Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-dwq4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-28T01:16:58.505Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part II - The Main Argument

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 November 2016

Birger Wernerfelt
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
Foundations of the Resource-Based View
, pp. 31 - 112
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Alchian, Armen A., and Demsetz, Harold, “Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization,” American Economic Review, 62, December, 777–95, 1972.Google Scholar
Allen, Terry F., An Analysis of Food Brokers Versus Grocery Manufacturers’ Sales Forces. D.B.A. thesis, University of Virginia, 1984.Google Scholar
Anderson, Erin, The Salesperson as outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis. Working paper. Cambridge, Mass.: Marketing Science Institute, pp. 84107, August, 1984.Google Scholar
Anderson, Erin, “The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis,” Marketing Science, 4, Summer, 234–54, 1985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Erin, and Schmittlein, David C., “Integration of the Salesforce: An Empirical Examination,” RAND Journal of Economics, 15, Autumn, 385–95, 1984.Google Scholar
Aoki, M., “Horizontal vs. Vertical Information Structure of the Firm,” American Economic Review, 76, December, 971–83, 1986.Google Scholar
Barnard, Chester, The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1938.Google Scholar
Ben-Porath, Yoram, “The F-Connection: Family, Friends, and Firms and the Organization of Exchange,” Population and Development Review, 6, March, 130, 1980.Google Scholar
Broadcast Music Inc. v. Columbia Broadcast System, 441 U.S. Report, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, n.s., 4, November, 386405, 1937.Google Scholar
Directory of Corporate Affiliations. New Providence, N.J.: National Register Publishing, 1996.Google Scholar
Dutta, Shantanu, Bergen, Mark, Heide, Jan B., and John, George, “Understanding Dual Distribution: The Case of Reps and House Accounts,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, April, 189204, 1995.Google Scholar
Etgar, Michael, “Effects of Administrative Control on Efficiency of Vertical Marketing Systems,” Journal of Marketing Research, 13, February, 1224, 1976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenoaltea, Stefano, “Slavery and Supervision in Comparative Perspective: A Model,” Journal of Economic History, 44, September, 635–68, 1984.Google Scholar
Garvey, Gerald, and Swan, Peter L., The Fable of the Barge-pullers: An Advantage of Capitalistic over Worker-owned Organizations, Mimeographed. Sidney: University of New South Wales, 1992.Google Scholar
Gresik, Thomas A., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “The Rate at Which a Simple Market Converges to Efficiency as the Number of Traders Increases: An Asymptotic Result for Optimal Trading Mechanisms,” Journal of Economic Theory, 48, 304–32, 1989.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford, and Hart, Oliver D., “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, August, 691719, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grout, Paul A., “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach,” Econometrica, 52, March, 449–60, 1984.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., “An Economist’s Perspective on the Theory of the Firm,” Columbia Law Review, 89, November, 1757–74, 1989.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy 98, December, 1119–58, 1990.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, “The Firm as an Incentive System,” American Economic Review, 84, September, 972–91, 1994.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid, “Optimality and Informational Efficiency in Resource Allocation Mechanisms,” in Arrow, Kenneth, Karlin, Samuel, and Suppes, Patrick (eds.), Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid, “On Informationally Decentralized Systems,” in McGuire, C. Bartlett and Radner, Roy (eds.), Decision and Organization, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1972.Google Scholar
Klein, Saul, Frazier, Gary L., and Roth, Victor J., “A Transaction Cost Analysis Model of Channel Integration in International Markets,” Journal of Marketing Research, 27, May, 196208, 1990.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M., “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” in Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Lilien, Gary L., “ADVISOR 2: Modelling the Marketing Mix Decision for Industrial Products,” Management Science, 25, February, 191204, 1979.Google Scholar
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean, “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts,” Review of Economic Studies, 66, 83114, 1999.Google Scholar
Masten, Scott E., “A Legal Basis for the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4, Spring, 181–98, 1988.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity,” in Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading,” Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–81, 1983.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, “The Organization of Decentralized Information Processing,” Econometrica, 61, September, 1109–46, 1993.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, and Van Zandt, Timothy, “Information Processing in Firms and Returns to Scale,” Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 25, no. 26, 265–98, 1992.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, and Van Zandt, Timothy, “Information Processing and Returns to Scale in Statistical Decision Problems,” Mimeographed, Murray Hill, N.J.: AT&T Bell Labs, 1993.Google Scholar
Schotter, Andrew, The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., “A Formal Theory of the Employment Relationship,” Econometrica, 19, July, 293305, 1951.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., Administrative Behaviour, 3rd edition, New York: Free Press 1976.Google Scholar
Stephens, M., Bibliography of Information Sources on Manufacturers’ Representatives, Geneva, Ill.: Manufacturers’ Representatives Educational Research Foundation, 1993.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., “The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 59, June, 185–93, 1951.Google Scholar
Taylor, Ronald K., Profiling Differences between Manufacturers’ Representatives and Direct Company Salespeople: An Exploratory Study, D.B.A. thesis, University of Indiana, 1988.Google Scholar
Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service, Business Reporting Publication 937, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of the Treasury, 1990.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “Hierarchical Control and Optimum Firm Size,” Journal of Political Economy, 75, April, 123–38, 1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “Transaction-cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations,” Journal of Law and Economics, 22, October, 223–61, 1979.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free Press, 1985.Google Scholar

