Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-495rp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-09T14:14:43.843Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - The Judiciary and Private Rights

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2013

Paul D. Moreno
Affiliation:
Hillsdale College, Michigan
Get access

Summary

DISTRIBUTION AND SUBSIDY

Republican policy-making abated after 1875, when the party lost its fourteen-year control of Congress and the presidency. For the next two decades, with only brief exceptions (1889–91 for the Republicans and 1893–95 for the Democrats), the parties shared federal political power. This enhanced the power of the federal judiciary, which was dominated by Republicans. The only Democratic president in those years, Grover Cleveland, tended to appoint judges with an orientation similar to the Republicans. This had led historians in the populist–progressive–New Deal tradition to claim that the judicial branch and legal system promoted the class interests of big business. Republican policy on the tariff, finance, and railroads contributed the more visible, public-law part of their program of class rule, they argued. Less noticed was the Republican judiciary’s use of such private-law doctrines as torts and contracts to buttress this system.

The federal judiciary’s private-law doctrine occasionally provoked political contention in the Gilded Age and progressive era, but only became a subject for legal historians later in the twentieth century. It flowed from the turn of legal historians from “internal” to “external” analysis of the law’s development. The common-law tradition had explained the development of law almost exclusively from legal sources – precedent cases above all; also statutes and official commentary. In the middle of the twentieth century, following the insights of sociological jurisprudence, legal realism, pragmatism, and other progressive legal theories, J. Willard Hurst began to interpret legal history in light of external political, social, and economic factors. Hurst explained that – far from adhering to laissez-faire – nineteenth-century Americans used the law and judges changed legal principles in order to facilitate economic development.

