Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-19T07:39:21.407Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

9 - Strategic Interaction and Externalities

FD-Games and Pollution

from Part IV - Advances in Explaining and Assessing Institutional Evolution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 November 2018

Ulrich Witt
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute, Jena
Andreas Chai
Affiliation:
Griffith University, Queensland
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Understanding Economic Change
Advances in Evolutionary Economics
, pp. 288 - 308
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aumann, R. 2008. Game Engineering. In: Neogy, S., Bapat, R., Das, A., and Parthasarathy, T. (eds.) Mathematical Programming and Game Theory for Decision Making. Singapore: World Scientific. 279285.Google Scholar
Billingsley, P. 1986. Probability and Measure. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Bjørndal, T. and Gordon, D. V. 1993. The Opportunity Cost of Capital and Optimal Vessel Size in the Norwegian Fishing Fleet. Land Economics, 69, 98107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boncoeur, J., Coglan, L., Le Gallic, B., and Pascoe, S. 2000. On the (Ir)relevance of Rates of Return Measures of Economic Performance to Small Boats. Fisheries Research, 49, 105115.Google Scholar
Brann, P. and Foddy, M. 1987. Trust and the Consumption of a Deteriorating Common Resource. The Journal of Conflict Resolution (1986–1998), 31, 615630.Google Scholar
Brenner, T. and Witt, U. 2003. Melioration Learning in Games with Constant and Frequency-Dependent Pay-offs. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 429448.Google Scholar
Carpenter, S. R., Ludwig, D., and Brock, W. A. 1999. Management of Eutrophication for Lakes Subject to Potentially Irreversible Change. Ecological Applications, 9, 751771.Google Scholar
Dawes, R. M. 1980. Social Dilemmas. The Annual Review of Psychology 31, 169–92.Google Scholar
Dawes, R. M. and Messick, D. M. 2000. Social Dilemmas. International Journal of Psychology, 35, 111116.Google Scholar
Deutsch, M. D. 1978. The Resolution of Conflict. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Döring, R. 2006. Investing in Natural Capital the Case of Fisheries. In: Sumaila, U. R. and Marsden, A. D. (eds.) North American Association of Fisheries Economists Forum Proceedings, 2006 Fisheries Centre, Univ BC, Vancouver, 4964.Google Scholar
Döring, R. and Egelkraut, T. M. 2008. Investing in Natural Capital as Management Strategy in Fisheries: The Case of the Baltic Sea Cod Fishery. Ecological Economics, 64, 634642.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edney, J. J. 1980. The Commons Problem: Alternative Perspectives. American Psychologist, 35, 131150.Google Scholar
Edney, J. J. 1981. Paradoxes on the Commons: Scarcity and the Problem of Equality. Journal of Community Psychology, 9, 334.Google Scholar
Edney, J. J. and Harper, C. S. 1978. The Effects of Information in a Resource Management Problem: A Social Trap Analysis. Human Ecology, 6, 387395.Google Scholar
Forges, F. 1986. An Approach to Communication Equilibria. Econometrica, 54, 13751385.Google Scholar
Gintis, H. 2000. Game Theory Evolving. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hamburger, H. 1973. N-person Prisoner’s Dilemma. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 3, 2748.Google Scholar
Hannesson, R. 1997. Fishing as a Supergame. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, 309322.Google Scholar
Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., and Williams, M. B. 2002. Estimating Individual Discount Rates in Denmark: A Field Experiment. The American Economic Review, 92, 16061617.Google Scholar
Hart, S. 1985. Nonzero-Sum Two-Person Repeated Games with Incomplete Information. Mathematics of Operations Research, 10, 117153.Google Scholar
