: Externalities and the evolution of status games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11:175–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, G., and Grüner, H.-P., 2000. Social limits to redistribution. American Economic Review 90:1491–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glazer, A., and Konrad, K. A., 1996. A signaling explanation for charity. American Economic Review 86:1019–28.Google Scholar
Harbaugh, W. T., 1998. The prestige motive for making charitable transfers. American Economic Review 88:277–82.Google Scholar
Veblen, T., 1899/1934. The Theory of the Leisure Class. Modern Library, New York.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., and Vesterlund, L., 2001. Which is the fairer sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116:293–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T. N., and Mui, V.-L., 1997. A laboratory study of group polarization in the team dictator game. Economic Journal 107:1465–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Kang, and Fang-Fang, Tang, 2009. Cultural differences between Tibetans and ethnic Han Chinese in ultimatum bargaining experiments. European Journal of Political Economy 25:78–84.
Eckel, C. C., and Grossman, P. J., 1996. The relative price of fairness: Gender differences in a punishment game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 30:143–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., 2000. Does culture matter in economic behavior? Ultimatum game bargaining among the Machiguenga in the Peruvian Amazon. American Economic Review 90:973–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., and McElreath, R., 2001. In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 91:73–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., and Smith, V., 1994. Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior 7:346–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oosterbeek, H., Sloof, R., and Kuilen, G., 2004. Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics 7:171–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruffle, B. S., 1998. More is better, but fair is fair: Tipping in dictator and ultimatum games. Games and Economic Behavior 23:247–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galton, F., 1889. Natural Inheritance. Macmillan, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G., and Tomes, N., 1986. Human capital and the rise and fall of families (The family and the distribution of economic rewards). Journal of Labor Economics part 2, 4:S1–S39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratberg, E., Nilsen, Ø. A., and Vaage, K., 2007. Intergenerational earnings mobility in Norway: Levels and trends. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 107:419–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chadwick, L., and Solon, G., 2002. Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. American Economic Review 92:335–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dearden, L., Machin, S., and Reed, H., 1997. Intergenerational mobility in Britain. Economic Journal 107:47–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lam, D., and Schoeni, R. F., 1993. Effects of family background on earnings and returns to schooling: Evidence from Brazil. Journal of Political Economy 101:710–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mulligan, C. B., 1999. Galton versus the human capital approach to inheritance. Journal of Political Economy 107:S184–S224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solon, G., 1992. Intergenerational income mobility in the U.S. American Economic Review 82:393–408.Google Scholar
Solon, G., 2002. Cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings mobility. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16:59–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zimmerman, D. J., 1992. Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature. American Economic Review 82:409–29.Google Scholar
Abed, G. T., and Gupta, S. (Eds.), 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
Baldacci, E., Hillman, A. L., and , N. Kojo, 2004. Growth, governance, and fiscal-policy transmission channels in low-income countries. European Journal of Political Economy 20:517–49. Reprinted in Gupta, S., Clements, B., and Inchauste, G. (Eds.), 2004. Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, pp. 67–104.Google Scholar
Doucouliagos, H., and Paldam, M., 2008. Aid effectiveness on growth: A meta-study. European Journal of Political Economy 24:1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W., 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Hillman, A. L., 2002. The World Bank and the persistence of poverty in poor countries. European Journal of Political Economy 18:783–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinikka, R., and Svensson, J., 2004. Local capture: Evidence from a central government transfer program in Uganda. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:679–705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fields, G. R., and Ok, E. A., 1999. The measurement of income mobility: An introduction to the literature. In Silver, J. (Ed.), Handbook on Income Inequality. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, pp. 557–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B., 1970. On the measurement of economic inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 2:244–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shorrocks, A. F., 1983. Ranking income distributions. Economica 50:1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J., 1950. A difficulty in the concept of social welfare. Journal of Political Economy 58:328–46. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 147–68.Google Scholar
Black, S., Devereux, P., and Salvanes, K., 2005. Why the apple doesn't fall far: Understanding intergenerational transmission of human capital. American Economic Review 95:437–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, J., and Moretti, E., 2003. Mother's education and the intergenerational transmission of human capital: Evidence from college openings. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:1495–532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duncan, G. J., and Brooks-Gunn, J. (Eds.), 1997. Consequences of Growing Up Poor. Russell Sage Foundation, New York.
