Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-23T10:29:43.530Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2010

Hal R. Varian
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Joseph Farrell
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Carl Shapiro
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Economics of Information Technology
An Introduction
, pp. 87 - 96
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alessandro Acquisti and Hal R. Varian, 2001. Conditioning prices on purchase history. Technical report, School of Information Management, University of California at Berkeley
William, James Adams and Janet, L. Yellen, 1976. Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90 (3): 475–498Google Scholar
Mark, Armstrong, 1999. Price discrimination by a many-product firm. Review of Economic Studies, 66 (1): 151–168Google Scholar
Mark, Armstrong and John, Vickers, 2001. Competitive price discrimination. RAND Journal of Economics, 32 (4): 579–605; http://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/people/armstrong/markpapers.htmlGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, M. Ausubel, 1991. The failure of competition in the credit card market. American Economic Review, 81 (1): 50–81Google Scholar
Charles Babcock, 2001. Will open source get snagged in .NET? ZDNet News, 6 August; http://www.zdnet.com/zdnn/stories/news/0,4586,2801560,00.html
Mark Bagnoli and Ted Bergstrom, 1989. Log-concave probability and its application. Unpublished working paper; http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Theory/delta.pdf
G. Baker and T. Hubbard, 2000. Contractibility and asset ownership: Computers and governance in the US trucking industry. Technical Report 7634, National Bureau of Economic Research
Yannis, Bakos and Erik, Brynjolfsson, 1999. Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits and efficiency. Management Science, 45 (12): 1613–1630Google Scholar
Yannis, Bakos and Erik, Brynjolfsson, 2000. Bundling and competition on the Internet: Aggregation strategies for information goods. Marketing Science, 19 (1): 63–82; http://ebusiness.mit.edu/erik/Google Scholar
Yannis Bakos and Erik Brynjolfsson, 2001. Aggregation and disaggregation of information goods: Implications for bundling, site licensing and micropayment systems. In Brian Kahin and Hal R. Varian, eds., Internet Publishing and Beyond: The Economics of Digital Information and Intellectual Property. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA; http://ebusiness.mit.edu/erik/
M. Baye and John Morgan, 2001. Price dispersion in the lab and on the Internet: Theory and evidence. Technical report, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University; http://www.princeton.edu/~rjmorgan/working.htm
M. Baye, J. Morgan, and P. Scholten, 2001. Price dispersion in the small and in the large: Evidence from an Internet price comparison site. Technical report, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University; http://www.princeton.edu/~rjmorgan/working.htm
Alan, Beggs and Paul, Klemperer, 1992. Multi-period competition with switching costs. Econometrica, 60 (3): 651–666Google Scholar
Stanley, Besen and Joseph, Farrell, 1994. Choosing how to compete: Strategies and tactics in standardization. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (2): 117–131Google Scholar
Robert Boynton, 2004. The tyranny of copyright. New York Times Magazine, 25 January
Adam M. Brandenburger and Barry J. Nalebuff, 1996. Co-opetition. Doubleday, New York
Timothy, Bresnahan and Trajtenberg, M., 1995. General Purpose Technologies: Engines of growth?Journal of Econometrics, 65 (1): 83–108Google Scholar
Gerald Brock, 1981. The Telecommunications Industry: The Dynamics of Market Structure. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
Erik, Brynjolfsson and Lorin, M. Hitt, 2000. Beyond computation: Information technology, organizational transformation and business performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14 (4): 23–48Google Scholar
Erik, Brynjolfsson and Michael, Smith, 1999. Frictionless commerce? A comparison of Internet and conventional retailers. Management Science, 46 (4): 563–585; http://ebusiness.mit.edu/erik/Google Scholar
Nicholas G. Carr, 2003. IT doesn't matter. Harvard Business Review, May
Nicholas G. Carr, 2004. Does IT Matter? Harvard Business School Press, Boston
Pei-Yu (Sharon) Chen and Lorin M. Hitt, 2001. Measuring the determinants of switching costs: A study of the on-line brokerage industry. Technical report, Wharton School
Clayton Christensen, 1997. The Innovator's Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail. Harvard Business School Press, Boston
Ronald, Coase, 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4: 386–405Google Scholar
Ronald, Coase, 1972. Durability and monopoly. Journal of Law and Economics, 15 (1): 143–149Google Scholar