Type
Chapter
Information
The American State from the Civil War to the New Deal
The Twilight of Constitutionalism and the Triumph of Progressivism
, pp. 23 - 31
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Gregory, Charles O., “Trespass to Negligence to Absolute Liability,”Virginia Law Review 37 (1951), 368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Robert W., “Introduction: J. Willard Hurst and the Common Law Tradition in American Legal Historiography,”Law and Society Review 10 (1975), 12, 28, 45Google Scholar
Law and the Conditions of Freedom in the Nineteenth-Century United States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1956)
Holt, Wythe, “Morton Horwitz and the Transformation of American Legal History,”William and Mary Law Review 23 (1982), 665Google Scholar
Kloppenberg, James T., “The Theory and Practice of American Legal History,”Harvard Law Review 106 (1993), 1339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belz, Herman, “Constitutional and Legal History in the 1980s: Reflections on American Constitutionalism,” in A Living Constitution or Fundamental Law: American Constitutionalism in Historical Perspective (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 1998), 169Google Scholar
Horwitz, Morton, The Transformation of American Law, 1780–1860 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977), 70, 235Google Scholar
Scheiber, Harry, “Federalism and the American Economic Order, 1789–1910,”Law and Society Review 10 (1975), 65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Lawrence M., A History of American Law (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1973), 14Google Scholar
Kelly, Alfred H., Harbison, Winfred A., and Belz, Herman, The American Constitution: Its Origin and Development, 7th ed. (New York: Norton, 1991), 239Google Scholar
Schwartz, Gary, “Tort Law and the Economy in Nineteenth Century America: A Reinterpretation,”Yale Law Journal 90 (1981), 1727CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A., “The Historical Origins and Economic Structure of Workers’ Compensation Law,”Georgia Law Review 16 (1982), 777–79Google Scholar
Rabin, Robert L., “The Historical Development of the Fault Principle: A Reinterpretation,”Georgia Law Review 15 (1981), 942; Schwartz, “Tort Law,” 1720Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A., “A Theory of Negligence,”Journal of Legal Studies 1 (1972), 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karsten, Peter, Heart versus Head: Judge-Made Law in Nineteenth Century America (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1997), 299, 35, 3Google ScholarPubMed
Wheeler, Stanton et al., “Do the ‘Haves’ Come Out Ahead? Winning and Losing in State Supreme Courts, 1870–1970,”Law and Society Review 21 (1987), 442–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, Mark Warren, Guardians of the Moral Order: The Legal Philosophy of the Supreme Court, 1860–1910 (De Kalb: Northern Illinois University Press, 2004)Google Scholar
Hovenkamp, Herbert, “The Political Economy of Substantive Due Process,”Stanford Law Review 40 (1988), 420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karsten, , “Explaining the Fight over the Attractive Nuisance Doctrine: A Kinder, Gentler Instrumentalism in the ‘Age of Formalism,’Law and History Review 10 (1992), 79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
“Vices of the Political System of the United States,” Apr. 1787, in The Papers of James Madison, ed. Hutchinson, William T. et al., 10 vols. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962–77), IX: 349–50Google Scholar
Hendrickson, David C., Peace Pact: The Lost World of the American Founding (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 2003), 214Google Scholar
Warren, Charles, “New Light on the History of the Federal Judiciary Act of 1789,”Harvard Law Review 37 (1923), 55, 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Main, Jackson Turner, The Antifederalists: Critics of the Constitution, 1781–88 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1961), 155–58Google Scholar
Friendly, Henry J., “The Historic Basis of Diversity Jurisdiction,”Harvard Law Review 41 (1928), 487CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Documentary History of the Ratification of the Constitution, ed. Kaminski, John P. et al., 22 vols. to date (Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin, 1993–2008), X: 1422, 1429, 1414, 1434
Jay, Stewart, “Origins of Federal Common Law: Part Two,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 133 (1985) 1263Google Scholar
Ritz, Wilfred J., Rewriting the History of the Judiciary Act of 1789: Exposing Myths, Challenging Premises, and Using New Evidence, ed. Holt, Wythe and LaRue, L. H. (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1990), 146Google Scholar
Freyer, Tony A., Forums of Order: The Federal Courts and Business in American History (Little Rock: University of Arkansas Press, 1979), 46Google Scholar
Freyer, , Harmony and Dissonance: The Swift and Erie Cases in American Federalism (New York: New York University Press, 1981), 29–31Google Scholar
“The Kentucky Resolutions,” 16 Nov. 1798, in Major Problems in American Constitutional History, ed. Hall, Kermit, 2 vols. (Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath, 1992), I: 234
Jay, Stewart, “Origins of Federal Common Law: Part One,”University of Pennsylvania Law Review 133 (1985), 1012–19Google Scholar
Freyer, Tony A., Forums of Order: The Federal Courts and Business in American History (Little Rock: University of Arkansas Press, 1979), xix, 102Google Scholar
LaPiana, William P., “Swift v. Tyson and the Brooding Omnipresence in the Sky: An Investigation of the Idea of Law in Antebellum America,” Suffolk University Law Review 20 (1986), 795Google Scholar
Bensel, Richard F., The Political Economy of American Industrialization, 1877–1900 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 321CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wendell, Mitchell, Relations Between the Federal and State Courts (New York: Columbia University Press, 1949), 159Google Scholar
Greve, Michael, The Upside-Down Constitution (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2012), 59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charles, and Beard, Mary made this charge in The Rise of American Civilization, 2 vols. (New York: Macmillan, 1927), II: 113Google Scholar
Graham, Howard Jay, “The ‘Conspiracy Theory’ of the Fourteenth Amendment,” Yale Law Journal 47 (1938), 371–403 and 48 (1938), 171–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beatty, Jack, The Age of Betrayal: The Triumph of Money in America, 1865–1900 (New York: Knopf, 2007)Google Scholar
Purcell, Edward A., Jr., Litigation and Inequality: Federal Diversity Jurisdiction in Industrial America, 1870–1958 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992), 26, 58, 86, 63Google Scholar
Soifer, Aviam, “The Paradox of Paternalism and Laissez-Faire Constitutionalism: United States Supreme Court, 1888–1921,” Law and History Review 5 (1987), 254CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fairman, Charles, Reconstruction and Reunion, 1864–88, Part Two (New York: Macmillan, 1987), 593Google Scholar
Kens, Paul, Justice Stephen Field: Shaping Liberty from the Gold Rush to the Gilded Age (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1997), 226Google Scholar
Brodhead, Michael J., David J. Brewer: The Life of a Supreme Court Justice, 1837–1910 (Carbondale: University of Southern Illinois Press, 1994), 109Google Scholar
Reeder, Robert P., “Chief Justice Fuller,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review and Law Register 59 (1910), 11Google Scholar
Porter, Mary Cornelia, “That Commerce Shall be Free: A New Look at the Old Laissez-Faire Court,” Supreme Court Review (1976), 142Google Scholar
Holmes, Jr Oliver Wendell., to Sir Pollock, Frederick, 29 Mar. 1922, in Holmes-Pollock Letters: The Correspondence of Mr. Justice Holmes and Sir Frederick Pollock, 1874–1932, ed. Howe, Mark DeWolfe, 2 vols. (Cambridge, MA: Belknap, 1961), II: 92Google Scholar
Heckman, Charles A., “Uniform Commercial Law in the Nineteenth Century Federal Courts: The Decline and Abuse of the Swift Doctrine,”Emory Law Journal 27 (1978), 58–60Google Scholar
Sherry, Suzanna, “Wrong, Out of Step, and Pernicious: Erie as the Worst Decision of All Time,” Pepperdine Law Review 39 (2012), 138Google Scholar
Kelly, Alfred H., “Constitutional Liberty and the Law of Libel: A Historian’s View,” American Historical Review 74 (1968), 439;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freyer, Tony A., “The Federal Courts, Localism, and the National Economy, 1865–1900,”Business History Review 53 (1979), 343–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×