Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-dwq4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-28T01:13:42.408Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

14 - Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

from Part V - Foundations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 November 2016

Birger Wernerfelt
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
Foundations of the Resource-Based View
, pp. 253 - 271
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aghion, Philippe, and Tirole, Jean, “Formal and Real Authority in Organizations,” Journal of Political Economy, 105, no. 1, February, 129, 1997.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., The Limits of Organization, New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 1974.Google Scholar
Bajari, Patrick, and Tadelis, Steven, “Incentives versus Transaction Costs: A Theory of Procurement Contracts,” RAND Journal of Economics, 32, no. 3, Autumn, 387407, 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, George P., Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin J., “Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, no. 4, November, 1125–56, 1994.Google Scholar
Baker, George P., Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin J., “Contracting for Control,” Working Paper, Harvard Business School, 2006.Google Scholar
Barnard, Chester I., The Functions of the Executive (Thirtieth Anniversary Edition), Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press, 1968.Google Scholar
Belmont Citizen-Herald, Lexington, MA: Community Newspaper Company, August 7, 2003a.Google Scholar
Belmont Citizen-Herald, Lexington, MA: Community Newspaper Company, August 14, 2003b.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Whinston, Michael D., “Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity,” American Economic Review, 88, no. 4, September, 902–32, 1998.Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick, and Rajan, Ashvin, “The Employment Relation and the Theory of the Firm: Arm’s Length Contracting vs. Authority,” Working Paper, Princeton University, 2001.Google Scholar
Crocker, Keith J., and Reynolds, Kenneth J., “The Efficiency of Incomplete Contracts: An Empirical Analysis of Air Force Engine Procurement,” RAND Journal of Economics, 24, no. 1, Spring, 126–46, 1993.Google Scholar
Dessein, Wouter, “Authority and Communication in Organizations,” Review of Economic Studies, 69, no. 4, 811–38, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewatripont, Mathias, and Tirole, Jean, “Modes of Communication,” Journal of Political Economy, 113, no. 6, December, 1217–38, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dye, Ronald A., “Costly Contract Contingencies,” International Economic Review, 26, no. 1, February, 233–50, 1985.Google Scholar
Gil, Ricard, “The Interplay of Informal, Formal, and Relational Contracts: Evidence from Movies,” Working Paper, University of California, Santa Cruz, 2006.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford, and Hart, Oliver D., “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, no. 4, August, 691719, 1986.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, “Agreeing Now to Agree Later: Contracts that Rule Out but do not Rule In,” Working Paper, Harvard University, 2004.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, “Contracts as Reference Points,” Working Paper, Harvard University, 2006.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von, “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Review, 35, no. 4, 519–30, 1945.Google Scholar
Lieberman, Marvin B., “The Learning Curve and Pricing in the Chemical Processing Industries,” Rand Journal of Economics, 15, no. 2, 231–28, 1984.Google Scholar
MacLeod, W. Bentley, and Malcomson, James M., “Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment,” Econometrica, 57, no. 2, March, 447–80, 1989.Google Scholar
Muth, Richard F., and Wetzler, Elliot, “The Effect of Constraints on House Costs,” Journal of Urban Economics, 3, no. 1, 5767, 1976.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading,” Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–81, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Allan, and Watson, Joel, “The Law and Economics of Costly Contracting,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 20, no. 1, April, 231, 2004.Google Scholar
Segal, Ilya, “Complexity and Renegotiation: A Foundation for Incomplete Contracts,” Review of Economic Studies, 66, no. 1, January, 5782, 1999.Google Scholar
Segal, Ilya, “Communication Complexity and Coordination by Authority,” Advances in Theoretical Economics, 4, Forthcoming, 2006 (www.bepress.com/bejte/advances/).Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven, “The Appeals Process and Adjudicator Incentives,” Journal of Legal Studies, 35, no. 1, 129, 2006 .Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., Administrative Behavior (Third Ed.), New York, NY: The Free Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Spier, Kathryn E.Incomplete Signals and Signalling,” Rand Journal of Economics, 23, no. 3, Autumn, 432–43, 1992 .Google Scholar
Tadelis, Steven, “Complexity, Flexibility, and the Make-or-Buy Decision,” American Economic Review, 92, no.2, May, 433–37, 2002.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “On the Nature and Scope of the Firm: An Adjustment-Cost Theory,” Journal of Business, 70, no. 4, 489514, 1997.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “Delegation, Committees, and Managers,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 16, no. 1, Spring, 3551, 2007.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “Bargaining Before or After Communication?Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 164, no. 2, June, 211–29, 2008 .CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “The Comparative Advantages of Firms, Markets, and Contracts: A Unified Theory,” Economica, 82, no. 329, 350657, 2015.Google Scholar
Zbaracki, Mark J., Ritson, Mark, Levy, Daniel, Dutta, Shantanu, and Bergen, Mark, “Managerial and Customer Costs of Price Adjustment: Direct Evidence from Industrial Markets,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 86, no. 2, May, 514–33, 2004.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×