Goldberger, A. S., and Manski, C. F., 1995. The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life by Richard J. Herrnstein and Charles Murray. Journal of Economic Literature 33:762–76.Google Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J., and Murray, C., 1995. The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life. The Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Bentham, J., 1879. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. The Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. A., 1971. A Theory of Justice. Belknap Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Ng, Y.-K., 1997. A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability. Economic Journal 107:1848–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergson, A., 1938. A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52:310–34. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 7–25.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A., 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C., 1955. Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. Journal of Political Economy 63:209–321. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 46–60.Google Scholar
Neumann, J., and Morgenstern, O., 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.Google Scholar
Sinn, H.-W., 1995. A theory of the welfare state. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97: 495–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R., 1980. Redistributive taxation as social insurance. Journal of Public Economics 14:49–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard, C. L., 1988. The marginal efficiency cost of redistribution. American Economic Review 78:1019–33.Google Scholar
Browning, E. K., and Johnson, W. R., 1984. The trade-off between equality and efficiency. Journal of Political Economy 92:175–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okun, A. M., 1975. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Brookings Institution Press, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D., 1991. The economic role of a work ethic. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 15:365–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCleary, R. M., and Barro, R. J., 2006. Religion and the economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20:49–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M., 1905/1920/1958. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Scribner, New York.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G., 1970. The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84:488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:313–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quiggin, J., 1982. A theory of anticipated utility. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3:323–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yaari, M., 1987. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55:95–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawkes, K., 1993. Why do hunter–gatherers work? An ancient version of the problem of public goods. Current Anthropology 34:314–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, G., 1999. Heaven's Door. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.Google Scholar
Dodson, M. E., 2001. Welfare generosity and locational choices among U.S. immigrants. International Review of Law and Economics 21:47–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, S. P., 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Making of World Order. Simon and Schuster, New York.Google Scholar
Nannestad, P., 2004. Immigration as a challenge to the Danish welfare state?European Journal of Political Economy 20:755–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hochman, H. M., and Rogers, J. D., 1969. Pareto optimal redistribution. American Economic Review 59:542–57.Google Scholar
Sugden, R., 1982. On the economics of philanthropy. Economic Journal 92:341–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abrams, B. A., and Schmitz, M. S., 1978. The crowding-out effect of government transfers on private charitable contributions. Public Choice 33:29–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, R. D., 1984. A positive model of private charity and public transfers. Journal of Political Economy 92:136–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., 1975. The Samaritan's dilemma. In Phelps, E. (Ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, pp. 71–87.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D., 1989. Efficient status seeking: Externalities and the evolution of status games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11:175–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, G., and Grüner, H.-P., 2000. Social limits to redistribution. American Economic Review 90:1491–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glazer, A., and Konrad, K. A., 1996. A signaling explanation for charity. American Economic Review 86:1019–28.Google Scholar
Harbaugh, W. T., 1998. The prestige motive for making charitable transfers. American Economic Review 88:277–82.Google Scholar
Veblen, T., 1899/1934. The Theory of the Leisure Class. Modern Library, New York.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., and Vesterlund, L., 2001. Which is the fairer sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116:293–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T. N., and Mui, V.-L., 1997. A laboratory study of group polarization in the team dictator game. Economic Journal 107:1465–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Kang, and Fang-Fang, Tang, 2009. Cultural differences between Tibetans and ethnic Han Chinese in ultimatum bargaining experiments. European Journal of Political Economy 25:78–84.
Eckel, C. C., and Grossman, P. J., 1996. The relative price of fairness: Gender differences in a punishment game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 30:143–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., 2000. Does culture matter in economic behavior? Ultimatum game bargaining among the Machiguenga in the Peruvian Amazon. American Economic Review 90:973–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., and McElreath, R., 2001. In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 91:73–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., and Smith, V., 1994. Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior 7:346–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oosterbeek, H., Sloof, R., and Kuilen, G., 2004. Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics 7:171–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruffle, B. S., 1998. More is better, but fair is fair: Tipping in dictator and ultimatum games. Games and Economic Behavior 23:247–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galton, F., 1889. Natural Inheritance. Macmillan, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G., and Tomes, N., 1986. Human capital and the rise and fall of families (The family and the distribution of economic rewards). Journal of Labor Economics part 2, 4:S1–S39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratberg, E., Nilsen, Ø. A., and Vaage, K., 2007. Intergenerational earnings mobility in Norway: Levels and trends. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 107:419–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chadwick, L., and Solon, G., 2002. Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. American Economic Review 92:335–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dearden, L., Machin, S., and Reed, H., 1997. Intergenerational mobility in Britain. Economic Journal 107:47–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lam, D., and Schoeni, R. F., 1993. Effects of family background on earnings and returns to schooling: Evidence from Brazil. Journal of Political Economy 101:710–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mulligan, C. B., 1999. Galton versus the human capital approach to inheritance. Journal of Political Economy 107:S184–S224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solon, G., 1992. Intergenerational income mobility in the U.S. American Economic Review 82:393–408.Google Scholar
Solon, G., 2002. Cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings mobility. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16:59–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zimmerman, D. J., 1992. Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature. American Economic Review 82:409–29.Google Scholar
Abed, G. T., and Gupta, S. (Eds.), 2002. Governance, Corruption, and Economic Performance. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
Baldacci, E., Hillman, A. L., and , N. Kojo, 2004. Growth, governance, and fiscal-policy transmission channels in low-income countries. European Journal of Political Economy 20:517–49. Reprinted in Gupta, S., Clements, B., and Inchauste, G. (Eds.), 2004. Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, pp. 67–104.Google Scholar
Doucouliagos, H., and Paldam, M., 2008. Aid effectiveness on growth: A meta-study. European Journal of Political Economy 24:1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W., 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Hillman, A. L., 2002. The World Bank and the persistence of poverty in poor countries. European Journal of Political Economy 18:783–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinikka, R., and Svensson, J., 2004. Local capture: Evidence from a central government transfer program in Uganda. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:679–705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fields, G. R., and Ok, E. A., 1999. The measurement of income mobility: An introduction to the literature. In Silver, J. (Ed.), Handbook on Income Inequality. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, pp. 557–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B., 1970. On the measurement of economic inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 2:244–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shorrocks, A. F., 1983. Ranking income distributions. Economica 50:1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J., 1950. A difficulty in the concept of social welfare. Journal of Political Economy 58:328–46. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 147–68.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • SOCIAL JUSTICE
  • Arye L. Hillman, Bar-Ilan University, Israel
  • Book: Public Finance and Public Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813788.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • SOCIAL JUSTICE
  • Arye L. Hillman, Bar-Ilan University, Israel
  • Book: Public Finance and Public Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813788.008
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • SOCIAL JUSTICE
  • Arye L. Hillman, Bar-Ilan University, Israel
  • Book: Public Finance and Public Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813788.008
Available formats
×