References

Antras, Pol, and Helpman, Elhanan, “Global Sourcing,” Journal of Political Economy, 112, no. 3, 552–80, 2004.Google Scholar
Atalay, Enghin, Hortacsu, Ali, and Syverson, Chad, “Vertical Integration and Input Flows,” American Economic Review, 104, no. 4, April, 1120–48, 2014.Google Scholar
Bajari, Patrick, and Tadelis, Steven, “Incentives versus Transaction Costs: A theory of Procurement Contracts,” RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 387407, 2001.Google Scholar
Baker, George P., Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin M., “Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 3983, 2002.Google Scholar
Barzel, Yoram, “Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets,” Journal of Law and Economics, 25, 2748, 1982.Google Scholar
Board, Simon, “Relational Contracts and the Value of Loyalty,” American Economic Review, 101, 3349–67, 2011.Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick, and Rajan, Ashvin, “The Employment Relation and the Theory of the Firm: Arm’s Length Contracting versus Authority,” Working Paper, Princeton University, 2001.Google Scholar
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Hitt, Lorn M., “Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation, and Business Performance,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 2348, 2000.Google Scholar
Busse, Meghan, Silva-Risso, Jorge, and Zettelmeyer, Florian, “$1000 Cash Back: The Pass-Through of Auto Manufacturer Promotions,” American Economic Review, 96, 1253–70, 2006.Google Scholar
Calzolari, Giacomo, and Spagnolo, Giancarlo, “Relational Contracting and Competitive Screening,” Working Paper, University of Bologna, 2009.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H.The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, n.s. 4, 386405, 1937.Google Scholar
Cremer, Jacques, Spiegel, Yossi, and Zheng, Charles Z., “Auctions with Costly Information Acquisition,” Economic Theory, 38, 4172, 2009.Google Scholar
Dessein, Wouter, and Santos, Tano, “Adaptive Organizations,” Journal of Political Economy, 114, 956–95, 2006.Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Hart, Oliver D., and Zehnder, Christian, “Contracts, Reference Points, and Competition: Behavioral Consequences of the Fundamental Transformation,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 7, 561–72, 2009.Google Scholar
Gibbons, Robert, Holden, Richard, and Powell, Michael, “Organization and Information: Firms’ Governance Choices in Rational-Expectations Equilibrium,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1813–41, 2012.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan, “Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 85120, 2002.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford, and Hart, Oliver D., “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691719, 1986.Google Scholar
Guasch, J., Luis, , Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions: Doing it Right, Washington DC: World Bank Publications, 2004.Google Scholar
Halac, Marina, “Relational Contracts and the Value of Relationships,” American Economic Review, 102, 750–79, 2012.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. and Moore, John, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1119–58, 1990.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, “Contracts as Reference Points,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123, 148, 2008.Google Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan, Melitz, Marc J., and Yeaple, Stephen R., “Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms,” American Economic Review, 94, 300–16, 2004.Google Scholar
Hortacsu, Ali, and Syverson, Chad, “Cementing Relationships: Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, Productivity, and Prices,” Journal of Political Economy, 115, 250300, 2007.Google Scholar
Jackson, Matthew O., and Sonnenschein, Hugo F., “Overcoming Incentive Constraints by Linking Decisions,” Econometrica, 75, 241–57, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E., “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms,” Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 508–23, 1978.Google Scholar
Maciejovsky, Boris, and Wernerfelt, Birger, “Costs of Implementation: Bargaining Costs versus Allocative Efficiency,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 77, 318–25, 2011.Google Scholar
Macleod, W. B., and Malcomson, J. M., “Reputation and Hierarchy in Dynamic Models of Employment,” Journal of Political Economy, 96, 832–54, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean, “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts,” Review of Economic Studies, 66, 83114, 1999.Google Scholar
Matouschek, Niko, “Ex Post Inefficiencies in a Property Rights Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 20, 125–47, 2004.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading,” Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–81, 1983.Google Scholar
Rosen, SherwinSpecialization and Human Capital,” Journal of Labor Economics, 1, 4349, 1983.Google Scholar
Simester, Duncan I., and Knez, Mark, “Direct and Indirect Bargaining Costs and the Scope of the Firm,” Journal of Business, 72, 283304, 2002.Google Scholar
Social Security Administration, U.S. Government, Online Social Security Handbook, 2009: http://socialsecurity.gov/OP_Home/handbook/handbook.08/handbook-0802.html.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations, New York, NY: Modern Library, 1965.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., “The Division of Labor Is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 59, 185–93, 1951.Google Scholar
Taylor, Curtis R., and Wiggins, Steven N., “Competition of Compensation: Supplier Incentives Under the American and Japanese Subcontracting Systems,” American Economic Review, 87, 598618, 1997.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “Inefficient Pre-Bargaining Search,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 168, 211–23, 2012.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations,” American Economic Review, 61, 112–23, 1971.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York, NY: The Free Press, 1975.Google Scholar