Wesley M. Cohen and Stephen A. Merrill, eds., 2004. Patents in the Knowledge Based Economy, Committee on Intellectual Property Rights in the Knowledge-Based Economy, Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy, Policy and Global Affairs, National Research Council of the National Academies of Science, The National Academies Press, Washington, DC
Wesley Cohen, Richard Nelson, and John Walsh, 2000. Protecting their intellectual assets: Appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not). National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 7552
Augustin Cournot, 1838. Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses. Hachette, Paris
Alan, Cowell, 2001. Profit soars at SAP. New York Times, 20 JulyGoogle Scholar
J. Dana and K. Spier, 2000. Revenue sharing, demand uncertainty, and control of competing firms. Technical report, Northwestern University
Paul, A. David, 1990. The dynamo and the computer: An historical perspective on the modern productivity paradox. American Economic Review, 80: 355–361Google Scholar
J. Bradford Delong and A. Michael Froomkin, 2001. Speculative microeconomics for tomorrow's economy. In Brian Kahin and Hal R. Varian, eds., Internet Publishing and Beyond: The Economics of Digital Information and Intellectual Property. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA; http://www.j-bradford/delong.net/OpEd/virtual/technet/spmicro.html
Raymond, Deneckere and Preston, McAfee, 1996. Damaged goods. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 5 (2): 149–174Google Scholar
David Dranove and Neil Gandal, 2000. The DVD vs. DIVX standard war: Empirical evidence of vaporware. Technical Report CPC00–16, University of California at Berkeley
Phred Dvorak, Nick Wingfield, and Sarah McBride, 2004. Technology titans battle over format of DVD successor. Wall Street Journal, 15 March
Nicholas, Economides, 1996. The economics of networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16 (4): 673–699; http://raven.stern.nyu.edu/networks/Google Scholar
Nicholas Economides and Charles Himmelberg, 1995. Critical mass and network size with application to the US fax market. Technical report, Stern School of Business, New York University; http://raven.stern.nyu.edu/networks/papers.html
Glenn Ellison and Sara Fisher Ellison, 2001. Search, obfuscation, and price elasticities on the Internet. Technical report, Department of Economics, MIT
Joseph Farrell and Paul Klemperer, 2003. Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects. In Mark Armstrong and Rob Porter, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. III. Amsterdam, North-Holland; http://www.paulklemperer.org
Joseph, Farrell and Robert, Merges 2004. Incentives to challenge and defend patents. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, forthcomingGoogle Scholar
Joseph, Farrell and Garth, Saloner, 1992. Converters, compatibility, and the control of interfaces. Journal of Industrial Economics, March: 9–35Google Scholar
Joseph, Farrell and Carl, Shapiro, 1988. Dynamic competition with switching costs. Rand Journal of Economics, 19: 123–137Google Scholar
Joseph, Farrell and Carl, Shapiro, 1989. Optimal contracts with lock-in. American Economic Review, 79 (1): 51–68Google Scholar
Joseph, Farrell and Philip, J. Weiser, 2003. Modularity, vertical integration, and open access policies: Towards a convergence of antitrust and regulation in the internet age. Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 17 (1): 85–135Google Scholar
Federal Trade Commission, 2003. To promote innovation: The proper balance of competition and patent law and policy; http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/10/cpreport.htm
Drew, Fudenberg and Jean, Tirole, 1985. Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology. Review of Economic Studies, 52: 383–402Google Scholar
Drew, Fudenberg and Jean, Tirole, 1987. Understanding rent dissipation: On the uses of game theory in industrial organization. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 77: 176–183Google Scholar
Drew, Fudenberg and Jean, Tirole, 1998. Upgrades, trade-ins, and buy-backs. Rand Journal of Economics, 29: 238–258Google Scholar
Drew, Fudenberg and Jean, Tirole, 2000. Customer poaching and brand switching. Rand Journal of Economics, 31: 634–657Google Scholar
Nancy, Gallini, 2002. The economics of patents: Lessons from recent US patent reform. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16 (2): 131–154Google Scholar
Nancy Gallini and Suzanne Scotchmer, 2001. Intellectual property: When is it the best incentive system? In Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds., Innovation Policy and the Economy, vol. II. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
Richard, J. Gilbert and Michael, L. Katz, 2001. An economist's guide to US v. Microsoft. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (2): 25–44Google Scholar
S. Colum Gilfillan, 1935. Inventing the Ship. Follett, Chicago
Austan Goolsbee and Peter J. Klenow, 2000. Evidence on learning and network externalities in the diffusion of home computers. Technical report, University of Chicago; http://gsbadg.uchicago.edu/vitae.htm