Haurie, A., Krawczyk, J. B., and Zaccour, G. 2012. Games and Dynamic Games. Singapore: World Scientific.Google Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J. 1997. The Matching Law: Papers in Psychology and Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hillis, J. F. and Wheelan, B. J. 1994. Fisherman’s Time Discounting Rates and Other Actors to Be Taken into Account in Planning Rehabilitation of Depleted Fisheries. In: Antona, M., Catanzano, J., and Sutinen, J. G. (eds.) Proceedings of the 6th Conference of the International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade, 1994 IIFET-Secretariat Paris. 657670.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 1996. Dynamics, Equilibria, and Values. PhD thesis, Maastricht University.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 2005. A Note on Repeated Games with Vanishing Actions. International Game Theory Review, 7, 107115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joosten, R. 2007a. Small Fish Wars and an Authority. In: Prinz, A., Steenge, A. E., and Schmidt, J. (eds.) The Rules of the Game: Institutions, Law, and Economics. Berlin: LiT Verlag. 131162.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 2007b. Small Fish Wars: A New Class of Dynamic Fishery Management Games. ICFAI Journal of Managerial Economics, 5, 1730.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 2009. Strategic Advertisement with Externalities: A New Dynamic Approach. In: Neogy, S. K., Das, A. K., and Bapat, R. B. (eds.) Modeling, Computation and Optimization. Singapore: World Scientific. 2143.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 2014. Social Dilemmas, Time Preferences and Technology Adoption in a Commons Problem. Journal of Bioeconomics, 16, 239258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joosten, R. 2015. Long-run Strategic Advertisement and Short-run Bertrand Competition. International Game Theory Review, 17.Google Scholar
Joosten, R. 2016. Strong and Weak Rarity Value: Resource Games with Complex Price–Scarcity Relationships. Dynamic Games and Applications, 6, 97111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joosten, R., Brenner, T., and Witt, U. 2003. Games with Frequency-Dependent Stage Payoffs. International Journal of Game Theory, 31, 609620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joosten, R. and Meijboom, R. 2010. Stochastic Games with Endogenous Transitions. In: Economics, M. P. I. o. (ed.) Papers on Economics and Evolution. Jena.Google Scholar
Komorita, S. S. and Parks, C. D. 1994. Social Dilemmas. Madison, WI: Brown & Benchmark.Google Scholar
Liebrand, W. B. G. 1983. A Classification of Social Dilemma Games. Simulation and Games, 14, 123138.Google Scholar
Long, N. V. 2010. A Survey of Dynamic Games in Economics. Singapore: World Scientific.Google Scholar
Mäler, K. G., Xepapadeas, A., and De Zeeuw, A. J. 2003. The Economics of Shallow Lakes. Environmental and Resource Economics, 26, 603624.Google Scholar
Messick, D. M. and Brewer, M. B. 1983. Solving Social Dilemmas: A Review. Annual Review of Personality and Social Psychology, 4, 1143.Google Scholar
Messick, D. M., Wilke, H., Brewer, M. B., Kramer, P. M., Zemke, P. E., and Lui, L. 1983. Individual Adaptations and Structural Change as Solutions to Social Dilemmas. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 44, 294309.Google Scholar
Osborne, M. J. and Rubinstein, A. 1994. A Course in Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Platt, J. 1973. Social Traps. American Psychologist, 28, 641651.Google Scholar
Scheffer, M. 1998. The Ecology of Shallow Lakes. London: Chapman & Hall.Google Scholar
Scheffer, M., Carpenter, S., Foley, J. A., Folke, C., and Walker, B. 2001. Catastrophic Shifts in Ecosystems. Nature, 413, 591596.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1978. Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Schoenmakers, G., Flesch, J., and Thuijsman, F. 2002. Coordination Games with Vanishing Actions. International Game Theory Review, 4, 119126.Google Scholar
Shapley, L. 1953. Stochastic Games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 39, 10951100.Google Scholar
Steg, L. 2003. Motives and Behavior in Social Dilemmas Relevant to the Environment. In: Hendrickx, L., Jager, W., and Steg, L. (eds.) Human Decision Making and Environmental Perception. Understanding and Assisting Human Decision Making in Real-Life Settings. Liber Amicorum for Charles Vlek. Groningen: Groningen University.Google Scholar
Van Damme, E. E. C. 1991. Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibria. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Warner, J. T. and Pleeter, S. 2001. The Personal Discount Rate: Evidence from Military Downsizing Programs. The American Economic Review, 91, 3353.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×