References

Atalay, Enghin, Hortacsu, Ali, and Syverson, Chad, “Vertical Integration and Input Flows,” American Economic Review, 104, no. 4, April, 1120–48, 2014.Google Scholar
Conner, Kathleen R., “A Historical Comparison of Resource-Based Theory and Five Schools of Thought within Industrial Organization Economics: Do We Have a New Theory of the Firm?Journal of Management, 17, no. 1, March, 121–54, 1991.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and Milgrom, P., “The Firm as an Incentive System,” American Economic Review, 84, September, 972–91, 1994.Google Scholar
Maciejovsky, Boris, and Wernerfelt, Birger, “Costs of Implementation: Bargaining Costs versus Allocative Efficiency,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 77, no. 3, March, 318–25, 2011.Google Scholar
Montgomery, Cynthia A., and Hariharan, Sam, “Diversified Expansion by Large Established 1959. Firms,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 15, no. 1, 7189, 1991.Google Scholar
Montgomery, Cynthia A., and Wernerfelt, Birger, “Diversification, Ricardian Rents, and Tobin’s q,” RAND Journal of Economics, 19, no. 4, Winter, 623–32, 1988.Google Scholar
Penrose, Edith, A Theory of the Growth of the Firm, New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons, 1959.Google Scholar
Rosen, Sherwin, “Substitution and the Division of Labor,” Economica, 45, no. 179, August, 235–50, 1978.Google Scholar
Sappington, David, and Wernerfelt, Birger, “To Brand or Not to Brand? A Theoretical and Empirical Question,” Journal of Business, 58, no. 3, July, 279–93, 1985.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., “A Formal Theory of the Employment Relationship,” Econometrica, 19, July, 293305, 1951.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, The Wealth of Nations, New York, NY: Modern Library, 1965.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., “The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 59, no. 3, June, 185–93, 1951.Google Scholar
Teece, David J., “Towards an Economic Theory of the Multi-Product Firm,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, no. 1, March, 3963, 1982.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal, 5, no. 3, June, 224–32, 1967.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “On the Nature and Scope of the Firm: An Adjustment-Cost Theory,” Journal of Business, 70, no. 4, October, 489514, 1997.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “The Comparative Advantages of Firms, Markets, and Contracts: A Unified Theory,” Economica, 82, April, 350–67, 2015.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “A Resource-based View of the Firm,” Strategic Management Journal, 5, 171–80, 1984.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, and Montgomery, Cynthia A., “Tobin’s q and the Importance of Focus in Firm Performance,” American Economic Review, 78, no. 1, March, 246–50, 1988.Google Scholar

References

Andrews, Kenneth, The Concept of Corporate Strategy, Homewood, Ill.,: Dow Jones-Irwin, 1971.Google Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab K., “On Optimum Subsidy to a Learning Industry: An Aspect of the Theory of Infant Industry Protection,” International Economic Review, 12, 5470, 1971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, Jay B., “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage,” Journal of Management, 17, no. 1, March, 89120, 1991.Google Scholar
IC Pen Corporation (A), Intercollegiate Case Clearing House, 1–374-305, 1974.Google Scholar
Boston Consulting Group, Perspectives on Experience, Boston: Boston Consulting Group, 1972.Google Scholar
Business Week, December 14, 1981.Google Scholar
Caves, Richard E., “Industrial Organization, Corporate Strategy and Structure,” Journal of Economic Literature, 58, 6492, 1980.Google Scholar
Henderson, Bruce D., Henderson on Corporate Strategy, Cambridge, Mass.,: Abt Books, 1979.Google Scholar
Penrose, Edith G., The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, New York: Wiley, 1959.Google Scholar
Ries, Al, and Trout, Jack, Positioning: The Battle for Your Mind, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1981.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., “The Expansion of Firms,” Journal of Political Economy, 81, 936–49, 1973.Google Scholar
Salter, Malcolm, and Weinhold, Wolf, Diversification by Acquisition, New York: Free Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Spence, A. Michael, “Investment Strategy and Growth in a New Market,” Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 119, 1979.Google Scholar
Teece, David J., “Towards an Economic Theory of the Multi-Product Firm,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, no. 1, March, 3963, 1982.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger, “The Use of Resources in Resource Acquisition,” Journal of Management, 37, no. 5, September, 1369–73, 2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • The Main Argument
  • Birger Wernerfelt, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
  • Book: Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 03 November 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316466872.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • The Main Argument
  • Birger Wernerfelt, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
  • Book: Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 03 November 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316466872.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • The Main Argument
  • Birger Wernerfelt, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
  • Book: Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 03 November 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316466872.004
Available formats
×