Robert, J. Gordon, 2000. Does the “New Economy” measure up to the great inventions of the past?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14 (4): 49–74Google Scholar
Amy R. Greenwald and Jeffrey O. Kephart, 1999. Shopbots and pricebots. Technical report, IBM Watson Labs; http://www.research.ibm.com/infoecon/paps/html/amec99_shopbot/shopbot.html
Ward, Hanson, 1998. The original WWW: Web lessons from the early days of radio. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 12 (3): 46–56; http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/issuetoc?ID=79208Google Scholar
E. Helpman, 1998. General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
Arye, Hillman and John, G. Riley, 1989. Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1: 17–39Google Scholar
David A. Hounshell, 1984. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore
Thomas, N. Hubbard, 2000. The demand for monitoring technologies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, May: 533–560Google Scholar
Maarten C. W. Janssen and José Luis Moraga-González, 2001. Two firms is enough for competition, but three or more is better. Technical report, Rotterdam University
Matthew Josephson, 1959. Edison: A Biography. McGraw-Hill, New York
Michael, L. Katz and Carl, Shapiro, 1985. Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75 (3): 424–440Google Scholar
Michael, L. Katz and Carl, Shapiro, 1986a. Product compatibility choice in a market with technological progress. Oxford Economic Papers, 38 (Special Issue on the New Industrial Economics): 146–165Google Scholar
Michael, L. Katz and Carl, Shapiro, 1986b. Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities. Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4): 822–884Google Scholar
Michael, L. Katz and Carl, Shapiro, 1992. Product introduction with network externalities. Journal of Industrial Economics, 40: 55–84Google Scholar
Michael, L. Katz and Carl, Shapiro, 1994. Systems competition and network effects. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (2): 93–115Google Scholar
Stuart Kauffman, 1995. At Home in the Universe: The Search for the Laws of Self-Organization and Complexity. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Moshe, Kim, Doron, Kliger, and Bent, Vale, 2003. Estimating switching costs: The case of banking. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 12 (1): 25–56Google Scholar
Benjamin, Klein, 2001. The Microsoft case: What can a dominant firm do to defend its market position?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (2): 45–62Google Scholar
Paul, Klemperer, 1987. Markets with consumer switching costs. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102 (2): 375–394Google Scholar
Paul, Klemperer, 1989. Price wars caused by switching costs. Review of Economic Studies, 56 (3): 405–420Google Scholar
Paul, Klemperer, 1995. Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 62: 515–539; http://www.paulklemperer.org/index.htmGoogle Scholar
Kortum, S. and Lerner, J., 1998. Stronger protection or technological revolution: What is behind the recent surge in patenting?Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48: 247–304Google Scholar
Alex Kuczynski, 2001. Big magazines get bigger as small ones get gobbled up. New York Times, 30 July; http://www.nytimes.com/2001/07/30/business/30MAG.html?pagewanted=print
, S. J. Leibowitz and Stephen, Margolis, 1990. The fable of the keys. Journal of Law and Economics, 33: 1–26Google Scholar
Mark, Lemley, 2001. Rational ignorance at the patent office. Northwestern University Law Review, 95: 1495–1532; http://repositories.cdlib.org/blewp/19Google Scholar
Mark, Lemley, 2002. Intellectual property rights and standard-setting organization. California Law Review, 90: 1889–1980; available at www.ssrn.comGoogle Scholar
Lawrence Lessig, 2001. The Future of Ideas: The Fate of the Commons in a Connected World. Random House, New York
, R. Levin, , A. Klevorick, , R. Nelson, and , S. Winter, 1987. “Appropriating the returns from industrial R&D,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 783–820Google Scholar
Martin Libicki, James Schneider, Dave R. Frelinger, and Ann Slomovic, 2000. Scaffolding the New Web: Standards and Standards Policy for the Digital Economy. RAND, Santa Monica; http://www.rand.org/publications/MR/MR1215/
Robert Litan and Alice Rivlin, 2001. The Economic Payoff from the Internet Revolution. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC
Robert Litan and Hal Varian, 2001. The netimpact study. Technical report, University of California at Berkeley, http://www.netimpactstudy.com
Gregory, Mankiw and Michael, Whinston, 1986. Free entry and social inefficiency. Rand Journal of Economics, 17 (1): 48–58Google Scholar
Charles Mann, 1998. Who will own your next good idea? The Atlantic Online, September; http://www.theatlantic.com/issues/98sep/copy.htm
Peter Menell, 2000. Intellectual property: General theories. In Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit de Gees, eds., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
