Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-g5fl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-29T09:23:48.809Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - ROYAL PROFIT AND THE PRIVILEGES OF THE ANCIENT DEMESNE, 1200–65

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 December 2009

Marjorie Keniston McIntosh
Affiliation:
University of Colorado, Boulder
Get access

Summary

At the opening of the thirteenth century the tenants of Havering enjoyed many forms of personal, tenurial and legal freedom. They could give their daughters in marriage without the permission of the lord and were not subject to punishment for lapses in the chastity of local women. They could leave the manor temporarily or permanently whenever they wished. They were free to buy, sell, lease or subdivide their land at will. Those who held directly from the crown owed only trivial labour in the royal fields within the manor. Should a dispute arise concerning their land, Havering people could bring legal action either before the king's central court or within their own manorial assembly.

Havering was also accustomed to considerable independence from seigneurial control. The king had no regular agent within the community to look after royal rights and profits. The chief functional officer was the manorial bailiff, a man chosen from among Havering's wealthier tenants who had no reason to place the crown's interests above those of his fellows. Income from the manor, submitted to the crown by the sheriff or the person to whom the king had granted the farm of Havering, was in practice collected by the bailiff. Royal justices occasionally inquired about the crown's personal property within Havering or about assarting from the woodlands. Such commissions were a threat, but at least they were rare. Neglect by the king must have been accepted by Havering's residents in the years around 1200 as traditional and proper.

Type
Chapter
Information
Autonomy and Community
The Royal Manor of Havering, 1200–1500
, pp. 13 - 49
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×