Peter, Menell, 2003. Envisioning copyright law's digital future. New York Law School Law Review, 46: 63–109Google Scholar
Robert, Merges, 1999. As many as six impossible patents before breakfast: property rights for business concepts and patent system reform. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 14 (2): 577–615Google Scholar
Judith Holland Mortimer, 2001. The effects of revenue-sharing contracts on welfare in vertically separated markets: Evidence from the video rental industry. Technical report, Economics Department, Harvard University
Barry Nalebuff, 1999. Bundling. Technical Report 99–14, School of Management, Yale University
Barry Nalebuff, 2000. Competing against bundles. Technical Report 00–7, School of Management, Yale University
National Research Council, 2004. A Patent System for the 21st Century, ed. Stephen A. Merrill, Richard C. Levin, and Mark B. Myers. Committee on Intellectual Property Rights in the Knowledge-Based Economy, Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy, Policy and Global Affairs, National Research Council of the National Academies of Science, Washington, DC
Waltern, Oi, 1971. A Disneyland dilemma: Two-part tariffs for a Mickey Mouse monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85: 77–96Google Scholar
Jennifer Reinganum, 1989. The timing of innovation: Research, development, and diffusion. In R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization. North-Holland, Amsterdam
John G. Riley, 1999. Asymmetric contests: A resolution of the Tullock paradox. In Peter Howitt, Elisabetta De Antoni, and Axel Leijonhufvud, eds., Money, Markets and Method: Essays in Honor of Robert W. Clower. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham; http://www.econ.ucla.edu/riley/research/
Jeffrey, Rohlfs, 1974. A theory of interdependent demand for a communications service. Bell Journal of Economics, 5 (1): 16–37Google Scholar
Jeffrey Rohlfs 2001. Bandwagon Effects in High-Technology Industries. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
Monica, Roman, 2001. Black ink all over Hewlett-Packard. Business Week, 22 January; http://www.businessweek.com/@@8zC3j2QQgISnLgEA/premium/content/01_22/Google Scholar
Linda Rosencrance, 2000. Amazon charging different prices on some DVDs. Computerworld, 5 September; http://www.computerworld.com/cwi/story/0,1199,NAV47_STO49569,00.html
Stephen, W. Salant, 1989. When is inducing self-selection suboptimal for a monopolist?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104 (2): 391–397Google Scholar
Pamela Samuelson, 2003. DRM {and, or, vs.} the law. Communications of the ACM, April: 41–45; http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~pam/papers.html
Pamela Samuelson, 2004. Legally speaking: Why reform the US patent system? Unpublished paper; http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~pam/papers.html
Pamela, Samuelson and Suzanne, Scotchmer, 2002. The law and economics of reverse engineering. Yale Law Journal, 111: 1575–1663Google Scholar
Pamela Samuelson and Hal R. Varian, 2002. The “New Economy” and information technology policy. In Jeffrey Frankle, ed., Economic Policy During the Clinton Administration. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA; http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~hal
Richard, Schmalensee, 1981a. Monopolistic two-part tariff arrangements. Bell Journal of Economics, 12: 445–466Google Scholar
Richard, Schmalensee, 1981b. Output and welfare implications of monopolistic third-degree price discrimination. American Economic Review, 71: 242–247Google Scholar
Joseph Schumpeter, 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
Joseph Schumpeter, 2000. The analysis of economic change. In Richard V. Clemence, ed., Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles and the Evolution of Capitalism. Transaction Books, New Brunswick, pp. 134–149. Originally published in Review of Economic Statistics, May 1935
Carl Shapiro, 2000. Competition policy in the information economy. In Einar Hope, ed., Foundations of Competition Policy Analysis, vol. XXV. Routledge, New York
Carl Shapiro, 2001a. Cross licenses, patent pools, and standard-setting. In Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds., Innovation Policy and the Economy, vol. II. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
Carl Shapiro, 2001b. Navigating the patent thicket. In Adam Jaffe, Joshua Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds., Innovation Policy and the Economy, National Bureau of Economics, Washington, DC; http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro
Carl Shapiro, 2004. Patent system reform: economic analysis and critique. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, forthcoming; http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro
Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, 1998a. Information Rules. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge, MA; http://www.inforules.com
Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, 1998b. Versioning: The smart way to sell information. Harvard Business Review, November–December: 106–114
Oz Shy, 2001. The Economics of Network Industries. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Susan Smulyan, 1994. Selling Radio: The Commercialization of American Broadcasting. Smithsonian Institution Press, Washington, DC
Charles Steindel and Kevin J. Stiroh, 2001. Productivity: What is it and why do we care? Technical report, New York Federal Reserve Bank; http://www.ny.frb.org/rmaghome/staffrp/2001/sr122.pdf
Kevin Stiroh, 2001. Information technology and the US productivity revival: What do the industry data say? Technical report, New York Federal Reserve Bank; http://www.ny.frb.org/rmaghome/staff_rp/2001/sr115.html
Nancy, Stokey, 1979. Intertemporal price discrimination. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93: 355–371Google Scholar
George, V. Thompson, 1954. Intercompany technical standardization in the early American automobile industry. Journal of Economic History, 14 (1): 1–20Google Scholar
David Ulph and Nir Vulkan, 2000. Electronic commerce and competitive first-degree price discrimination. Technical report, University College, London; http://www.ecn.bris.ac.uk/www/ecnv/welcome.htm
David Ulph and Nir Vulkan, 2001. E-commerce, mass customization and price discrimination. Technical report, University College, London; http://www.ecn.bris.ac.uk/www/ecnv/welcome.htm
Abbott Usher, 1954. A History of Mechanical Invention. Dover, Cambridge, MA
Hal, R. Varian, 1980. A model of sales. American Economic Review, 70: 651–659Google Scholar
Hal, R. Varian, 1985. Price discrimination and social welfare. American Economic Review, 75 (4): 870–875Google Scholar
Hal R. Varian, 1997. Economic aspects of personal privacy. In Larry Irving, ed., Privacy and Self-Regulation in the Information Age. National Telecommunications and Information Administration, Washington, DC; http://www.ntia.doc.gov/reports/privacy/privacy_rpt.htm
Hal, R. Varian, 2000. Buying, sharing and renting information goods. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48 (4): 473–488Google Scholar
Hal R. Varian, 2001. Versioning information goods. In Brian Kahin and Hal R. Varian, eds., Internet Publishing and Beyond: The Economics of Digital Information and Intellectual Property. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA; http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~hal/people/hal/papers.html
Hal R. Varian and Carl Shapiro, 2003. Linux adoption in the public sector: An economic analysis. Unpublished paper; http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~hal/Papers/2004/linux-adoption-in-the-public-sector.pdf
Brian Viard, 2003. Do switching costs make markets more or less competitive: The case of 800-number portability. Unpublished paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University; http://faculty-gsb.stanford.edu/viard/Personal/PDF/port.pdf
Miguel, J. Villas-Boas, 1999. Dynamic competition with customer recognition. RAND Journal of Economics, 30 (4): 604–631Google Scholar
J. Miguel Villas-Boas 2001. Price cycles in markets with customer recognition. Technical report, Hass School of Business, University of California at Berkeley
Nir Vulkan, 2003. The Economics of E-Commerce: A Strategic Guide to Understanding and Designing the Online Marketplace. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Martin, Weitzman, 1998. Recombinant growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113: 331–360Google Scholar
Michael, D. Whinston, 1990. Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion. American Economic Review, 80 (4): 837–859Google Scholar
Michael, D. Whinston, 2001. Exclusivity and tying in US v. Microsoft: What we know, and don't know. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (2): 63–80Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Hal R. Varian, University of California, Berkeley, Joseph Farrell, University of California, Berkeley, Carl Shapiro, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: The Economics of Information Technology
  • Online publication: 06 July 2010
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754166.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Hal R. Varian, University of California, Berkeley, Joseph Farrell, University of California, Berkeley, Carl Shapiro, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: The Economics of Information Technology
  • Online publication: 06 July 2010
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754166.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Hal R. Varian, University of California, Berkeley, Joseph Farrell, University of California, Berkeley, Carl Shapiro, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: The Economics of Information Technology
  • Online publication: 06 July 2010
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754166.004
Available formats
×